Abstract
In this paper we seek to advance the debate on the conditions under which the WTO Dispute Settlement Body can bring about trade-liberalizing policy change in WTO members. Under what conditions do WTO members change domestic policies or measures that are challenged in WTO litigation? Starting from the assumption that policymakers are political-support maximizers who seek to avoid the mobilization of political enemies, we argue that the degree of integration in Global Value Chains (GVCs) of the economic sectors affected by a WTO dispute influences members’ propensity to change domestic policies when targeted in WTO litigation. The initiation of a WTO dispute against sectors highly integrated in GVCs engenders the emergence of a domestic coalition of pro-trade liberalization groups composed of exporters seeking to avoid the imposition of retaliatory measures and import-dependent firms wishing to exploit the opportunity to access cheaper imports. Under these circumstances, trade-liberalizing responses to WTO legal challenges are therefore more likely. We test this hypothesis by estimating a Cox proportional hazard model and find that GVCs positively impact states’ propensity to comply with the WTO dispute settlement panel rulings.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.



Notes
- 1.
For a more comprehensive review of these various literatures see Bernauer et al. (2014) and De Bièvre et al. (2017).
- 2.
On the private-public partnership in WTO dispute settlement, see Shaffer (2003).
- 3.
- 4.
See also, OECD (2014).
- 5.
For a detailed overview of exporting sectors and the collective action dilemmas they face, see Dür (2010).
- 6.
We follow Grossman and Helpman (2001) and consider policymakers to be self-interested actors.
- 7.
For an extensive overview, see Read (2005).
- 8.
See: the proceedings of the Impact of the Section 201 Safeguard Action on Certain Steel Products. Hearing before the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Ways and Means Subcommittee on Trade, March 26 2003.
- 9.
Tonya Vinas “DDayFor Steel,” Industry Week, December 21, 2004. Accessed on May 12, 2016 via: http://www.industryweek.com/none/d-day-steel. See also: “U.S. Disagrees with the WTO steel Ruling,” The World Trade Review, 15 December 2003. Accessed via: http://www.worldtradereview.com/news.asp?pType=N&iType=A&iID=72&siD=23&nID=12206.
- 10.
See: Press Briefing by US Trade Representative Zoellick on Ending the Temporary Steel Safeguards. Washington: The White House Office of the Press Secretary Available at: http://iipdigital.usembassy.gov/st/english/texttrans/2003/12/20031204164450yessedo0.718197.html#ixzz45cv7YfiB Accessed on April 12, 2016.
- 11.
Relevant data are missing for a subset of WTO defendants, including Thailand, Egypt, Guatemala, Argentina, Colombia, Chile, the Dominican Republic, and the Philippines. Collectively, these defendants account for 17 cases, which are omitted from our first model due to data limitations. However, in our second model, we conduct two separate analyses using alternative data sources, which can include most of these missing disputes. They reveal substantively similar results.
- 12.
We start the clock to calculate ‘time until compliance’ from the AB report because the extent of a violation, and therefore the extent of policy change required to bring about compliance, is only clarified for the defendants after a final ruling is delivered by the AB. As a robustness check, however, we run separate analyses in our supplementary appendix in which we calculate the ‘time until compliance’ from the original panels’ report. Our results are substantively similar.
- 13.
Four additional details warrant attention. First, in cases where there were multiple complainants in a dispute, we distinguish each pair and count them as separate disputes. This decision is consistent with a number of works in the field (e.g., Horn et al. 1999; Bagwell et al. 2004) and was made so that we can observe the impact of additional WTO members in a dispute. Second, our sample does not include disputes that targeted horizontal measures, since these disputes did not target specific sectors. Although some horizontal measures may involve certain sectors more than others, we only examine responses to litigation if there is a sector whose import dependence can be measured. Third, a few disputes resulted in compliance around the same time there was a panel ruling. Even though the defendants in these disputes did not comply with a panel ruling per se, they demonstrated domestic policy change after a panel composition, in which the clarity of violations were most likely made before the circulation of panel reports. Finally, in certain disputes, defendants notified the WTO DSB of compliance, but we could not find the corresponding domestic legislation. These cases are coded “complied with” and we rely on WTO Members’ notification to the DSB and official WTO records to consider the extent of compliance.
- 14.
For the World Input Output Database, see: http://www.wiod.org/new_site/database/wiots.htm
- 15.
For the TiVA dataset, see http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=TIVA2015_C1#.
- 16.
The data on FDI stocks were collected from the OECD where available and EUROSTAT for the EU. For the data on developing WTO members, we utilized UNCTAD. The closest year available was used if data were missing for certain years.
- 17.
See OECD (1993), for an overview on HHI index and sector concentration.
- 18.
- 19.
Results remain substantively similar when omitting outliers.
- 20.
More information on the specifics of the TiVA data and the substantive effects can be found in the appendix.
- 21.
References
Amador, J., & Cabra S. (2014). Global Value Chains Surveying Drivers and Measures. Working Paper 1739 (2014). Frankfurt: European Central Bank (ECB). https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp1739.en.pdf?13f6d86f40a3c60325f27cbc08a18742. Accessed 22 March 2016.
Antràs, P. (2010). International trade and organizations. Vol. 2. National Bureau of Economic Research. Reporter 2010, 2, 7-10.
Antràs, P., & Staiger, R. (2012). Offshoring and the role of trade agreements. American Economic Review, 102(7), 3140–3183.
Baccini, L., & Kim, S. Y. (2012). Preventing protectionism: International institutions and trade policy. The Review of International Organizations, 7(4), 369–398.
Baccini, L., Dür, A., & Elsig, M. (2015). Intra-industry trade, global value chains, and the political economy of Preferential trade liberalization. Unpublished manuscript.
Bagwell, K., Mavroidis, P., & Staiger, R. (2004). The case for tradable remedies in WTO dispute settlement. Discussion paper no. 0405-05. New York: Department of Economics, Columbia University.
Baldwin, R. (2012). Global supply chains: Why they emerged, why they matter, and where they are going. In Working Paper 2012–01. Hong Kong: Fung Global Institute.
Baldwin, R. (2014). WTO 2.0: Governance of 21st century trade. The Review of International Organizations, 9(2), 261–283.
Bechtel, M., & Sattler, T. (2015). What is litigation in the World Trade Organization worth? International Organization, 69(02), 375–403.
Berkhout, J., Carroll, B., Braun, C., Chalmers, A. W., Destrooper, T., Lowery, D., Otjes, S., & Rasmussen, A. (2015). Interest organizations across economic sectors: Explaining interest group density in the European Union. Journal of European Public Policy, 22(04), 462–480.
Bernard, A., Jensen, B. and Schott, P. K. (2009). Importers, exporters, and multinationals: A portrait of firms in the U.S. that trade goods. In Producer Dynamics edited by Timothy Dunne, J. Bradford Jensen and Mark J. Roberts. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Bown, C. (2004). On the economic success of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(3), 811–823.
Bown, C. (2009). Self-enforcing trade: Developing countries and WTO dispute settlement. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Bown, C., & Reynolds, K. (2015). Trade flows and trade disputes. The Review of International Organizations, 10, 145–177. doi:10.1007/s11558-014-9208-2.
Box-Steffensmeier, J., Reiter, D., & Zorn, C. (2003). Nonproportional hazards and event history analysis in international relations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47(1), 33–53.
Brewster, R., & Chilton, A. (2014). Supplying Complinace: Why and when the United States complies with WTO rulings. Yale Journal of International Law, 39(2), 201–246.
Burch, D., & Lawrence, G. (2005). Supermarket own brands, supply chains and the transformation of the agri-food system. International Journal of Sociology of Agriculture and Food, 13(1), 1–18.
Busch, M. (2000). Bargaining in the shadow of the law: Early settlement in GATT/WTO disputes. Fordham International Law Journal, 24, 158–172.
Busch, M., & Pelc, K. (2010). The politics of judicial economy at the World Trade Organization. International Organization, 64(2), 257–279.
Busch, M., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Transatlantic trade conflicts and GATT/ WTO dispute settlement. In Dispute Prevention and Dispute Settlement in the Transatlantic Partnership (eds) Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann and Mark Pollack. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Chase, K. (2003). Economic interests and regional trading arrangements: The case of NAFTA. International Organization, 57(1), 137–174.
Chaudoin, S., Kucik, J., & Pelc K., (2016). Do WTO disputes actually increase trade? International Studies Quarterly, 0, 1–13 – Advanced online publication. Accessible via: http://isq.oxfordjournals.org/content/early/2016/04/15/isq.sqw009.
Chayes, A., & Chayes, A. H. (1993). On compliance. International Organization, 47(2), 175–205.
Commission of the European Communities (CEC) (2002). The European Commission’s strategy to respond to the US decision to impose protectionist duties on steel imports. MEMO/02/59, 18 March.
Davey, W. J. (2005). Implementation in WTO dispute settlement: An Introduction to the problems and possible solutions. In Research paper 05–16. Chicago: College of Law, University of Illinois.
Davis, C. (2012). Why adjudicate: Enforcing trade rules in the WTO. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Davis, C., & Pelc, K. (2015). Cooperation in hard Times: Self-Restraint of Trade Protection. Journal of Conflict Resolution. doi: 10.1177/0022002715595699.
De Bièvre, D., & Dür, A. (2005). Constituency interests and delegation in European and American trade policy. Comparative Political Studies, 38(10), 1271–1296.
De Bièvre, D., & Eckhardt, J. (2011). Interest groups and EU anti-dumping policy. Journal of European Public Policy, 18(3), 339–360.
De Bièvre, D., Poletti, A., Hanegraff, M., & Beyers, J. (2016). International institutions and interest mobilization: The WTO and lobbying in EU and US trade policy. Journal of World Trade, 50(2), 289–312.
De Bièvre, D., Poletti, A., & Yildirim, A. (2017). About the melting of icebergs: Discovering the political-economic determinants of dispute initiation and resolution in the WTO. In M. Elsig, B. Hoekman, & J. Pauwelyn (Eds.), In Assessing the World Trade Organisation: Fit for Purpose? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dür, A. (2010). Protection for exporters: Power and discrimination in Transatlantic trade relations, 1930–2010. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Eckhardt, J. (2011). Firm lobbying and EU trade policy making: Reflections on the anti-dumping case against Chinese and Vietnamese shoes (2005-2011). Journal of World Trade, 45(5), 965–991.
Eckhardt, J. (2013). ‘EU unilateral trade policy-making: What role for import-dependent firms?’. Journal of Common Market Studies, 51(6), 989–1005.
Eckhardt, J. (2015). Business lobbying and trade governance: The case of EU-China relations. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Eckhardt, J., & Poletti, A. (2016). The politics of global value chains: Import dependent firms and EU-Asia trade agreements. Journal of European Public Policy. doi:10.1080/13501763.2015.1085073.
Efron, B. (1977). The efficiency of Cox's likelihood function for censored data. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 72(359), 557–565.
Elsig, M., & Pollack, M. (2014). Agents, trustees, and international courts: Nomination and appointment of judicial candidates in the WTO appellate body. European Journal of International Relations, 20(2), 391–415.
Elms, D. & Low, P. (2013). “Global value chains in a changing world”, Introduction, Switzerland: World Trade Organization. Accessible via: https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/aid4tradeglobalvalue13_e.pdf. Accessed 30 March 2017.
Gereffi, G. (1999). International trade and industrial upgrading in the apparel commodity chain. Journal of International Economics, 48(1), 37–70.
Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J., & Sturgeon, T. (2005). The governance of global value chains. Review of International Political Economy, 12(1), 78–104.
Goldstein, J. (1996). International law and domestic institutions: Reconciling North American "unfair" trade Laws. International Organization, 50(4), 541–564.
Goldstein, J., & Martin, L. L. (2000). Legalization, trade liberalization, and domestic politics: A cautionary note. International Organization, 54(3), 603–632.
Goldstein, J., & Steinberg, R. (2008). Negotiate or litigate? Effects of WTO judicial delegation on US trade politics. Law and Contemporary Problems, 71(1), 257–282.
Goldstein, J., Kahler, M., Keohane, R., & Slaughter, A. (2000). Introduction: Legalization and world politics. International Organization, 54(3), 385–399.
Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. The American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850.
Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (2001). Special interest politics. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Guzman, A., & Simmons, B. (2002). To settle or empanel? An empirical analysis of litigation and settlement at the WTO. The Journal of Legal Studies, 31(1), 205–235.
Guzman, A., & Simmons, B. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: The selection of defendants in World Trade Organization disputes. The Journal of Legal Studies, 34(2), 557–598.
Hanmer, M. J., & Kalkan, K. O. (2013). Behind the curve: Clarifying the best approach to calculating predicted probabilities and marginal effects from limited dependent variable models. American Journal of Political Science, 57(1), 267–277.
Hathaway, O. A. (1998). Positive feedback: The impact of trade liberalization on industry demands for protection. International Organization, 52(3), 575–612.
Henisz, W. J. (2011). Political constraints database. Data and codebook accessed via; http://www-management.wharton.upenn.edu/henisz/.
Hiscox, M. J. (2001). Class versus industry cleavages: Inter-industry factor mobility and the politics of trade. International Organization, 55, 1–46.
Hoekman, B., & Mavroidis, P. (2000). WTO dispute settlement, transparency and surveillance. The World Economy, 23(4), 527–542.
Hoffman, T., & Kim, S. Y. (2009). The political economy of compliance in WTO disputes. Unpublished Manuscript.
Horn, H., & Mavroidis, P. (2008). The WTO dispute settlement system data set: Some descriptive statistics. Washington: World Bank www.worldbank.org/trade/wtodisputes.
Horn, H., Nordström, H., & Mavroidis, P. (1999). Is the use of the WTO dispute settlement system biased? Discussion paper 2340. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
Horn, H., Johannesson, L., & Mavroidis, P. (2011). The WTO dispute settlement system 1995-2010: Some descriptive statistics. Journal of World Trade, 45(6), 1107–1138.
Hudec, R. E. (1993). Enforcing international trade law: The evolution of the modern GATT legal system. Salem: Butterworth Legal Publishers.
Jacobs, M. (2016). Smart threats and success in WTO dispute settlement: The bush steel tariffs. E-International Relations, March 24, 2016. http://www.e-ir.info/2016/03/24/smart-threats-and-success-in-wto-dispute-settlement-the-bush-steel-tariffs/. Accessed 1 November 2016.
Jensen, B., Quinn, D., & Weymouth, S. (2015). The influence of firm global supply chains and foreign currency Undervaluations on US trade disputes. International Organization, 69, 913–947.
Johnson, R. C., & Noguera, G. (2012). Accounting for intermediates: Production sharing and trade in value added. Journal of International Economics, 86(2), 224–236.
Keohane, R. (1984). After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Kim, S. Y. (2012). Protectionism during recession: Is this time different? The Political Economist, 9(2), 6–8.
Kim, S. Y. (2015). Regionalization in search of regionalism: Production networks and deep integration commitments in Asia’s PTAs. In In The Purpose, Design, and Effects of Preferential Trade Agreements, (eds) Andreas Dür and Manfred Elsig. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., & Alchian, A. A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics, 24, 297–326.
Kropko, J., & Harden, J. (n.d.). Beyond the hazard ratio: Generating expected durations from the cox proportional hazards model. Working Paper. International Methods Colloquium. http://media.wix.com/ugd/13cbcb_c74861dcbc8448cf99da5c01de6f53d1.pdf. Accessed 12 April 2016.
Krugman, P. (1981). “Intraindustry specialization and the gains from trade”. Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), 959–73.
Lanz, R., & Miroudot, S. (2011). Intra-firm trade: Patterns, determinants and policy implications. Working paper 114. Trade policy papers. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) publishing. http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/trade/intra-firm-trade_5kg9p39lrwnn-en. Accessed 12 April 2016.
Magee, S., Brock, W. A., & Young, L. (1989). Black hole tariff and endogenous policy theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Manger, M. (2009). Investing in protection: The politics of Preferential trade agreements between North and South. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Manger, M. (2012). Vertical trade specialization and the formation of North- South PTAs. World Politics, 64(4), 622–658.
Mansfield, E., Milner, H., & Rosendorff, P. (2002). ‘Why democracies cooperate more: Electoral control and international trade agreements’. International Organization, 56(3), 477–513.
Marshall, M., & Jaggers, K. (2002). Polity IV Project: Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800-2007. http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm. Accessed 12 April 2016.
Martin, L. (1992). Interests, power, and multilateralism. International Organization, 46(4), 765–792.
Messer, A., Berkhout, J., & Lowery, D. (2011). The density of the EU interest system: A test of the ESA model. British Journal of Political Science, 41(01), 161–190.
Milner, H. (1987). Resisting the protectionist temptation: Industry and the making of trade policy in France and the United States during the 1970s. International Organization, 41(4), 639–665.
Milner, H., & Moravcsik, A. (2009). Power, interdependence, and Nonstate actors in world politics. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Orefice, G., & Rocha, N. (2014). Deep integration and production networks: An empirical analysis. The World Economy, 37(1), 106–136.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (1993). Glossary for Industrial Organisation Economics and Competition Law. https://www.oecd.org/regreform/sectors/2376087.pdf. Accessed 15 February 2016.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (2014) Global Value Chains, Challenges, Opportunities, and Implications for Policy, Report prepared and submitted for the G-20 Trade Minister's Meeting, Sydney, Australia, July 2014. https://www.oecd.org/tad/gvc_report_g20_july_2014.pdf. Accessed 12 April 2016.
Pauwelyn, J. (2000). Enforcement and countermeasures in the WTO: Rules are rules-toward a more collective approach. American Journal of International Law, 94(2), 335–347.
Peritz, L. (2016). When are international institutions effective? The impact of domestic veto players on compliance with WTO rulings. Paper presented at the 9th annual meeting of the political economy of international organizations. Salt Lake City, Utah.
Poletti, A., & De Bièvre, D. (2014). Political mobilization, veto players, and WTO litigation: Explaining European Union responses in trade disputes. Journal of European Public Policy, 21(8), 1181–1198.
Poletti, A., & De Bièvre, D. (2015). Judicial politics in international trade relations: Introduction to the special issue. World Trade Review, 14, S1–S11.
Poletti, A., & De Bièvre, D. (2016). Judicial politics and international cooperation: From disputes to deal-making at the World Trade Organization. Colchester: ECPR Press.
Poletti, A., De Bièvre, D., & Chatagnier, J. T. (2015). Cooperation in the shadow of WTO law: Why litigate when you can negotiate? World Trade Review, 14(S1), S33–S58.
Read, R. (2005). The EU-US WTO steel dispute: Political economy of protection and the efficacy of the WTO dispute settlement understanding. In N. Perdikis & R. Read (Eds.), The WTO and the regulation of international trade: Recent trade disputes between the European Union and the United States (pp. 135–175). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Rickard, S. (2010). Democratic differences: Electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements. European Journal of International Relations, 16(4), 711–729.
Sattler, T., & Bernauer, T. (2011). Gravitation or discrimination? Determinants of litigation at the World Trade Organization. European Journal of Political Research, 50(2), 143–167.
Sattler, T., Spilker, G., & Bernauer, T. (2014). Does WTO dispute settlement enforce or inform? British Journal of Political Science, 44(04), 877–902.
Schattschneider, E. E. (1935). Politics, pressures and the tariff. New York: Prentice Hall.
Shaffer, G. (2003). Defending interests: Public-private partnerships in WTO litigation. Washington: Brookings Institution Press.
Slaughter, A. (1995). International law in a world of liberal states. European Journal of International Law, 6, 503–538.
Spilker, G. (2012). Compliance with WTO dispute rulings. Working paper 2011-25. Zurich: Switzerland: National Centre of competence in research trade regulation.
Timmer, M. P., Dietzenbacher, E., Los, B., Stehrer, R., & de Vries, G. (2015). An illustrated user guide to the world Input–output database: The case of global automotive production. Review of International Economics, 23, 575–605.
Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton University Press.
United States International Trade Commission (USITC) (2003). Steel-Consuming Industries: Competitive Conditions With Respect to Steel Safeguard Measures (Investigation No. 332–452).
Von Stein, J. (2012). The Engines of Compliance. In Synthesizing Insights from International Law and International Relations, (eds) Jeffrey Dunoff and Mark Pollack. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Weiss, E., & Jacobson, H. K. (1998). Engaging countries: Strengthening compliance with international environmental accords. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Wilson, B. (2007). Compliance by WTO members with adverse WTO dispute settlement rulings: The record to date. Journal of International Economic Law, 10(2), 397–403.
World Trade Organization. (2004). Handbook on the WTO dispute settlement system. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Yildirim, A. (2016). Domestic political implications of global value chains: Explaining EU responses to litigation at the World Trade Organisation. Comparative European Politics. doi:10.1057/s41295-016-0085-3.
Zangl, B. (2008). Judicialization matters! A comparison of dispute settlement under GATT and the WTO. International Studies Quarterly, 52(4), 825–854.
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to the attendees of the 9th Political Economy of International Organizations (PEIO) conference held in Salt Lake City, Utah. We extend our thanks to Leonardo Baccini, for his valuable comments. The authors gratefully acknowledge the support of the Research Fund of the University of Antwerp.
Author information
Affiliations
Corresponding author
Electronic supplementary material
ESM 1
(ZIP 516 kb)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Yildirim, A.B., Tyson Chatagnier, J., Poletti, A. et al. The internationalization of production and the politics of compliance in WTO disputes. Rev Int Organ 13, 49–75 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-017-9278-z
Published:
Issue Date:
Keywords
- International institutions
- World trade organization
- Global value chains
- Compliance