Skip to main content
Log in

Working Out the Willingness to Accept and Willingness to Pay Gap Using Economics, Psychology, and Happiness Approaches to Valuation

  • Published:
Applied Research in Quality of Life Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The gap between willingness to accept and willingness to pay is an outcome of incomplete valuation procedure. The solution then is a complete valuation procedure. One approach presented in this paper focuses on the income and substitution effects as the missing items to the valuation procedure. Another approach deals with the hedonic contents of the income, the good, and the setting of the good as the missing items to the valuation procedure. This paper submits a third approach that uses (evaluative) happiness as a proxy of utility while taking account of the hallmarks of the other two valuation procedures: the setting of the good under consideration and the income and substitution effects.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Kahneman and Tversky (1979) and Thaler (1980) assume a “utility” function with an asymmetric sigmoid form. They examine psychological utility when a good is given to or taken away from a person. Their findings indicate that U Y is not constant when money is accepted or it is paid. To verify, hold psychological utility constant across for the alternative states of acceptance or payment of money then check out the slopes. Notice that U Y for a gain of money (i.e., WTA) is less than U Y for a loss of an equal amount of money (i.e., WTP).

  2. The “setting” is a specific type of endowment. The “endowment effect,” on the other hand, is associated with ownership, possession, entitlement, or claim. The “reference effect” is contingent to an endowment. Studies that look into the endowment effect draw attention to the individual’s perception of the setting in explaining the WTA-WTP gap and not on the income and/or the good itself.

  3. WTP became the choice of valuation over WTA on the presumption that WTA is a “flawed” procedure. See also Mitchell and Carson (1999) on using WTP. Knetsch (1990) and Gregory and Brown (1999) note that using WTP when WTA is appropriate implies two things: first, the good is undervalued; and, second, allocative efficiency is effectively abandoned.

  4. The paper does not discuss the debates concerning the measurement of SWB itself. Readers may wish to check Andrews and Robinson (1991) for a review of measures. Psychology recognizes the reliability and validity of SWB measures, but economics is more hesitant to do so. Frey and Stutzer (2002), Frey (2008), Krueger and Schkade (2008), and Oswald and Wu (2010) are recent papers in economics that accept the reliability and validity of SWB measures. A related issue with SWB concerns its cardinality. Psychology, in this case, takes the cardinality of SWB for granted, but economics is hesitant to do so. Ng (1997, 2003), and van Praag and Ferrer-i-Carbonell (2008), among others, treat SWB as a cardinal measure. The mounting evidence not only from psychology but also from the biological and related sciences suggests that SWB measures are viable proxies for utility (c.f., Kahneman and Sugden 2005; Di Tella and MacCulloch 2006).

  5. The effect of Z or that of both Y and Z on another external variable like health can be examined as well. In such case, the utility function takes the form, respectively, U = F[[Y(Z), Z(Y)] + W(Z)] or U = F[[Y(Z), Z(Y)] + W(Y, Z)], where W is the “health” function.

  6. An important issue here is whether the fickleness, even fleeting, nature of emotions bring instability in the valuation procedure. If so, the results are deemed spurious. It is not straightforward to what extent Eq. 2 is resolved with Eq. 4 since there are no real indirect income effects. In addition, other aspects like personality are excluded in the consideration (see, e.g., Georgantzís and Navarro-Martinez 2010; Boyce and Wood 2011; Boyce et al. 2013).

  7. Putting the economics and psychology of valuation together obtains a utility function of the form U = H[Y(Z), Z(Y), E(Y, Z), Q(Z)], where Y and Z are assumed endogenous to each other and the three elements of hedonic content are assumed not trivial. Thus, \( \frac{\partial U/\partial Z}{\partial U/\partial Y}=\frac{H_Z+{H}_Y\frac{ dY}{ dZ}+{H}_Z\frac{ dQ}{ dZ}+{H}_E\frac{\partial E}{\partial Z}+{H}_E\frac{\partial E}{\partial Y}\kern.2em \frac{ dY}{ dZ}}{H_Y+{H}_Z+{H}_E\frac{\partial E}{\partial Y}+{H}_E\frac{\partial E}{\partial Z}\kern.2em \frac{ dZ}{ dY}} \) is the valuation of Z. Given the nature of emotion, \( \left({H}_E\frac{\partial E}{\partial Z}+{H}_E\frac{\partial E}{\partial Y}\frac{ dY}{ dZ}\right) \) and \( \left({H}_E\frac{\partial E}{\partial Y}+{H}_E\frac{\partial E}{\partial Z}\frac{ dZ}{ dY}\right) \) might introduce instability and volatility to the valuation procedure.

  8. Stated or declared SWB is some transformation of the underlying well-being (SWB*) provided the former is highly correlated with the latter. Algebraically, SWB = h[U(·)], where U(·) is SWB*. It implies SWB 2 > SWB 1 iff U 2 (·) > U 1 (·). For various reasons (e.g., cognitive biases, cultural predispositions, etc.), SWB* − SWB = e, where e is an error term. Presumably, e does not come from a change in the valence of life circumstances but rather from the errors of “interpretation. If e ~ N(0, σ e 2 ), then a sufficiently large set of data compensates for the discrepancy to approximate SWB ≡ SWB*. That SWB ↔ SWB* is possible when individual are more informed about their situation and well-being.

