The Review of International Organizations

, Volume 5, Issue 4, pp 475–496 | Cite as

Enforcing international environmental cooperation: Technological standards can help

Article

Abstract

Market instruments, such as emissions trading or pollution taxes, are less costly than “command and control” regulation. Yet technological standards are common in international environmental agreements and now figure prominently among proposals to mitigate global warming. I show that technological standards can be combined with market instruments to create collective enforcement power. They allow states to internationally enforce technology installation, so the payoff to free riding decreases. A notable feature of the argument is that technological standards and market instruments are complements, while previous research has treated them as substitutes. Empirically, technological standards are most valuable if international cooperation is difficult to enforce and the rate of technological change in concerned industries is slow.

Keywords

Environmental policy International cooperation Technological standards Institutional design Game theory 

JEL Codes

C72 F53 Q58 

References

  1. Aidt, T. S. (1998). Political internalization of economic externalities and environmental policy. Journal of Public Economics, 69(1), 1–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Asheim, G. B., Froyn, C. B., Hovi, J., & Menz, F. C. (2006). Regional versus global cooperation for climate control. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 51(1), 93–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Ausubel, J. H., & Victor, D. G. (1992). Verification of international environmental agreements. Annual Review of Energy and the Environment, 17, 1–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Axelrod, R., & Keohane R. O. (1985). Achieving cooperation under anarchy: Strategies and institutions. World Politics, 38(1), 226–254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Barrett, S. (1994). Self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Oxford Economic Papers, 46(Supplement), 878–894.Google Scholar
  6. Barrett, S. (1999). A theory of full international cooperation. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 11(4), 519–541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Barrett, S. (2003). Environment and statecraft: The strategy of environmental treaty-making. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  8. Barrett S. (2006). Climate treaties and ’breakthrough’ technologies. American Economic Review, 96(2), 22–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Barrett S. (2008). Climate treaties and the imperative of enforcement. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 24(2), 239–258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Barrett S. (2009). The coming global climate-technology revolution. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(2), 53–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Baumol, W. J., & Oates, W. E. (1988). The theory of environmental policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  12. Bechtel, M. M., & Tosun, J. (2009). Changing economic openness for policy convergence: When can trade agreements induce convergence of environmental regulation? International Studies Quarterly, 53(4), 931–953.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Biermann, F., & Brohm, R. (2005). Implementing the Kyoto Protocol without the U.S.A.: The strategic role of energy tax adjustments at the border. Climate Policy, 4(3), 289–302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1975). Polluters’ profits and political response: Direct controls versus taxes. American Economic Review, 65(1), 139–147.Google Scholar
  15. Carraro, C., & Siniscalco, D. (1993). Strategies for the international protection of the environment. Journal of Public Economics, 52(3), 309–328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Dai, X. (2002). Information systems in treaty regimes. World Politics, 54(4), 405–436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Desombre, E. R. (1995). Baptists and bootleggers for the environment: The origins of united states unilateral sanctions. Journal of Environment and Development, 4(1), 53–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Downs, G. W., Rocke, D. M., & Barsoon, P. N. (1996). Is the good news about compliance good news about cooperation? International Organization, 50(3), 379–406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Esty, D. C. (2001). Bridging the trade-environment divide. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(3), 113–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Fearon, J. D. (1998). Bargaining, enforcement, and international cooperation. International Organization, 52(2), 269–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Fernandez, R., & Portes, J. (1998). Returns to regionalism: An analysis of nontraditional gains from regional trade agreements. World Bank Economic Review, 12(2), 197–220.Google Scholar
  22. Fischer, C., & Newell R. G. (2008). Environmental and technology policies for climate mitigation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 55(2), 142–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Gilligan, M. J. (2004). Is there a broader-deeper trade-off in international multilateral agreements? International Organization, 58(3), 459–484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Goldsmith, J. L., & Posner, E. A. (2005). The limits of international law. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  25. Greene O. (1998). Implementation review and the Baltic Sea regime. In: D. G. Victor, K. Raustiala, E. B. Skolnikoff (Eds.), The implementation and effectiveness of international environmental commitments: Theory and practice. Cambridge: MIT.Google Scholar
  26. Keohane, N. O., Revesz, R. L., & Stavins, R. N. (1998). The choice of regulatory instruments in environmental policy. Harvard Environmental Law Review, 22(2), 313–367.Google Scholar
  27. Keohane, R. O. (1984). After Hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Kono, D. Y. (2006). Optimal obfuscation: Democracy and trade policy transparency. American Political Science Review, 100(3), 369–384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International Organization 55(4), 761–799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Kruger, J., Oates, W. E., & Pizer, W. A. (2007). Decentralization in the E.U. Emissions Trading Scheme and lessons for global policy. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1(1), 112–133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Kverndokk, S., Rosendahl, K. E., & Rutherford, T. F. (2004). Climate policies and induced technological change: Which to choose, the carrot or the stick? Environmental and Resource Economics, 27(1), 21–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Lackner, K. S. (2003). A guide to C.O.2 sequestration. Science, 300, 1677–1678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Maloney, M. T., & McCormick, R. E. (1982). A positive theory of environmental quality regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 25(1), 99–123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Meckling, J. O., & Chung, G. Y. (2009). Sectoral approaches to international climate policy: A typology and political analysis, Belfer Center. Discussion Paper 2009-02, Energy Technology Innovation Policy.Google Scholar
  35. Milner, H. V., & Kubota, K. (2005). Why the move to free trade? democracy and trade policy in the developing countries. International Organization, 59(1), 107–143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Mitchell, R. B. (1994). Regime design matters: Intentional oil pollution and treaty compliance. International Organization, 48(3), 425–458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Mitchell, R. B., & Keilbach, P. M. (2001). Situation structure and institutional design: Reciprocity, coercion, and exchange. International Organization, 55(4), 891–917.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Murdoch, J. C., Sandler, T., & Sargent, K. (1997). A tale of two collectives: Sulphur versus nitrogen oxides emission reduction in Europe. Economica, 64(254), 281–301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Neumayer, E. (2001). Greening trade and investment: Environmental protection without protectionism. London: Earthscan.Google Scholar
  40. Oates, W. E. (1999). An essay on fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 1120–1149.Google Scholar
  41. Sawa, A. (2008). A sectoral approach as an option for a post-Kyoto framework?. Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements Discussion Paper 08-23. December 2008.Google Scholar
  42. Skjaerseth, J. B. (1998). The making and implementation of North Sea commitments: The politics of environmental participation. In: D. G. Victor, K. Raustiala, E. B. Skolnikoff (Eds.), The implementation and effectiveness of international environmental commitments: theory and practice. Cambridge: MIT.Google Scholar
  43. Stavins, R. N. (2003). Experience with market-based environmental policy instruments. In: K. G. Mäler, J. R. Vincent (Eds.), Handbook of environmental economics: Economywide and international environmental issues (Vol 1). Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  44. Stern, N. (2006). The economics of climate change: The stern review. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  45. Topkis, D. M. (1998). Supermodularity and complementarity. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  46. Vogel, D. (2000). Environmental regulation and economic integration. Journal of International Economic Law, 3(2), 265–279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Weitzman, M. L. (1974). Prices vs. quantities. Review of Economic Studies, 4(4), 477–491.Google Scholar
  48. Weyant, J. P., & Olavson, T. (1999). Issues in modeling induced technological change in energy, environmental, and climate policy. Environmental Modeling and Assessment, 4(2-3), 67–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science + Business Media, LLC 2010

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Political ScienceColumbia UniversityNew YorkUSA

Personalised recommendations