Skip to main content
Log in

Need for speed: The lending responsiveness of the IMF

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

How responsive a lender is the International Monetary Fund (IMF)? In this paper, I introduce new data on IMF loan approval periods: The days that transpire between when a borrower submits a “Letter of Intent” to the Executive Board requesting a loan and when the Board approves that request. The data reveal considerable variation across requests. Why are some loan requests approved swiftly while others wait much longer for approval? I argue that the financial interests of the G-5 economies drive variation in responsiveness contingent on when a request was made. I expect that during much of the 1980s, as G-5 commercial bank exposure increases, borrowers will face longer waits for approval. In such cases, the G-5 should have been more likely to press for the use of the “concerted lending” strategy. This protected G-5 financial systems by catalyzing private financing on behalf of those countries, but it also delayed loan approval. Into the 1990s, global capital flows grew more complex and catalyzing private capital flows required a swift response. Thus, during these years I expect increased G-5 bank exposure to be associated with shorter waits for approval. In such cases, the G-5 should have been more likely to press for accelerated approval. A quick response would have the best chance of attracting back private capital and reduce the threat posed by the crisis. Statistical analyses of 275 loan requests from 1984–2012 support these expectations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Bagehot asserted that during crises the Bank of England “should lend to all that bring good securities quickly, freely, and readily. By that policy they allay a panic; by every other policy they intensify it” (Bagehot 1873).

  2. The G-5 includes the United States, United Kingdom, Germany, Japan, and France.

  3. Mody and Saravia use a cutoff of one standard deviation which is, they admit, a “softer” approach than (Kaminsky and Reinhart 1999) which identifies speculative attacks at three standard deviations above the mean.

  4. Severe crises are identified when EMP is 1.5 standard deviations above the country mean.

  5. From a practical perspective, there is also no readily available record of when each country first began negotiations with Fund staff.

  6. This procedure was confirmed in a phone conversation with a high level IMF official.

  7. “While there were about 300 SBAs during this period, only 200 of them coincide with crises in the previous two years” (Mody and Saravia 2013, 192).

  8. 8 The IMF’s concessional loan programs are primarily designed to promote economic development and reduce poverty rather than respond to financial crises. Thus, from this paper’s perspective, they fall outside of the scope of the IMF’s international lender of last resort actions. By comparison, (Mody and Saravia 2013) only look at SBAs.

  9. 9 SBA dates were collected by the author at the IMF archives in Washington D.C.; EFF dates were collected by a research assistant via the Fund’s digital archive.

  10. The only Managing Director during this period not from a G-5 country was Spain’s Rodrigo Rato who held the position from June 2004 to November 2007.

  11. It should be noted that this position was created in 1994.

  12. Boughton (2001) describes the moment this became the Fund’s new approach: “The turning point came at the November 1982 meeting in New York...at which the Managing Director informed the banks that the Fund would not approve Mexico’s requests for an extended arrangement until the banks provided him with written assurances that they would increase their exposure by enough to cover a substantial fraction ($5 billion) of Mexico’s scheduled interest payments for 1983” (406).

  13. For a detailed description of the concerted lending approach, see Boughton (2001), 405-409.

  14. Bird and Rowlands (2004) date the strategy from 1982 through 1986 while Caskey (1989) notes that the strategy was adopted during the Mexican debt adjustment program through 1987.

  15. For example, between 1990 and 1994, roughly $670 billion of foreign capital flowed into countries in Asia and Latin America as investors around the world began putting their money into emerging stock markets and securities (Truman 1996, 201; Calvo, Leiderman and Reinhart 1996, 123).

  16. Calvo (1998) referred to the crises that developed in the 1990s as capital account crises to distinguish them from current account crises which were the dominant variety in previous decades.

  17. One notable exception to this point is the case of Korea during the Asian Financial Crisis. In January, 1998, the IMF implemented a concerted lending-like approach to forcibly catalyze additional lending from major banks. However, this approach was only used after the Fund’s initial, massive loan to Korea had already been approved in December 1997. Indeed, Korea’s SBA was approved one day after the Letter was filed making it the second shortest loan approval period in the sample. Thus, in the one known case where concerted lending was employed after 1987, it did not have the effect of delaying Board approval. Rather, it came following an incredibly swift vote. For more on the Korean crisis, see Boughton (2012, 557-565.)

  18. This view of catalytic financing has been compared to as “Powell Doctrine” in military affairs: Once a decision is made to intervene, it must be done with “overwhelming force” if it is to succeed (Zettelmeyer 2000; Jeanne and Wyplosz 2001). See Morris and Shin (2006) for an alternative view on the necessity of large credits for catalytic financing. Empirically, Mody and Saravia (2006) find limited evidence that larger loans from the IMF are more effective at catalyzing private financial flows on behalf of borrowers.

  19. For a excellent account of the Board’s debate surrounding the Mexican request, see Copelovitch (2010, 213-227).

  20. The RFI is sometimes referred to as the Emergency Financing Mechanism. It is not a separate lending arrangement per se rather it is a mechanism which can be activated when a member country is “facing an urgent balance of payments need” yet does not need a “full-fledged program” (International Monetary Fund 2012d).

  21. The RFI has been used on behalf of Korea and Indonesia in 1997, Turkey in 2001, Armenia, Georgia, Hungary, Iceland, Latvia, Pakistan, and Ukraine from 2008-2009, and Greece (twice), Ireland, Portugal, and Cyprus from 2010-2013.

  22. After the Asian financial crisis in 1997-1998, the Fund debuted the Contingent Credit Line (CCL) which was designed to prevent contagion by providing precautionary lines of credit to countries at risk (Bird and Rajan 2002). More recently, in the aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis of 2008, the IMF has introduced three new facilities designed to provide speedier financing to member states facing balance of payments crises: the Flexible Credit Line (FCL), the Precautionary and Liquidity Line (PLL), and the and Rapid Credit Facility (RCL) (IMF 2012a, b). Even the SBA was recently overhauled in order to make the workhorse arrangement more effective for members who may not qualify for an FCL arrangement “by providing increased flexibility to front-load access” intended to improve its “crisis prevention and crisis resolution” performance (IMF 2009, 3).

  23. The BIS consolidated bank claims data is the highest level aggregate data type that includes both private and public (sovereign) foreign debts.

  24. Data available at http://www.bis.org/statistics/consstats.htm

  25. This is calculated as follows: publicly guaranteed bond debt + private non-guaranteed bond debt/total public and publicly guaraneed debt owed to private creditors + total private non-guaranteed debt. All data are from WDI.

  26. Bailey et al. (2015, 1) estimate dynamic national ideal points using voting data in the UNGA from 1946-2012. They show that ideal point estimates improve upon conventional dyadic similarity indicators such as Affinity or S-scores (Gartzke 1998; Signorino and Ritter 1999) by distinguishing UN agenda changes from changes in state preferences.

  27. Data available at http://www.uni-heidelberg.de/fakultaeten/wiso/awi/professuren/intwipol/datasets.html

  28. There is no systematic variation in the Board’s meeting schedule that should affect IMF responsiveness. Since its creation, the Board has functioned in “continuous session at the principal office of the Fund” and meets “as often as the business of the Fund may require (Articles of Agreement, Article XII, Section 3(g)). Van Houtven (2002, 14-15) explained that, at the time of his writing, “total Board meeting time averages more than 12 hours a week and over 600 hours per year, which demonstrates the intense oversight exercised by the Board on activities of the IMF. Nearly one-third of the Board meeting time is devoted to policy issues, about 60 percent to surveillance, and the remainder to administrative and budgetary matters.”

  29. The variable Speculative Attack was created by the author based on the EMP index. It is calculated as follows:

    $$EMP_{i,t} = \frac{\Delta e_{i,t}}{\sigma_{{\Delta}_{e_{i}}}} - \frac{\Delta r_{i,t}}{\sigma_{{\Delta}_{r_{i}}}} $$

    e is the end-of-the-month U.S. dollar exchange rate of country i and r is the end-of-the-month non-gold reserves. A higher score on the index indicates increased pressure on a country’s currency. I identify a speculative attack as:

    $$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} Speculative Attack_{i,t} &&= 1\, if\, EMP_{i,t} > 2\sigma_{EMP_{i}} + \mu_{EMP_{1}} \\ &&= 0\, otherwise \end{array} $$

    σ E M P and μ E M P are the country-specific mean and standard deviation of EMP, respectively.

  30. Regional variables were created in Stata using the “Kountry” command based on the “Middle East broad” classification. Additionally, countries listed as “Oceana” were recoded as Asia resulting in five regional dummies: Africa, Americas, Asia, Middle East/North Africa (MENA) and Europe. In my statistical models, Europe is the baseline category to which other regions are compared.

  31. In each of these cases, I add 1 to the raw data prior to transformation in order to prevent zero values from becoming missing observations after transformation as the log of zero is undefined.

  32. For handling ties, I use the Efron method.

  33. An advantage of the Cox model is that it does not make parametric assumptions about the baseline hazard rate. This contrasts with parametric models, including Poisson and Negative Binomial models, which assume the hazard rate takes on a specific shape. Box-Steffensmeier and Zorn (2001, 21, 46) explain that unless “there exists strong theoretical expectation regarding the ‘shape’ of the hazard rate (or by extension, survival times), conditional on covariates in the model” then non-parametric models, like Cox, are preferable to parametric models.

  34. In my data collection efforts at the IMF archives, there were a total of three Letters of Intent filed for SBAs that I was unable to locate a corresponding approval date. In chronological order, these are: Malawi (8/11/1986), Brazil (9/13/1990), and Paraguay (1/9/1991). I was unable to determine whether these requests were rejected by the Board or withdrawn by the borrower countries. Because of this uncertainty and their rarity, I opted to exclude these cases from the analysis.

  35. Specifically, I calculate Shoenfeld residuals as described in Box-Steffensmeier and Zorn (2001).

  36. Nonetheless, the results are substantively unchanged when these are included.

  37. Based on Model 1, I generated simulations using the R package Zelig to replicate estimates of survival rates at levels specified for covariates of interest while holding all other covariates at their means. Point estimates displayed are the median observation from the simulation at each day after the loan request based on 1000 sample replications. The same process was used to generate all other post-estimation figures.

  38. The inclusion of Bond Debt leads to the omission of more than 30 observations which may bias these results against Hypothesis 4. Among these missing observations are most IMF credits to European countries since 2008. This includes credits to Greece (2010, 2012), Iceland (2008), Ireland (2010), Latvia (2008), and Portugal (2011). In each of these cases, G-5 bank exposure is above the mean and approval periods are quite swift.

  39. This is a parametric model, in contrast to the Cox model. Thus, it assumes a particular “shape” of the hazard rate. However, as Box-Steffensmeier and Zorn (2001, 21) explain, “if the distribution of failure times is parameterized incorrectly” then the findings may be inaccurate.

  40. The MENA (Middle East, North Africa) variable is absent because none of the borrowers in this sub-sample are from that region. The results are substantively unchanged if regional controls are removed.

  41. I generated simulations using the R package Zelig to replicate estimates of counted days between request and approval at levels specified for covariates of interest while holding all other covariates at their means. Point estimates used are means from simulations based on 1000 sample replications. The same process was used to generate all other post-estimation estimates discussed here.

  42. Mody and Saravia (2013) calculate the number of months between crisis and IMF program. However, measuring in days allows me to avoid losing information due to rounding up or down to the nearest month.

  43. There is one caveat here: In a number of cases, a borrower negotiated a new IMF program less than two years after its previous program. In such cases, I use the earliest crisis since the previous IMF program as the starting point.

References

  • Bagehot, W. (1873). Lombard street: a description of the money market. London: Henry S. King and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, M.A., Strezhnev, A., & Voeten, E. (2015). Estimating dynamic state preferences from United Nations voting. Journal of Conflict Resolution. Forthcoming.

  • Bird, G., & Rajan, R.S. (2002). The evolving asian financial architecture. Essays in international economics. No. 226. Princeton University: International Economics Section.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, G., & Rowlands, D. (2004). Does the IMF perform a catalytic role? And What if it Doesn’t? World Economics, 5, 117–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J., & Lee, J. (2005). IMF programs: who is chosen and what are the effects? Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1245–1269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordo, M.D., & James, H. (2000). The international monetary fund: its present role in historical perspective. Greek Economic Review, 20, 43–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boughton, J.M. (2000). From suez to Tequilla: the IMF as crisis manager. The Economic Journal, 110, 273–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boughton, J.M. (2001). Silent revolution: the international monetary fund, 1979–1989. Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boughton, J.M. (2012). Tearing down walls: the international monetary fund 1990-1999. Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Box-Steffensmeier, J.M., & Zorn, C.J.W (2001). Duration models and proportional hazards in political science. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 972–988.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broz, J.L., & Hawes, M.B. (2006). Congressional politics of financing the international monetary fund. International Organization, 60, 367–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G.A. (1998). Varieties of capital-market crises. In G.A. Calvo & M. King (Eds.) , The debt burden and its consequences for monetary policy (pp. 181–202). New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G.A., Leiderman, L., & Reinhart, C.M. (1996). Inflows of capital to developing countries in the 1990s. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10, 123–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caskey, J.P. (1989). The IMF and concerted lending in latin American debt restructurings: A formal analysis. Journal of International Money and Finance, 8, 105–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copelovitch, M.S. (2010). The international monetary fund in the global economy: banks, bonds, and bailouts. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., & Jensen, N. (2007). Independent actor or agent? An empirical analysis of the impact of US interests on IMF conditions. Journal of Law and Economics, 50, 105–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., Sturm, J.E., & Vreeland, J. (2009a). Global horse trading: IMF loans for votes in the United Nations Security Council. European Economic Review, 53, 742–757.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., Sturm, J.E., & Vreeland, J. (2009b). Development aid and international politics: does membership on the UN Security Council influence World Bank decisions? Journal of Development Economics, 88, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • [EBD] Executive Board Document (1985). requests for waiver of circulation periods of papers on the executive board agenda. EBD/85/5. International Monteary Fund. 4 January.

  • [EBD] Executive Board Document (1996). Minimum circulation periods for board documents. EBD/96/33. International Monteary Fund. 13 March.

  • [EBM] Executive Board Minutes (1983a). Minutes of the executive board meeting 83/57. International Monetary Fund. 6 April.

  • [EBM] Executive Board Minutes (1983b). Minutes of the executive board meeting 83/65. International Monetary Fund. 22 April.

  • [EBM] Executive Board Minutes (1995). Minutes of the executive board meeting 95/11. International Mon teary Fund. 19 November.

  • Eichengreen, B., Rose, A.K., Wyplosz, C., Dumas, B., & Weber, A. (1995). Exchange market mayhem: The antecedents and aftermath of speculative attacks. Economic Policy, 10, 249–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erb, R.D. (1983). Statement by Mr. Erb on fund policies and external debt servicing problems, executive board meeting 83/57. International Monetary Fund. 6 April.

  • Fernandez-Arias, E (2010). International lending of last resort and sovereign debt restructuring. In C.A.P. Braga & G.A. Vinclette (Eds.) , Sovereign debt and the financial crisis: Will this time be different? (pp. 331–353). Washington, DC: World Bank.

  • Fernandez-Arias, E., & Levy-Yeyati, E. (2010). Global financial safety nets: where Do we go from here? Inter-american development bank, working paper No. IDB-WP-231. Available at http://www.iadb.org/en/research-and-data/publication-details,3169.html?pub_id=idb-wp-231. Accessed 30 Nov.

  • Gartzke, E. (1998). Kant we all just get along? Opportunity, willingness, and the origins of the democratic peace. American Journal of Political Science, 41, 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenspan, A. (2007). The age of turbulence: adventures in a new world. New York: Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guitian, M. (1995). Conditionality: past, present, future. Staff Papers - International Monetary Fund, 42, 792–835.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imai, K., King, G., & Lau, O. (2007). Zelig: everyone’s statistical software. Available at http://GKing.harvard.edu/zelig. Accessed 25 Oct 2015.

  • Imai, K., King, G., & Lau, O. (2008). Toward a common framework for statistical analysis and development. Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics, 17(4), 892–913.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (2009). GRA lending toolkit and conditionality: Reform Proposals. Available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2009/031309A.pdf. Accessed 30 Nov 2015.

  • International Monetary Fund (2012a). The IMF’s rapid credit facility: Factsheet. Available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/rcf.htm. Accessed 13 Sept 2012.

  • International Monetary Fund (2012b). The IMF’s flexible credit line: Factsheet. Available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/fcl.htm. Accessed 13 Sept 2012.

  • International Monetary Fund (2012c). IMF Conditionality: Factsheet. Available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/conditio.htm. Accessed 28 Sept 2012.

  • International Monetary Fund (2012d). The IMF’s rapid financing instrument (RFI). Available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/rfi.htm. Accessed 26 Oct 2012.

  • Jeanne, O., & Wyplosz, C. (2001). The international lender of last resort: how large is large enough? NBER Working Paper, 8381.

  • Kaminsky, G.L., & Reinhart, C.M. (1999). The twin crises: the causes of banking and balance-of-payments problems. The American Economic Review, 89, 473–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilby, C. (2013). The political economy of project preparation: an empirical analysis of world bank projects. Journal of Development Economics, 105, 211–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, M., & Santaella, J.A. (1997). Economic determinants of IMF financial arrangements. Journal of Development Economics, 54, 405–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuziemko, I., & Werker, E.D. (2006). How much is a seat on the security council worth? Foreign aid and bribery at the United Nations. Journal of Political Economy, 114, 905–930.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laeven, L., & Fabian V. (2008). Systemic banking crises: a new database. IMF Working Paper, WP/08/224. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2008/wp08224.pdf. Accessed 23 Dec, 2015.

  • Leblang, D. (2003). To devalue or defend? The political economy of exchange rate policy. International Studies Quarterly, 47, 533–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M.G., Jaggers, K., & Gurr, T.R. (2012). Polity IV.

  • Mody, A., & Saravia, D. (2006). Catalysing private capital flows: do IMF programmes work as commitment devices? The Economic Journal, 116, 843–867.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mody, A., & Saravia, D. (2013). The response speed of the international monetary fund. International Finance, 15, 189–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, S., & Shin, H.S. (2006). Catalytic finance: when does it work? Journal of International Economics, 70, 161–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moser, C., & Sturm, J.E. (2011). Review of international organizations. Explaining IMF lending decisions after the cold war, 6, 307–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munk, R. (2010). Exchange stabilization fund loans to sovereign borrowers: 1982-2010. Law and Contemporary Problems, 73, 215–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, S. (2014). Playing favorites: how shared beliefs shape the IMFs lending decisions. International Organization, 68(2), 297–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oatley, T., & Yackee, J. (2004). American interests and IMF lending. International Politics, 41, 415–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prasad, E., Rogoff, K., Wei, S.J., & Kose, M.A. (2003). Effects of financial globalization on developing countries. IMF Working Paper.

  • Rodrik, D., & Velasco, A. (1999). Short-term capital flows. NBER Working Paper, 7364.

  • Sachs, J. (1988). International policy coordination: the case of the developing country debt crisis. In M. Feldstein (Ed.) , International economic cooperation (pp. 233–320). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Sachs, J. (1995). Do we need an international lender of last resort? Frank D. Graham Lecture, Princeton University, April 20.

  • Schwartz, A.J. (2002). Earmarks of a lender of last resort. In C.A.E. Goodhart & G. Illing (Eds.) , Financial crises, contagion, and the lender of last resort (pp. 449–460). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  • Signorino, C.S., & Ritter, J.M. (1999). Tau-b or Not Tau-b: measuring the similarity of foreign policy positions. International Studies Quarterly, 43, 115–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smuc, T., Gamberger, D., Antulov-Fantulin, N., Lucanin, D., & Piskorec, M. (2015). FOC Project. http://lis.irb.hr/foc/data/data.html. Accessed 4 Aug 2015.

  • Stone, R. (2004). The political economy of IMF lending in Africa. American Political Science Review, 98, 577–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, R. (2008). The scope of IMF conditionality. International Organization, 62, 589–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, R. (2011). Controlling institutions: international organizations and the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Thacker, S.C. (1999). The high politics of IMF lending. World Politics, 52, 38–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Truman, E.M. (1996). The mexican peso crisis: implications for international finance (pp. 200–209). Federal Reserve Bulletin. March.

  • Van Houtven, L. (2002). Governance of the IMF: Decision making, institutional oversight, transparency, and accountability. Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vreeland, J. (2003). The IMF and economic development. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vreeland, J. (2007). The international monetary fund: politics of conditional lending. New York: Routeledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zettelmeyer, J. (2000). Can official crisis lending be counterproductive in the short run? Economic Notes, 29, 12–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniel McDowell.

Additional information

I would like to thank J. Lawrence Broz, Benjamin Cohen, Mark Copelovitch, Jeffry Frieden, Randall Henning, Christopher Kilby, Steven Liao, Tom Pepinsky, David Steinberg, Michael Tierney, and participants at the 2014 International Political Economy Society (IPES) conference for their helpful comments on this paper. I would also like to thank the Appleby-Mosher Fund for Research for their generous support of this project.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(ZIP 769 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

McDowell, D. Need for speed: The lending responsiveness of the IMF. Rev Int Organ 12, 39–73 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-015-9240-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-015-9240-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation