Skip to main content
Log in

A Global Picture of the Gamma-Ricker Map: A Flexible Discrete-Time Model with Factors of Positive and Negative Density Dependence

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Bulletin of Mathematical Biology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The gamma-Ricker model is one of the more flexible and general discrete-time population models. It is defined on the basis of the Ricker model, introducing an additional parameter \(\gamma >0\). For some values of this parameter (\(\gamma \le 1)\), population is overcompensatory, and the introduction of an additional parameter gives more flexibility to fit the stock–recruitment curve to field data. For other parameter values (\(\gamma >1\)), the gamma-Ricker model represents populations whose per-capita growth rate combines both negative density dependence and positive density dependence. The former can lead to overcompensation and dynamic instability, and the latter can lead to a strong Allee effect. We study the impact of the cooperation factor in the dynamics and provide rigorous conditions under which increasing the Allee effect strength stabilizes or destabilizes population dynamics, promotes or prevents population extinction, and increases or decreases population size. Our theoretical results also include new global stability criteria and a description of the possible bifurcations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alves MT, Hilker FM (2017) Hunting cooperation and Allee effects in predators. J Theor Biol 419:13–22

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Asmussen MA (1979) Density-dependent selection II. The Allee effect. Am Nat 114(6):796–809

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Avilés L (1999) Cooperation and non-linear dynamics: an ecological perspective on the evolution of sociality. Evol Ecol Res 1(4):459–477

    Google Scholar 

  • Berec L (2010) Impacts of foraging facilitation among predators on predator-prey dynamics. Bull Math Biol 72(1):94–121

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Beverton R, Holt S (1957) On the dynamics of exploited fish populations. Fish Investig Ser 2(19):1–533

    Google Scholar 

  • Cid B, Hilker FM, Liz E (2014) Harvest timing and its population dynamic consequences in a discrete single-species model. Math Biosci 248:78–87

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Clark CW (2010) Mathematical bioeconomics: the mathematics of conservation, vol 91. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Courchamp F, Berec L, Gascoigne J (2008) Allee effects in ecology and conservation. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cushing D (1971) The dependence of recruitment on parent stock in different groups of fishes. J Conseil 33(3):340–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • El-Morshedy HA, Jiménez-López V (2008) Global attractors for difference equations dominated by one-dimensional maps. J Differ Equ Appl 14(4):391–410

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Eskola HT, Geritz SA (2007) On the mechanistic derivation of various discrete-time population models. Bull Math Biol 69(1):329–346

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Eskola HT, Parvinen K (2007) On the mechanistic underpinning of discrete-time population models with Allee effect. Theor Popul Biol 72(1):41–51

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hilker FM (2010) Population collapse to extinction: the catastrophic combination of parasitism and Allee effect. J Biol Dyn 4(1):86–101

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hilker FM, Paliaga M, Venturino E (2017) Diseased social predators. Bull Math Biol 79(10):2175–2196

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Iles T (1994) A review of stock–recruitment relationships with reference to flatfish populations. Neth J Sea Res 32(3–4):399–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kot M (2001) Elements of mathematical ecology. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Liz E (2010) Complex dynamics of survival and extinction in simple population models with harvesting. Theor Ecol 3(4):209–221

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Liz E, Ruiz-Herrera A (2015) Delayed population models with Allee effects and exploitation. Math Biosci Eng 12:83–97

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Quinn TJ, Deriso RB (1999) Quantitative fish dynamics. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Reish R, Deriso R, Ruppert D, Carroll R (1985) An investigation of the population dynamics of Atlantic Menhaden (Brevoortia tyrannus). Can J Fish Aquat Sci 42(S1):147–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricker WE (1954) Stock and recruitment. J Fish Board Can 11(5):559–623

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheuring I (1999) Allee effect increases the dynamical stability of populations. J Theor Biol 199(4):407–414

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Schreiber SJ (2001) Chaos and population disappearances in simple ecological models. J Math Biol 42(3):239–260

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Schreiber SJ (2003) Allee effects, extinctions, and chaotic transients in simple population models. Theor Popul Biol 64:201–209

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Wiggins S (1990) Introduction to applied nonlinear dynamical systems and chaos. Texts in applied mathematics, vol 2. Springer, New York

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng J, Kruse GH (2003) Stock–recruitment relationships for three major Alaskan crab stocks. Fish Res 65(1):103–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng J, Murphy M, Kruse G (1995) A length-based population model and stock–recruitment relationships for red king crab, Paralithodes camtschaticus, in Bristol Bay, Alaska. Can J Fish Aquat Sci 52(6):1229–1246

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks sincerely Prof. Frank Hilker and two reviewers of a previous version of this paper. They devoted much of their valuable time to review this paper, and their insightful critique greatly helped to improve it. This research has been supported by the Spanish Government and FEDER, under Grant MTM2013-43404-P.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eduardo Liz.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 2

Computing the Schwarzian derivative of f and simplifying, we get

$$\begin{aligned} (Sf)(x)=\frac{-q(x)}{2x^2(\gamma -\delta x)^2},\quad \forall \; x\ne \gamma /\delta , \end{aligned}$$
(8)

where

$$\begin{aligned} q(x)=\delta ^4x^4-4\gamma \delta ^3x^3+6\gamma ^2\delta ^2x^2-4(\gamma ^3-\gamma )\delta x+\gamma ^4-\gamma ^2. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(q''(x)=12\delta ^2(\gamma -\delta x)^2\), it follows that q is convex. On the other hand, equation \(q'(x)=0\) has a unique real root \(x_0=(\gamma -\gamma ^{1/3})/\delta \), and

$$\begin{aligned} m=q(x_0)=3\gamma \left( \gamma -\gamma ^{1/3}\right) \end{aligned}$$

is a global minimum of q.

It is clear that \(m>0\) if \(\gamma >1\), and therefore, \(q(x)>0\) for all \(x\in {\mathbb {R}}\). If \(\gamma =1\), then \(x_0=m=0\), and hence, \(q(x)>0\) for all \(x>0\). In both cases, it follows from (8) that \((Sf)(x)<0\) for all \(x\in (0,\infty ), x\ne \gamma /\delta .\)

If \(0<\gamma <1\), then q(x) has two real roots \(x_1,x_2\), with \(x_1<0<x_2\). Moreover, \(q(x)>0\) for all \(x>x_2\). Since \(q(\gamma /\delta )=3\gamma ^2>0\), it follows that \(\gamma /\delta >x_2\), and therefore, \(q(x)>0\) for all \(x>\gamma /\delta \). Again (8) ensures that \((Sf)(x)<0\) for all \(x\in (\gamma /\delta ,\infty )\). \(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 1

We need two auxiliary results that we include here for completeness of the proof. The first one is a consequence of Corollary 2.10 in El-Morshedy and Jiménez-López (2008):

Proposition 5

Let \(f:(0,\infty )\rightarrow (0,\infty )\) be a \({\mathcal {C}}^3\) map with a unique fixed point p and a unique critical point c, which is a local maximum. If \(-1\le f'(p)<1\) and \((Sf)(x)<0\) for all \(x\in (c,\infty )\), then p is globally asymptotically stable.

The second one is taken from Proposition 1 in Liz and Ruiz-Herrera (2015):

Proposition 6

Consider the difference equation

$$\begin{aligned} x_{n+1}=f(x_n), \end{aligned}$$

where f satisfies the following conditions:

  1. (H1)

    \(f:[0,\infty )\rightarrow [0,\infty )\) is a \({\mathcal {C}}^1\)-unimodal map, with a unique critical point \(c>0\), such that \(f'(x)>0\) for all \(x\in (0,c)\) and \(f'(x)<0\) for all \(x\in (c,\infty )\).

  2. (H2)

    \(f(0)=f'(0)=0\), and \(\lim _{x\rightarrow \infty }f(x)=0\).

  3. (H3)

    f has three fixed points \(0<x_1<x_2\), so that \(f(x)<x\) for all \(x\in (0,x_1)\cup (x_2,\infty )\) and \(f(x)>x\) for all \(x\in (x_1,x_2)\).

  4. (H4)

    f is three times differentiable, and \((Sf)(x)<0\) whenever \(f'(x)\ne 0\).

If \(f^2(c)>x_1\) and \(f'(x_2)\ge -1\), then \(x_2\) is asymptotically stable and its immediate basin of attraction is \((x_1,f^{-1}(x_1)\).

We proceed with the proof of Theorem 1 (A). First, we observe that condition (6) is equivalent to \(f'(p)\ge -1\). Indeed,

$$\begin{aligned} f'(p)= \beta p^{\gamma -1}e^{-\delta p} (\gamma -\delta p)=\frac{f(p)}{p} (\gamma -\delta p)=\gamma -\delta p. \end{aligned}$$

Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} f'(p)\ge -1\Longleftrightarrow p\le \frac{\gamma +1}{\delta } \Longleftrightarrow f\left( \frac{\gamma +1}{\delta } \right) \le \frac{\gamma +1}{\delta }. \end{aligned}$$

It is clear that the last inequality is equivalent to (6).

Now, the result follows easily from Propositions 1, 2 and 5. Notice that the inequality \(f'(p)<1\) always holds because

$$\begin{aligned} f'(p)=\gamma -\delta p<1 \Longleftrightarrow \delta p>\gamma -1. \end{aligned}$$

The last inequality trivially holds because \(\gamma -1\le 0\).

If (6) does not hold, then \(f'(p)<-1\), and therefore, p is unstable.

Fig. 5
figure 5

(Color Figure Online) Graph of the map \(\beta =T_{\delta }(\gamma )\) showing the stability switches for the largest positive equilibrium of (1). a \(T_{\delta }\) is decreasing for \(\delta =0.1<e^{-2}\), b \(T_{\delta }\) is unimodal for \(\delta =1>e^{-2}\)

The proof of Theorem 1 (B) follows from Proposition 6. Propositions 1 and 2 ensure that assumptions (H1)–(H4) hold.

Finally, the convergence to the equilibrium p is eventually monotone if and only if \(f'(p)\ge 0\), which is equivalent to say that \(f(c)\le c\) for the unique critical point \(c=\gamma /\delta \) of f. It is clear that condition \(f(\gamma /\delta )\le \gamma /\delta \) is equivalent to (7). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

The equilibrium is asymptotically stable if \(\beta \le T_{\delta }(\gamma )\). It is easily seen that \(T_{\delta }(0)=e/\delta \) and \(\lim _{x\rightarrow \infty }T_{\delta }(x)=0\). Moreover, \(T_{\delta }'(x)=0\) if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} (1+x)e^{-2/(1+x)}=\delta . \end{aligned}$$
(9)

It is clear that Eq. (9) has a unique positive solution \({\bar{\gamma }}\) if and only if \(\delta >e^{-2}\).

Thus, if \(\delta \le e^{-2}\) then \(T_{\delta }\) is decreasing on \((0,\infty )\), and therefore, increasing \(\gamma \) is destabilizing if \(\beta <e/\delta \), and the fixed point p is unstable for all values of \(\gamma >0\) if \(\beta \ge e/\delta \). See Fig. 5a.

If \(\delta >e^{-2}\), then \(T_{\delta }\) attains a local maximum at \({\bar{\gamma }}>0\). Thus, there are three possibilities (see Fig. 5b):

  • If \(\beta \le e/\delta \), the increasing \(\gamma \) is destabilizing.

  • If \(e/\delta<\beta <T_{\delta }(\gamma )\), then there are two stability switches.

  • If \(\beta >T_{\delta }(\gamma )\), then p is unstable for all \(\gamma >0\).

A singular case is \(\beta =T_{\delta }(\gamma )\), for which p is only asymptotically stable if \(\gamma ={\bar{\gamma }}\).

Proof of Proposition 4

The proof of Proposition 4 is very similar to the proof of Proposition 3, using the map \(G_{\delta }\) that defines the extinction boundary:

$$\begin{aligned} G_{\delta }(x):=e^{x-1}\left( \frac{x-1}{\delta }\right) ^{1-x}=\left( \frac{\delta e}{x-1}\right) ^{x-1},\quad x>1. \end{aligned}$$

In this case, \(G_{\delta }\) is unimodal, with a global maximum \(G_{\delta }(1+\delta )=e^{\delta }\). Moreover, \(\lim _{x\rightarrow 1^+}G_{\delta }(x)=1, \lim _{x\rightarrow \infty }G_{\delta }(x)=0.\) See Fig. 6. We leave the details to the reader.

Fig. 6
figure 6

(Color Figure Online) Graph of the map \(\beta =G_{\delta }(\gamma )\) showing the survival/extinction switches for (1)

Proof of Theorem 2

The equation that defines a positive equilibrium of (1) is \(\beta p^{\gamma -1}e^{-\delta p}=1\), or, equivalently, \(p^{1-\gamma }e^{\delta p}-\beta =0\). For a fixed value of \(\beta >0\), define the map

$$\begin{aligned} F(p,\gamma ):=p^{1-\gamma }e^{\delta p}-\beta ,\quad p>0,\gamma >0. \end{aligned}$$

By the implicit function theorem, equation \(F(p,\gamma )=0\) defines a function \(p=p(\gamma )\) if \(\partial F/\partial p\ne 0\). By Proposition 4, we know that \(p(\gamma )\) exists for \(\gamma \in (0,\infty )\) if \(\beta \ge e^{\delta }\), and otherwise, \(p(\gamma )\) exists in two open intervals \((0,\gamma _1], [\gamma _2,\infty )\), with \(0<1\le \gamma _1<\gamma _2\).

Moreover, we can compute

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p}{\partial \gamma }=\frac{-\partial F/\partial \gamma }{\partial F/\partial p}=\frac{p \ln (p)}{1-\gamma +\delta p}. \end{aligned}$$

First we show that the denominator is always positive. Indeed, if \(\gamma \le 1\), then \(1-\gamma +\delta p\ge \delta p>0\). If \(\gamma >1\), then it is clear that the largest equilibrium point p satisfies \(p>p^*\), where \(p^*\) is the fixed point at which \(f'(p^*)=1\). Now, it is easy to check that \(p^*=(\gamma -1)/\delta \), and therefore,

$$\begin{aligned} p>\frac{\gamma -1}{\delta }\Longrightarrow 1-\gamma +\delta p>0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, \(\partial p/\partial \gamma >0\) if \(p>1\), and \(\partial p/\partial \gamma <0\) if \(p<1\).

Now, if \(\gamma \le 1\), then it is clear that \(p=1\) if and only if \(\beta =e^{\delta }\). Moreover, since \(f(x)>x\) for \(x<p\) and \(f(x)<x\) for \(x>p\), it follows that \(p>1\) if \(\beta >e^{\delta }\), and \(p<1\) if \(\beta <e^{\delta }\).

If \(\gamma >1\) and \(\beta >e^{\delta }\), a simple graphical analysis also shows that \(p>1\). Hence, \(p(\gamma )\) is an increasing function of \(\gamma \) for \(\gamma \in (0,\infty )\) if \(\beta >e^{\delta }\).

If \(\gamma >1\) and \(\beta <e^{\delta }\), then two extinction switches occur at \(\gamma _1, \gamma _2\), with \(1\le \gamma _1<\gamma _2\). Moreover, since \(\gamma _1<1+\delta <\gamma _2\), we get that \(p(\gamma _1)=(\gamma _1-1)/\delta<1<(\gamma _2-1)/\delta =p(\gamma _2)\). Thus, \(p(\gamma )\) is a decreasing function of \(\gamma \) in \((0,\gamma _1)\) and an increasing function of \(\gamma \) in \((\gamma _2,\infty )\).

Finally, if \(\beta =e^{\delta }\), then \(x=1\) is an equilibrium of (1) for all \(\gamma >0\). Moreover, \(p=1\) is the largest positive equilibrium if \(\gamma \le 1+\delta \); for \(\gamma > 1+\delta , x=1\) is unstable, and the largest positive equilibrium is \(p>1\). Thus, \(p(\gamma )\) is an increasing function of \(\gamma \) in \((1+\delta ,\infty )\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liz, E. A Global Picture of the Gamma-Ricker Map: A Flexible Discrete-Time Model with Factors of Positive and Negative Density Dependence. Bull Math Biol 80, 417–434 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11538-017-0382-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11538-017-0382-2

Keywords

Navigation