Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

War mobilization or war destruction? The unequal rise of progressive taxation revisited

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper sheds new light on the massive increase of progressive taxation in the first half of the twentieth century. Existing studies have explained this increase with the mass mobilization during the World Wars and the call for a fair sharing of the burdens of these wars. My analysis suggests that this effect was not uniform across mobilizing countries. Instead, the call for higher taxation of the rich was curbed by allocational concerns about capital rebuilding in those countries whose capital stock had been severely damaged during the war. Therefore, these countries increased progressive taxes much less. I find some evidence for this thesis in an analysis of top income and inheritance tax rates in 20 developed economies and a case study of tax policy debates in Germany after World War II. My finding has importance for the understanding of progressive taxation as well as for the understanding of tax policies more generally. It suggests that the two World Wars affected the development of tax systems not only through a distributional but also through an allocational channel.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Arguments that challenge purely distributional accounts and point out the political importance of (allocational) producer group coalitions have a venerable tradition in comparative political economy (e.g., Baccaro and Pontusson 2016; Hall and Soskice 2001; Katzenstein 1985). However, their focus has always been on the labor market and the welfare state, whereas taxation has received little attention. For a rare but important exception, see Mares and Queralt (2015).

  2. Queralt (2016) argues that lack of access to international war financing leads to a strengthening of the tax state. However, this does not mean that taxes will become more progressive.

  3. Other taxes (in particular the corporate income tax) might be even more important for capital formation (see Musgrave 1979). Unfortunately, a lack of data prevents me from studying these taxes systematically. However, if destruction affects taxes that less explicitly target the creation of capital, it should affect these taxes even more strongly. In this sense, the selection of income and inheritance taxes works against my hypothesis.

  4. See Beckert (2008) for an excellent account of historical debates about inheritance taxation.

  5. That these arguments were indeed often invoked is demonstrated by the case study of Germany below.

  6. The point is not that allocational arguments were not discussed in non-destroyed countries. As Daunton (2002) reports, concerns about capital allocation were repeatedly raised in the UK after both World Wars. However, I argue that these arguments were much less likely to succeed.

  7. Scheve and Stasavage briefly discuss allocational concerns under the header that taxing the rich may be ‘self-defeating’ (2016: 18) and reject this argument empirically, arguing that lower growth rates did not cause the decline of tax rates since the 1970s. This, however, tests a different mechanism than the one advanced here: a gradual decline of growth instead of a shock to the capital stock. They also discuss the effect of destruction, but from the exact opposite angle: They speculate that the rich may have lost political influence, ‘perhaps because of wartime destruction of their assets’. However, they find no evidence for this: ‘[non-destroyed countries], did just as much or more to tax the rich as did governments in countries […] that were devastated by World War I’ (2016: 91). I offer an explanation for this observation.

  8. Great Britain suffered German bombardments, mainly in 1940 and 1941. However, their destructions pale in comparison to the havoc caused by Allied bombing of Germany after 1942 (Overy 2014: 112, 162–163; Armstrong et al. 1991: 8).

  9. Based on war location, war duration, and the number of victims, Obinger and Schmitt (2017) rank the ‘war intensity’ for WWII participants as follows: Germany (highest) – Austria – Japan – Italy – Finland – UK – France – New Zealand - Australia – Canada – US (lowest).

  10. France also suffered the largest decline of its working age population due to the war. In terms of the capital stock per employee, the war-damage might thus not have been as severe as it would seem.

  11. In addition, high destruction countries were probably more likely to also suffer a loss of financial wealth (e.g., because they more often had to resort to printing money for financing the war).

  12. These countries include all 13 war participants discussed above as well as seven non-mobilizing countries: Denmark, Ireland, the Netherlands, Norway, Spain (income tax only), Sweden, and Switzerland.

  13. As I try to measure cumulative destruction over the war period, I use income in the last year of the five-year periods.

  14. Industrial capital, though, had survived the war in a surprisingly good condition (and was on average much younger than it had been before the war, Abelshauser 2011), but his was not really clear to observers at the time.

  15. All translations from German sources in this section are my own.

References

  • Abelshauser, W. (2011). Deutsche Wirtschaftsgeschichte seit 1945. München: C. H. Beck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldcroft, D. H., & Morewood, S. (2013). The European economy since 1914. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, P., Glyn, A., & Harrison, J. (1991). Capitalism since 1945. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, J. (2008) Do tax structures affect aggregate economic growth?, OECD Economics Department Working Paper 643.

  • Atkinson, A. (2015). Inequality. What can be done? Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baccaro, L., & Pontusson, J. (2016). Rethinking comparative political economy: the growth model perspective. Politics & Society, 44, 175–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartels, L. (2008). Unequal democracy: The political economy of the new gilded age. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2008). Inherited wealth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beramendi, P., & Rueda, D. (2007). Social democracy constrained: indirect taxation in industrialized democracies. British Journal of Political Science, 37, 619–641.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boss, A. (1987) Incentives und Wirtschaftswachstum: zur Steuerpolitik in der frühen Nachkriegszeit, Kiel Working Paper 295.

  • Bundesarchiv (2016[1950]) Die Kabinettsprotokolle der Bundesregierung. Protokoll der 39. Kabinettssitzung am 27. Januar 1950.

  • Cusack, T. R., & Beramendi, P. (2006). Taxing work. European Journal of Political Research, 45, 43–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daunton, M. (2002). Just taxes. The politics of taxation in Britain, 1914–1979. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Deutscher Bundestag (1949a) Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Änderung des Einkommensteuergesetzes, BT-Drucksache Nr. 317.

  • Deutscher Bundestag (1949b). Plenarprotokoll. Stenografischer Bericht der 5. Sitzung der 1. Wahlperiode (20.09.1949).

  • Deutscher Bundestag (1950). Plenarprotokoll. Stenografischer Bericht der 26. Sitzung der 1. Wahlperiode (11.01.1950).

  • Deutscher Bundestag (1952). Schriftlicher Bericht des Ausschusses für Finanz- und Steuerfragen über den Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Förderung des Kapitalmarkts durch steuerliche Begünstigung festverzinslicher Wertpapiere, BT-Drucksache Nr. 3773.

  • Deutscher Bundestag (1953). Plenarprotokoll. Stenografischer Bericht der 252. Sitzung der 1. Wahlperiode (04.03.1953).

  • Deutscher Bundestag (1954). Plenarprotokoll. Stenografischer Bericht der 18. Sitzung der 2. Wahlperiode (11.03.1954).

  • Diefendorf, J. M. (1993). In the wake of war: The reconstruction of German cities after world war II. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Domenico, R. P. (2002). Remaking Italy in the twentieth century. Lanham: Rowman&Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlicher, W. (1974). Deutsche Finanzpolitik 1949-1974. Wirtschaftsdienst, 54, 239–244.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B. (2007). The European economy since 1945: Coordinated capitalism and beyond. Princeton: Princeton Unviersity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, C. R., Kim, K. S., & Westphal, L. E. (1975). Economic growth in South Korea since World War II. In C. R. Frank, K. S. Kim, & L. E. Westphal (Eds.), Foreign trade regimes and economic development: South Korea (pp. 6–24). Cambridge: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ganghof, S. (2006). Tax mixes and the size of the welfare state: causal mechanisms and policy implications. Journal of European Social Policy, 16, 360–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelman, A., & Stern, H. (2006). The difference between “significant” and “not significant” is not itself statistically significant. The American Statistician, 60, 328–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilens, M. (2012). Affluence and influence: Economic inequality and political power in America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hacker, J. S., & Pierson, P. (2010). Winner-take-all politics: How Washington made the rich richer—and turned its back on the middle class. New York: Simon&Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P. A., & Soskice, D. (Eds.). (2001). Varieties of capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann, M. (2007). Wege in den Schuldenstaat. Die strukturellen Probleme der deutschen Finanzpolitik als Resultat historischer Entwicklungen. Vierteljahreshefte für Zeitgeschichte, 55, 425–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hentschel, V. (1983). Steuersystem und Steuerpolitik in Deutschland 1890-1970. In W. Conze & R. M. Lepsius (Eds.), Sozialgeschichte der Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Beiträge zum Kontinuitätsproblem (pp. 256–295). Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoover, G. E. (1927). The economic effects of inheritance taxes. American Economic Review, 17, 38–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hughes, M. L. (1999). Shouldering the Burdens of Defeat. West Germany and the Reconstruction of Social Justice. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kato, J. (2003). Regressive taxation and the welfare state: Path dependency and policy diffusion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Katzenstein, P. (1985). Small states in world markets. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keese, M., Salou, G. and Richardson, P. (1991) The measurement of output and factors of production for the business sector in OECD Countries, OECD Department of Economics and Statistics Working Paper No. 99, Paris.

  • Kopczuk, W. and Slemrod, J. (2000) The impact of the estate tax on the wealth accumulation and avoidance behavior of donors NBER Working Paper 7960.

  • Londono, J. (2014) War and progressive income taxation in the 20th century, BEHL Working Paper WP2014-03.

  • Maddison, A. (1994) Standardised estimates of fixed capital stock: A six country comparison, Research Memorandum 570, Groningen Growth and Development Centre.

  • Mares, I., & Queralt, D. (2015). The non-democratic origins of income taxation. Comparative Political Studies, 48, 1974–2009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milward, A. S. (2003 [1984]) The reconstruction of Western Europe, 1945–51, Abingdon: Routledge.

  • Muscheid, J. (1986). Die Steuerpolitik in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland 1949–1982. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. (1979). Tax policy and capital formation. National Tax Journal, 351–357.

  • Neumark, F. (1986). Review of “Die Steuerpolitik in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland 1949-1982”. FinanzArchiv, 45, 338–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obinger, H., & Petersen, K. (2017). Mass warfare and the welfare state - causal mechanisms and effects. British Journal of Political Science, 47, 203–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obinger, H. and Schmitt, C. (2017) 'The impact of the second world war on postwar social spending', European Journal of Political Research, Online First.

  • OECD (2010) Tax policy reform and economic growth, OECD Tax Policy Studies No. 20.

  • Overy, R. (2014) The bombing war: Europe 1939–1945: Penguin.

  • Peacock, A. T., & Wiseman, J. (1961). The growth of public expenditure in the United Kingdom. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Queralt, D. (2016). The legacy of war on fiscal capacity. Unpublished Manuscript.

  • Scheve, K., & Stasavage, D. (2010). The conscription of wealth: mass warfare and the demand for progressive taxation. International Organization, 64, 529–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, K., & Stasavage, D. (2012). Democracy, war, and wealth: lessons from two centuries of inheritance taxation. American Political Science Review, 106, 81–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, K., & Stasavage, D. (2016). Taxing the rich. A history of fiscal fairness in the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Seawright, J. (2016) 'The case for selecting cases that are deviant or extreme on the independent variable', Sociological Methods & Research, Online First.

  • Seawright, J., & Gerring, J. (2008). Case selection techniques in case study research. A menu of qualitative and quantitative options. Political Research Quarterly, 61, 294–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steinmo, S. (1993). Taxation and democracy. Swedish, British and American approaches to financing the modern state. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, D. (2004). 1914–1918: The history of the first world war. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. (1990). Coercion, Capital, and European States: A.D. 990–1990. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuckerman, L. (2004). The rape of Belgium: The untold story of world war I. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Nils Redeker, Daniele Caramani, Julian Garritzmann, Thomas Brambor, Raphael Reinke, Kenneth Scheve, and three anonymous reviewers for helpful comments. Earlier versions of the manuscript were presented at the 2016 European Political Science Association General Conference and the 2016 American Political Science Association Annual Meeting.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lukas Haffert.

Electronic supplementary material

ESM 1

(DOCX 16 kb)

ESM 2

(DOCX 285 kb)

ESM 3

(DTA 531 kb)

ESM 4

(DO 10 kb)

ESM 5

(DO 19 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Haffert, L. War mobilization or war destruction? The unequal rise of progressive taxation revisited. Rev Int Organ 14, 59–82 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-018-9300-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-018-9300-0

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation