Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

International regulation without international government: Improving IO performance through orchestration

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

International organizations (IOs) have been widely criticized as ineffective. Yet scholars and practitioners assessing IO performance frequently focus on traditional modes of governance such as treaties and inter-state dispute-resolution mechanisms. When they observe poor performance, moreover, they often prescribe a strengthening of those same activities. We call this reliance on traditional state-based mechanisms “International Old Governance” (IOG). A better way to understand and improve IO performance is to consider the full range of ways in which IOs can and do operate—including, increasingly, by reaching out to private actors and institutions, collaborating with them, and supporting and shaping their activities. Such actions are helping to develop an intricate global network of public, private and mixed institutions and norms, partially orchestrated by IOs, that we call “Transnational New Governance” (TNG). With proper orchestration by IOs, TNG can ameliorate both “state failure”—the inadequacies of IOG—and “market failure”—the problems that result when the creation and evolution of norm-setting institutions is highly decentralized. Orchestration thus provides a significant way for IOs to improve their regulatory performance. Some IOs already engage actively with private actors and institutions—we provide a range of illustrations, highlighting the activities of the UN Environment Programme (UNEP). Yet there remains a significant “orchestration deficit” that provides real opportunities for IOs. We draw on the lessons of existing IO activities to suggest additional possibilities for improving IO performance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. “TNG” parallels domestic “New Governance” (NG): we draw on the growing NG literature in developing our arguments (Abbott and Snidal 2009a, b; Cashore et al. 2004; Salamon 2002; de Burca and Scott 2006; Trubek and Trubek 2007; Lobel 2004; Ayres and Braithwaite 1992).

  2. Economic globalization was also strong in the pre-1914 period, yet on most measures the late 20th century surge in globalization reached or exceeded previous levels, especially as developing countries and the former Soviet bloc embraced more open economic policies. Information flows are significantly more globalized in the current period, supporting new methods of organizing global production, “whether integrated vertically in global factories or through looser cross-border production networks.” Combined with a reduction in the globalization and mobility of labor, these factors led to the appearance of numerous labor rights, human rights and environmental RSS schemes. Kahler and Lake (2003).

  3. For a full discussion of the Governance Triangle, its nuances and its implicit assumptions, see Abbott and Snidal (2009a, b). Note that RSS schemes range widely in scope and scale. For example, Rugmark organizes the certification of child-labor-free rug production in South Asia, whereas UNGC promotes human rights, labor, environmental and corruption standards across many sectors on a global basis.

  4. The vertex Zones (1, 2 and 3) are dominated by a single actor, the quadrilateral Zones (4, 5 and 6) involve two dominant actors, while Zone 7 involves significant involvement of all three actors.

  5. For examples of domestic New Governance, see Freeman (1997–98); Trubek and Trubek (2007); Holzinger et al. (2006); Coglianese et al. (2003).

  6. The tripartite structure of Zone 7 arrangements such as EITI is reminiscent of—but different from—the tripartite state-worker-employer structure of the ILO. Among other differences, a broader range of stakeholders typically participates in the new institutions, their governance arrangements are more fluid, and as in most RSS schemes, their norms are voluntary and address firms directly.

  7. Adapted from Abbott and Snidal (2009a).

  8. See Mattli and Woods (2009) on the importance of demonstration effects, and Abbott and Snidal (2005) for a discussion for demonstration effects significant to RSS.

  9. Abbott and Snidal (2009a) discusses the difficulty of summarizing these changes, given that RSS schemes involve a range of activities, from the negotiation of standards through their enforcement.

  10. For a fuller analysis of the “competencies” of different actors and RSS schemes, see Abbott and Snidal (2009a).

  11. When IOs are motivated by policy aims, our analysis of orchestration can be viewed as a positive statement regarding what IOs will do (given the right information about policy alternatives); when IOs have alternative goals or do not understand the potential of orchestration, then our analysis is necessarily more normative, suggesting what IOs should do (if they had the “right” goals and information).

  12. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/emas/about/summary_en.htm; http://ec.europa.eu/environment/emas/pdf/com_2008_402_draft.pdf

  13. http://ec.europa.eu/environment/ecolabel/whats_eco/ov_concept_en.htm

  14. For this reason, Arnold and Whitford (2006) suggests that states should mandate the types of internal management systems that IFC, EMAS and ECO call for, rather than leaving them to be imposed as conditions on voluntary programs.

  15. Abbott and Snidal (2009b) applies New Governance theory to the international context.

  16. http://www.sa-intl.org/index.cfm?fuseaction=Page.viewPage&pageId=473

  17. http://www.globalreporting.org/AboutGRI/WhoWeAre/; Dingwerth 2007: 111

  18. http://www.cleanclothes.org/faq/485; http://www.bsci-eu.org/index.php?id=2020

  19. The 1992 UN Conference on Environment and Development, especially Agenda 21, called for engagement with “major groups” in society to achieve sustainable development; they include business, NGOs and labor unions.

  20. http://www.ifoam.org/about_ifoam/status/index.html

  21. http://www.unep.fr/scp/business/dialogue/2008/Oct2008_list_participants.pdf. UNEP expanded its civil society and private sector engagement activities in 2002. See http://www.unep.org/civil_society/PDF_docs/Enhancing_Civil_Society_Engagement_In_UNEP.pdf.

  22. http://www.unep.fr/scp/business/vi/about.htm. UNEP has also described its role in helping to create GRI as that of international catalyst (Dingwerth 2007: 110).

  23. http://www.iisd.ca/mea-l/guestarticle95.html

  24. http://www.unep.fr/scp/gri/history.htm; http://www.unep.fr/scp/business/dialogue/; http://www.b4esummit.com/; http://www.unep.fr/scp/ecolabelling/; http://www.unep.fr/scp/unchaining/. A notable capacity-building success was UNEP support for multi-stakeholder development of the East African Organic Products Standard.

  25. http://www.betterwork.org/public/global. The program grew out of the ILO’s role in monitoring labor standards in Cambodian apparel factories under a bilateral trade agreement with the US.

  26. Commission on Human Rights Resolution 2005/69, 20 April 2005.

  27. “Protect, Respect and Remedy: A Framework for Business and Human Rights,” 7 April 2008, http://www.business-humanrights.org/SpecialRepPortal/Home/ReportstoUNHumanRightsCouncil/2008; Human Rights Council Resolution 8/7, 18 June 2008.

  28. Summit Declaration: Growth and Responsibility in the World Economy, Para. 84, 7 June 2007, http://www.g-8.de/Content/EN/Artikel/__g8-summit/anlagen/2007-06-07-gipfeldokument-wirtschaft-eng,templateId=raw,property=publicationFile.pdf/2007-06-07-gipfeldokument-wirtschaft-eng.pdf.

  29. Endorsements cannot, of course, overcome capacity deficits or structural weaknesses in private schemes. For example, GRI largely limits its activities to promulgating reporting standards; it does not monitor, certify or enforce their use by firms and other actors.

  30. http://www.globalreporting.org/AboutGRI/Funding/; GRI Sustainability Report 2007-08 at 32, http://www.globalreporting.org/NR/rdonlyres/E8B6ED9E-1A29-4154-A6DA-F14E6F71A2C9/2877/SR_FINAL_09_06_with_links.pdf

  31. http://www.unep.fr/scp/gri/; http://www.globalreporting.org/AboutGRI/WhatWeDo/OurHistory

  32. http://www.unpri.org/about/

  33. http://www.unglobalcompact.org/AboutTheGC/; http://www.unglobalcompact.org/docs/about_the_gc/governance_update2008.pdf

  34. http://www.unglobalcompact.org/Issues/Environment/Climate_Change/; http://www.unglobalcompact.org/docs/issues_doc/Environment/CLIMATESTATEMENT_revised_postsummit.pdf; http://www.unglobalcompact.org/docs/news_events/8.1/caring_for_climate.pdf

  35. http://www.unglobalcompact.org/Issues/Environment/CEO_Water_Mandate/; http://www.unglobalcompact.org/docs/news_events/8.1/Ceo_water_mandate.pdf

  36. http://www.unepfi.org/index.html; http://www.unepfi.org/about/background/index.html; http://www.unepfi.org/work_streams/index.html

  37. http://www.toinitiative.org/index.php?id=41; http://www.toinitiative.org/index.php?id=11

  38. http://www.sustainabletourismcriteria.org/

  39. http://www.unep.fr/energy/activities/rsb/; http://www.unep.fr/energy/bioenergy/documents/pdf/VersionZero.pdf

  40. Of course, UNEP has played an active role in developing and implementing treaties and other instruments directed at states.

  41. http://www.unep.org/climateneutral/About/tabid/95/Default.aspx.

  42. Bauer and Biermann cite many of the leading sources from these periods.

  43. Under the ILO model, firms and environmental NGOs would play significant roles in a WEO.

  44. Under some of these proposals, private actors would be allowed significant input into decision-making. See, e.g., Frank Biermann, “The Rationale for a World Environment Organization,” in Bauer and Biermann (2005).

  45. The same decision requested the Executive Director to identify incremental options that could be implemented immediately or in the next UNEP work program.

  46. Another suggestion is a new treaty on sustainable development to set out general objectives, principles, rights and obligations, and establish its own implementing institutions, which would apply across multiple treaty regimes.

  47. http://www.fao.org/docrep/008/a0116t/a0116t01.htm#bm1.1; http://www.msc.org/newsroom/msc-news/archive-2006/leader-in-fishery-certification-and-eco-labelling. FAO and MSC are even more deeply interrelated: the MSC standard was a partial model for the Guidelines, while MSC originally based its standard partially on the FAO Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries, a voluntary instrument that addresses both states and private fisheries stakeholders. See http://www.fao.org/DOCREP/005/v9878e/v9878e00.htm.

  48. These programs provide very modest reputational benefits by promoting their standards to labor organizations, NGOs and other stakeholders who can directly observe firm compliance.

  49. http://www.ungm.org/Info/About.aspx; http://www.ungm.org/Info/Guidelines.aspx

  50. Michael Lipson (2010), in this volume, emphasizes the parallel problem of ambiguity, where actors disagree over how to interpret IO actions.

References

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (1998). Why states act through formal international organizations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 42(1), 3–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (2000). Hard and Soft Law in International Governance. International Organization, 54(3), 421–456.

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (2005). The international standards process: Setting and applying global business norms. In P. Nobel (Ed.), International standards and the law (pp. 106–142). Berne: Staempfli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (2009a). The governance triangle: Regulatory standards, institutions and the shadow of the state. In W. Mattli & N. Woods (Eds.), (pp. 44–88).

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (2009b). Strengthening international regulation through transnational new governance: overcoming the orchestration deficit. Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law, 42(2), 501–578.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andonova, L. B. (2010). Public-Private partnerships for the earth: politics and patterns of hybrid authority in the multilateral system. Global Environmental Politics, 10(2), 25–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andonova, L. B., Betsill, M. M., & Bulkeley, H. (2009). Transnational climate governance. Global Environmental Politics, 9(2), 52–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, R., & Whitford, A. B. (2006). Making environmental self-regulation mandatory. Global Environmental Politics, 6(4):1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ayres, I., & Braithwaite, J. (1992). Responsive regulation: Transcending the deregulation debate. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baccaro, L., & Mele, V. (2010). Pathology of path-dependency? The ILO and the challenge of ‘new governance’. Manuscript. University of Geneva.

  • Bäckstrand, K. (2008). Accountability of networked climate governance: the rise of transnational climate partnerships. Global Environmental Politics, 8(3), 74–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, M., & Finnemore, M. (2004). Rules for the world: International organizations in global politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartley, T. (2007). Institutional emergence in an era of globalization: the rise of transnational private regulation of labor and environmental conditions. The American Journal of Sociology, 113(2), 297–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, S. (2009). The secretariat of the United Nations Environment Programme: tangled up in blue. In Biermann & Siebenhüner (Eds.), (pp.169–202).

  • Bauer, S., & Biermann, F. (2005). The debate on a world environment organization: An introduction. In F. Biermann & S. Bauer (Eds.), A world environment organization: Solution or threat for effective international environ-mental governance? Aldershot (UK): Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berruga, E., & Maurer, P. (2006). Co-chairmen’s summary of the informal consultative process on the institutional framework for the UN’s environmental activities, 27 June 2006, available at http://www.environmentalgovernance.org/cms/wp-content/uploads/reform_docs/GA_informal_plenary.pdf, visited June 8, 2010.

  • Betsill, M. N., & Corell, E. (2001). NGO influence in international environmental negotiations: a framework for analysis. Global Environmental Politics, 1(4), 65–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biermann, F. (2000). The case for a world environment organization. Environment, 42(9), 22–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biermann, F., & Pattberg, P. (2008). Global environmental governance: taking stock, moving forward. Annual Review of Environmental Resources, 33, 277–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biermann, F., & Siebenhüner, B. (2009a). Managers of global change: The influence of international environmental bureaucracies. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biermann, F., & Siebenhüner, B. (2009b). The role and relevance of international bureaucracies: Setting the stage. In Biermann & Siebenhüner (Eds.), 2009a, (pp. 1–14).

  • Biermann, F., & Siebenhüner, B. (2009c). The influence of international bureaucracies in world politics: Findings from the MANUS Research Program. In Biermann & Siebenhüner (Eds.) 2009a, (pp.319–49).

  • Biermann, F., Siebenhüner, B., Bauer, S., Busch, P. O., Campe, S., Dingwerth, K., Grothmann, T., Marschinski, R., & Tarradell, M. (2009). Studying the influence of international bureaucracies: A conceptual framework. In Biermann & Siebenhüner (Eds.), 2009a, (pp. 37–74).

  • Börzel, T. A., & Risse, T. (2005). Public-private partnerships: Effective and legitimate tools of international governance. In E. Grande & L. W. Pauly (Eds.), Reconstituting political authority: Complex sovereignty and the foundations of global governance (pp. 195–216). Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cashore, B., Auld, G., & Newsom, D. (2004). Governing through markets: Forest certification and the emergence of non-state authority. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charnovitz, S. (1996–97). Two centuries of participation: ngos and international governance. Michigan Journal of International Law, 18(1), 183–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coglianese, C., Nash, J., & Olmstead, T. (2003). Performance-based regulation: prospects and limitations in health, safety, and environmental protection. Administrative Law Review, 55(4), 705–729.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corell, E., & Betsill, M. N. (2001). A comparative look at NGO influence in international environmental negotiations: desertification and climate change. Global Environmental Politics, 1(4), 86–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, A. C., Haufler, V., & Porter, T. (Eds.). (1999). Private authority and international affairs. Albany: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. (1999). Can international organizations be democratic?: A skeptic’s view. In I. Shapiro & C. Hacker-Cordon (Eds.), Democracy’s edges (pp. 19–36). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • de Burca, G., & Scott, J. (Eds.). (2006). Law and new governance in the EU and the US. Oxford: Hart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dingwerth, K. (2007). The new transnationalism. Transnational governance and democratic accountability. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorf, M. C., & Sabel, C. F. (1998). A constitution of democratic experimentalism. Columbia Law Review, 98(2), 267–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elsig, M. (2010). The World Trade Organization at work: performance in a member-driven milieu. Review of International Organizations 5(3).

  • Finnemore, M., & Sikkink, K. (1998). International norm dynamics and political change. International Organization., 52(4), 887–917.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, J. (1997–98). Collaborative governance in the administrative state. UCLA Law Review, 45(1), 1–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fung, A., O’Rourke, D., & Sabel, C. (2000). Ratcheting labor standards. World Bank Social Protection Discussion Paper No. 0011.

  • Geoffrey, P. (1992). New ways to make international environmental law. American Journal of International Law, 86(1), 259–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gutner, T., & Thompson, A. (2010). Explaining IO performance: A framework. Review of International Organizations 5(3).

  • Haftel, Y. Z., & Thompson, A. (2006). The independence of international organizations: concept and applications. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(2), 253–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. B., & Biersteker, T. J. (Eds.). (2002). The emergence of private authority in global governance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardenbrook, A. (2007). The equator principles: the private financial sector’s attempt at environmental responsibility. Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law, 40(1), 197–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins, D., Lake, D., Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (Eds.). (2006). Delegation and Agency in International Organizations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Heal, G. (2008). When principles pay: Corporate social responsibility and the bottom line. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holzinger, K., Knill, C., & Schäfer, A. (2006). Rhetoric or reality? new governance in EU environmental policy. European Law Journal, 12(3), 403–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunter, D. B. (2008). Civil society networks and the development of environmental standards at international financial institutions. Chicago Journal of International Law, 8(2), 437–478.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahler, M., & Lake, D. A. (2003). Globalization and governance. In M. Kahler & D. A. Lake (Eds.), Governance in a global economy: Political authority in transition (pp. 1–30). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keck, M. E., & Sikkink, K. (1998). Activists beyond borders: Advocacy networks in international politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipson, M. (2010). Performance under ambiguity: international organization performance in UN peacekeeping. Review of International Organizations 5(3).

  • Lobel, O. (2004). The renew deal: the fall of regulation and the rise of governance in contemporary legal thought. Minnesota Law Review, 89(2), 342–470.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lodefalk, M., & Whalley, J. (2002). Reviewing proposals for a world environment organization. The World Economy, 25(5), 601–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marschinski, R., & Behrle, S. (2009). The world bank: Making the business case for the environment. In Biermann and Siebenhüner (Eds.) 2009, (pp. 101–142).

  • Mattli, W., & Woods, N. (Eds.). (2009). In whose benefit? Explaining regulatory change in global politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meidinger, E. (2007). Beyond Westphalia: Competitive legalization in emerging transnational regulatory systems. In C. Brutsch & D. Lehmkuhl (Eds.), Law and legalization in transnational relations (pp. 121–143). Abingdon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Najam, A. (2005). Neither necessary, nor sufficient: Why organizational tinkering will not improve environmental governance. In F. Biermann & S. Bauer (Eds.), A world environment organization: Solution or threat for effective international environmental governance? Aldershot (UK): Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. J. (2003). Delegation to international organizations: Agency theory and world bank environmental reform. International Organization, 57(2), 241–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Otto, D. (1996). Nongovernmental organizations in the United Nations system: the emerging role of international civil society. Human Rights Quarterly, 18(1), 107–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pattberg, P. (2007). Private institutions, global governance. The new politics of environmental sustainability. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pattberg, P., & Stripple, J. (2008). Beyond the public and private divide: remapping transnational climate governance in the 21st century. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 8(4), 367–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prakash, A., & Potoski, M. (2006). The voluntary environmentalists: Green clubs, ISO 14001, and voluntary regulations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Price, R. (2003). Transnational civil society and advocacy in world politics. World Politics, 55(4), 579–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Risse, T. (2002). Transnational actors and world politics. In W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, & B. A. Simmons (Eds.), Handbook of international relations (pp. 255–274).

  • Risse, T., Ropp, S. C., & Sikkink, K. (1999). The power of human rights: International norms and domestic change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ruggie, J. G. (2004). Reconstructing the global public domain—issues, actors, and practices. European Journal of International Relations, 10(4), 499–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salamon, L. M. (Ed.). (2002). The tools of government: A guide to the new governance. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trubek, D. M., & Trubek, L. G. (2007). New governance and legal regulation: complementarity, rivalry, and transformation. Columbia Journal of European Law, 13, 539–564.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNEP (2000). Voluntary initiatives: Current status, lessons learnt and next steps. Discussion paper based on UNEP multi-stakeholder workshop on voluntary initiatives, 20 September, Paris.

  • UNEP (2009a). Natural allies: Engaging civil society in UNEP’s work. (2d ed.), http://www.unep.org/civil_society/PDF_docs/UNEP-NaturalAllies-June2009.pdf.

  • UNEP (2009b). Decision 25/4: International environmental governance. In Proceedings of the Governing Council/Global Ministerial Environment Forum at its twenty-fifth session, Annex I, Decisions adopted by the Governing Council/Global Ministerial Environment Forum at its twenty-fifth session, UNEP/GC.25/17, 26 February 2009

  • UNEP (2009c). International environmental governance: outcome of the work of the consultative group of ministers or high-level representatives: Note by the Executive Director. UNEP/GCSS.XI/4, 2 December 2009

  • UNEP. (2010a). Decision SS.XI/1, International environmental governance. In Proceedings of the Governing Council/Global Ministerial Environment Forum at its eleventh special session, UNEP/GCSS.XI/11, 3 March 2010

  • UNEP. (2010b). Options for broader reform of international environmental governance: Background paper by the Executive Director. http://environmentalgovernance.org/cms/wp-content/uploads/2010/05/Options-for-Broader-Reform-of-IEG_17May20101.pdf.

  • United Nations (2001). Report of the Secretary-General, Cooperation between the United Nations and all relevant partners, in particular the private sector. UN Doc A/56/323.

  • United Nations (2006). Report of the Secretary-General, Partnerships for Sustainable Development, UN Doc E/CN.17/2006/6.

  • Vaubel, R. (2006). Principal-agent problems in international organizations. Review of International Organizations, 1(2), 125–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vogel, D. (2005). The market for virtue: The potential and limits of corporate social responsibility. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Moltke, K. (2005). Clustering international environmental agreements as an alternative to a world environment organization. In F. Biermann & S. Bauer (Eds.), A world environment organization: Solution or threat for effective international environmental governance? (pp. 175–204). Aldershot (UK): Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weaver, C. (2010). The political paradox of international evaluation: the curious case of the IMF. Review of International Organizations 5(3).

  • World Bank (2004). Sustaining forests: A development strategy, available at http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTFORESTS/Resources/SustainingForests.pdf.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the editors, Tamar Gutner and Alexander Thompson, and the anonymous reviewers for valuable comments on this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Duncan Snidal.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Abbott, K.W., Snidal, D. International regulation without international government: Improving IO performance through orchestration. Rev Int Organ 5, 315–344 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-010-9092-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-010-9092-3

Keywords

JEL codes

Navigation