  9. The extant literature discusses three types of happiness: emotional happiness, evaluative (or judgment) happiness, and eudaimonic happiness. Part of the problem in using “happiness” is confusion on the type of happiness used in the analysis. This paper suggests that evaluative happiness is the more appropriate proxy for subjective well-being in the valuation procedure.

  10. Frey and Stutzer (2010) argue that cardinality is not required to perform the SWB approach to valuation. Studies in psychology assume that self-reports are cardinal and interpersonally comparable but applications in economics assume that self-reports are ordinal and interpersonally comparable.

  11. Emotion is excluded in the expression because it can lead to exaggerated valuations. This problem is associated with focusing illusion, immune neglect, focalism, miswanting, projection bias, or visceral effect (Gilbert et al. 1998; Schkade and Kahneman 1998; Loewenstein 1996; Wilson et al. 2000; Loewenstein et al. 2003), other hedonic matters like existence value (Boyce et al. 1992; Kahneman and Knetsch 1992), and other biases (Gilovich et al. 2002).

  12. Suppose H Y > 0 and \( {H}_Z\frac{ dQ}{ dZ}>0 \). The receipt of money means \( \left({H}_{Y_{WTA}}>0\right)\downarrow \) and \( \left({H}_Z\frac{ dZ}{ dY}\right)>0\uparrow \), whereas the payment of money means \( \left({H}_{Y_{WTP}}>0\right)\uparrow \) and \( \left({H}_Z\frac{ dZ}{ dY}\right)<0\downarrow \). Let \( \frac{ dZ}{ dY}>0 \). The indirect income effect depends on H Z (Eqs. 3a and 3b). Notice that \( \frac{H_Z+{H}_Z\frac{ dQ}{ dZ}}{H_{Y_{WTA}}+{H}_Z\frac{ dZ}{ dY}}=\frac{H_Z+{H}_Z\frac{ dQ}{ dZ}}{H_{Y_{WTP}}+{H}_Z\frac{ dZ}{ dY}} \) resolves Eq. 2. The outcome is the same if \( \frac{ dZ}{ dY}<0 \).

References

  • Amiran, E., & Hagen, D. (2003). Willingness to pay and willingness to accept: how much can they differ? Comment. American Economic Review, 93(1), 458–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, F., & Robinson, J. (1991). Measures of subjective well-being. In J. Robinson, P. Shaver, & L. Wrightsman (Eds.), Measures of personality and social psychological attitudes (pp. 61–114). San Diego: Academic Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Boyce, C., & Wood, A. (2011). Personality and marginal utility of income: personality interacts with increases in household income to determine life satisfaction. Journal of Economic Psychology, 78(1–2), 183–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyce, R., Brown, T., McClelland, G., Peterson, G., & Schulze, W. (1992). An experimental examination of intrinsic values as a source of the WTA-WTP disparity. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1366–1373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyce, C., Wood, A., & Powdthavee, N. (2013). Is personality fixed? Personality changes as much as “variable” economic factors and more strongly predicts changes in life satisfaction. Social Indicators Research, 111(1), 287–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Champ, P., Bishop, R., Brown, T., & McCollum, D. (1997). Using donation mechanisms to value non-use benefits from public goods. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 33(2), 151–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coursey, D., Hovis, J., & Schulze. (1987). The disparity between willingness to accept and willingness to pay measures of value. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(3), 679–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cropper, M., & Oates, W. (1992). Environmental economics: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 30(2), 675–740.

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R. & MacCulloch (2006). Some uses of happiness data in economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(1), 25–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R., MacCulloch, R., & Oswald, A. (2001). Preferences of inflation and unemployment: evidence from surveys of happiness. American Economic Review, 91(1), 335–341.

  • Dolan, P., Fujiwara, D., & Metcalfe, R. (2011). A step towards valuing utility the marginal and cardinal way, Discussion Paper No. 1602, Center for Economic Progress, London School of Economics.

  • Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A., & van Praag, B. (2002). The subjective costs of health losses due to chronic diseases: an alternative model for monetary appraisal. Health Economics, 11(8), 709–722.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. (1985). Choosing the right pond: Human behavior and the quest for status. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. (2008). Happiness: A revolution in economics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2002). Happiness and economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., Luechinger, S., & Stutzer, A. (2010). The life satisfaction approach to environmental valuation. Annual Review of Resource Economics, 2010(1), 139–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgantzís, N., & Navarro-Martinez, D. (2010). Understanding the WTA–WTP gap: attitudes, feelings, uncertainty and personality. Journal of Economic Psychology, 31(6), 895–907.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, D., Pinel, E., Wilson, T., Blumberg, S., & Wheatley, T. (1998). Immune neglect: a source of durability bias in affective forecasting. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 75(3), 617–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilovich, T., Griffen, D., & Kahneman, D. (2002). Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gregory, T., & Brown, R. (1999). Why the WTA-WTP disparity matters. Ecological Economics, 28(3), 323–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann, M. (1991). The willingness to pay and willingness to accept: how much can they differ? American Economic Review, 81(3), 635–647.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harowitz, J., & McConnell, K. (2002). A review of the WTA/WTP studies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 44(3), 426–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, A. (1941). Consumer’s surplus and the compensating variation. Review of Economic Studies, 8(2), 117–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. (1939). Value and Capital: An inquiry into some fundamental principles of economic theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. (1941). The rehabilitation of consumer surplus. Review of Economic Studies, 8(2), 108–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Knetsch, J. (1992). Valuing public goods: the purchase of moral satisfaction. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 22(1), 57–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Sugden, R. (2005). Experienced utility as a standard for policy evaluation. Environmental & Resource Economics, 32(1), 161–181.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decisions under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., & Thaler, R. (1990). Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase Theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 1325–1348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., & Thaler, R. (1991). Anomalies: the endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 193–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knetsch, J. (1990). Environmental policy implications of disparities between willingness to pay and compensation demanded for measures of values. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 18(3), 227–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knetsch, J., & Wong, W.-K. (2009). The endowment effect and the reference state: evidence and manipulations. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 71(2), 407–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Köszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 1133–1165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A., & Schkade, D. (2008). The reliability of subjective well-being measures. Journal of Public Economics, 92(8–9), 1833–1845.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krutilla, J. (1967). Conservation reconsidered. American Economic Review, 57(4), 777–786.

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R., Nickell, S., & Mayraz, G. (2008). The marginal utility of income. Journal of Public Economics, 92(8–9), 1846–1857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, C.-H., Chuang, S.-C., Kao, D., & Kung, C.-Y. (2006). The role of emotions in the endowment effect. Journal of Economic Psychology, 27(4), 589–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List, J. (2003). Does market experience eliminate market anomalies? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 41–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. (1996). Out of control: visceral influences on behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65(3), 272–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1993). Preferences for sequences of outcomes. Psychological Review, 100(1), 91–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Projection bias in predicting future utility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1209–1248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mäler, K.-G. (1974). Environmental economics: A theoretical inquiry. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, R., & Carson, R. (1999). Using surveys to value public goods: The contingent valuation method. Washington DC: Resources for the Future.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Oceanographic and Atmospheric Administration [NOAA]. (1994). Proposed rules for valuing environmental damages. Federal Register, 59(5), 1062–1091.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ng, Y.-K. (1997). A case for happiness, cardinalism, and interpersonal comparability. Economic Journal, 107(445), 1848–1858.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng, Y.-K. (2003). From preference to happiness: towards a more complete welfare economics. Social Choice and Welfare, 20(2), 307–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Novemsky, N., & Kahneman, D. (2005). How do intentions affect loss aversion? Journal of Marketing Research, 42(2), 139–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oswald, A., & Wu, S. (2010). Objective confirmation of subjective measures of human well-being: evidence from the USA. Science, 327(5965), 576–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peters, E., Slovic, P., & Gregory, R. (2003). The role of affect in the WTA/WTP disparity. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 16(4), 309–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C., & Zeiler, K. (2005). The willingness to pay – willingness to accept gap, the ‘endowment effect’, subject misconceptions, and experimental procedures for eliciting valuations. American Economic Review, 95(3), 530–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Randall, A., & Stoll, J. (1980). Consumer’s surplus in commodity space. American Economic Review, 70(3), 449–455.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ready, R., Whitehead, J., & Blomquist, G. (1995). Contingent valuation when respondents are ambivalent. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29(2), 181–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Redelmeier, D., & Kahneman, D. (1996). Patients’ memories of painful medical treatments: real-time and retrospective evaluations of two minimally invasive procedures. Pain, 66(1), 3–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schkade, D., & Kahneman, D. (1998). Does living in California make people happy? A focusing illusion in judgments of life satisfaction. Psychological Science, 9(5), 340–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. (1980). Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1(1), 39–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: a reference dependent model. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1039–1061.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Praag, B., & Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. (2008). Happiness quantified: A satisfaction calculus approach. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Welsch, H. (2002). The preferences over prosperity and pollution: environmental valuation based on happiness surveys. Kyklos, 55(4), 473–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Welsch, H., & Kühling, J. (2009). Using happiness data for environmental valuation: issues and applications. Journal of Economic Surveys, 23(2), 385–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willig, R. (1976). Consumer’s surplus without apology. American Economic Review, 66(4), 589–597.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, T., Wheatley, T., Meyers, J., Gilbert, D., & Axsom, D. (2000). Focalism: a source of durability bias in affective forecasting. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 78(5), 821–836.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Edsel L. Beja Jr..

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Beja, E.L. Working Out the Willingness to Accept and Willingness to Pay Gap Using Economics, Psychology, and Happiness Approaches to Valuation. Applied Research Quality Life 9, 819–829 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11482-013-9271-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11482-013-9271-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation