Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The impact of cross-shareholding under different power structures considering green investment and green marketing

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Environmental Science and Pollution Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Cross-shareholding has played an important role in strengthening strategic synergy among enterprises, but its impact on the green development of enterprises is unclear. In this paper, we construct an analytical framework that includes a manufacturer and a retailer to explore the impact of cross-shareholdings under different leaderships on green supply chain operational decisions and profits, in which the manufacturer invests in green technologies and the retailer conducts green marketing. By constructing and solving the game model of manufacturer-led and retailer-led before and after cross-shareholding, it is found that after cross-shareholding, the product’s green level and the retailers’ marketing level are improved. For supply chain leaders, cross-shareholdings always increase their profits. Only when the follower holds the leader’s shares no more than a certain value, cross-shareholding will increase the total profit of the supply chain. In addition, we obtain the optimal decisions and profits of the supply chain in the integrated situation and design two-part pricing contracts to achieve cross-shareholding supply chain coordination. The results of this paper can provide theoretical guidance and decision support for enterprises interested in using cross-shareholding to improve supply chain performance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

Not applicable.

References

  • Agrawal VV, Ferguson M, Toktay LB, Thomas VM (2011) Is leasing greener than selling? Manage Sci 58:523–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson L, Rosenthal S (2014) Signaling the green sell: the influence of eco-label source, argument specificity, and product involvement on consumer trust. J Advert 43:33–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks C, Chen Z, Zeng Y (2018) Institutional cross-ownership and corporate strategy: the case of mergers and acquisitions. J Corp Finan 48:187–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cerqueti R, Rotundo G, Ausloos M (2020) Tsallis entropy for cross-shareholding network configurations. Entropy 22:676

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen C (2001) Design for the environment: a quality-based model for green product development. Manage Sci 47:250–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen J, Hu Q, Song J-S (2017) Effect of partial cross ownership on supply chain performance. Eur J Oper Res 258:525–536

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong C, Liu Q, Shen B (2019) To be or not to be green? Strategic investment for green product development in a supply chain. Trans Res E: Logistics Trans Rev 131:193–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erdogmus I, Lak H, Çiçek M (2016) Attractive or credible celebrities: who endorses green products better? Procedia Soc Behav Sci 235:587–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan Y, Ren M, Zhang J, Wang N, Zhang C (2022) Risk identification and assessment on green product certification — model construction and empirical analysis. J Clean Prod 370:133593

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gao K, Shen H, Gao X, Chan K (2019) The power of sharing: evidence from institutional investor cross-ownership and corporate innovation. Int Rev Econ Financ 63:284–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guo S, Choi T-M, Shen B (2020) Green product development under competition: a study of the fashion apparel industry. Eur J Oper Res 280:523–538

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hafezi M, Zhao X, Zolfagharinia H (2022) Together we stand? Co-opetition for the development of green products. Eur J Oper Res 306:1–22

    Google Scholar 

  • He J, Huang J, Zhao S (2019) Internalizing governance externalities: the role of institutional cross-ownership. J Financ Econ 134:400–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heydari J, Bineshpour P, Walther G, Ülkü MA (2022) Reconciling conflict of interests in a green retailing channel with green sales effort. J Retail Consum Serv 64:102752

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong Z, Guo X (2019) Green product supply chain contracts considering environmental responsibilities. Omega 83:155–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hussain J, Pan Y, Ali G, Xiaofang Y (2020) Pricing behavior of monopoly market with the implementation of green technology decision under emission reduction subsidy policy. Sci Total Environ 709:136110

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Kou X, Liu H, Gao H, Liu H, Yu X (2022) Cooperative emission reduction in the supply chain: the value of green marketing under different power structures. Environ Sci Pollut Res 29:68396–68409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li B, Wang H, Zheng W (2021a) Who will take on green product development in supply chains? Manufacturer or retailer. J Clean Prod 314:128000

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li G, Wu H, Sethi S, Zhang X (2021b) Contracting green product supply chains considering marketing efforts in the circular economy era. Int J Prod Econ 234:108041

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li Q, Guan X, Shi T, Jiao W (2020) Green product design with competition and fairness concerns in the circular economy era. Int J Prod Res 58:165–179

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Li Z, Pan Y, Yang W, Ma J, Zhou M (2021c) Effects of government subsidies on green technology investment and green marketing coordination of supply chain under cap-and-trade mechanism. Energy Economics 101:105426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu G, Yang H, Dai R (2020) Which contract is more effective in improving product greenness under different power structures: revenue sharing or cost sharing? Comput Ind Eng 148:106701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma P, Li KW, Wang Z-J (2017) Pricing decisions in closed-loop supply chains with marketing effort and fairness concerns. Int J Prod Res 55:6710–6731

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mu Z, Li Q, Dai G, Li K, Zhang G, Zhang F (2022) Government subsidy policy and online selling strategy in a platform supply chain with green R&D and DDM activities. Sustainability 14(15):9658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qiao A, Choi SH, Pan Y (2021) Multi-party coordination in sustainable supply chain under consumer green awareness. Sci Total Environ 777:146043

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Rahbar E, Wahid N (2011) Investigation of green marketing tools’ effect on consumers’ purchase behavior. Bus Strat Ser 12:73–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ranjan A, Jha JK (2019) Pricing and coordination strategies of a dual-channel supply chain considering green quality and sales effort. J Clean Prod 218:409–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ren D, Guo R, Lan Y, Shang C (2021) Shareholding strategies for selling green products on online platforms in a two-echelon supply chain. Trans Res E: Logistics Trans Rev 149:102261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rizzi F, Gigliotti M, Runfola A, Ferrucci L (2022) Don’t miss the boat when consumers are in-store! Exploring the use of point-of-purchase displays to promote green and non-green products. J Retail Consum Serv 68:103034

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shen B, Cao Y, Xu X (2020) Product line design and quality differentiation for green and non-green products in a supply chain. Int J Prod Res 58:148–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shi J (2019) Contract manufacturer’s encroachment strategy and quality decision with different channel leadership structures. Comput Ind Eng 137:106078

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shi J, Yang D, Zheng Z, Zhu Y (2022) Strategic investment for green product development and green marketing in a supply chain. J Clean Prod 366:132868

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun R, Ding Y, Wen C, Gao K (2022) Research on cross-shareholding behavior of Chinese listed companies. J Invest Manag 11:25–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor T (2002) Supply chain coordination under channel rebates with sales effort effects. Manage Sci 48:992–1007

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tian J, Cao W, Ji X (2021) Is cross-shareholding conducive to corporate sustainability? Evidence from the environmental investment of Chinese listed firms. Front Psychol 12:789811

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang L, Song Q (2020) Pricing policies for dual-channel supply chain with green investment and sales effort under uncertain demand. Math Comput Simul 171:79–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei Z, Huang Y (2022) Supply chain coordination under carbon emission tax regulation considering greening technology investment. Int J Environ Res Public Health 19(15):9232

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Xia Q, Zhi B, Wang X (2021) The role of cross-shareholding in the green supply chain: green contribution, power structure and coordination. Int J Prod Econ 234:108037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xiao T, Choi TM (2019) Quality, greenness, and product line choices for a manufacturer with environmental responsibility behaviors. IEEE Trans Eng Manage 67:1–15

    Google Scholar 

  • Zeng H, Jiang D, Li Y (2022) Cooperative and non-cooperative green advertising in the low-carbon supply chain under monopoly or competitive market. Sustainability 14(15):9190

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang S, Meng Q (2021) Electronics closed-loop supply chain value co-creation considering cross-shareholding. J Clean Prod 278:123878

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang X, Chen T, Shen C (2020) Green investment choice in a duopoly market with quality competition. J Clean Prod 276:124032

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu J, Gao Y, Shi Y, Paul SK (2022) Green investment mechanism considering supply chain risk aversion and negotiating power. Comput Ind Eng 171:108484

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

This research was funded by the General Project of Humanities and Social Sciences of the Ministry of Education of China (NO. 20YJC630124, 21YJC630077); the General Project of Humanities and Social Sciences Research of Colleges and Universities in Henan Province (NO. 2023-ZDJH-028, 2021-ZDJH-402); the Key Scientific Research Project of University of Henan Province of China (NO. 212102310059, 212102310998); the Annual Project of Philosophy and Social Sciences of Henan Province of China (NO. 2021BJJ104); Henan Province Colleges and Universities Youth Backbone Training Program of Colleges and Universities in Henan Province (NO. 2020GGJS175); Henan Province Soft Science Research Program (212400410099); Key scientific research projects of colleges and universities in Henan Province (20A630037); and National Natural Science Foundation of China (12171441).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Hao Liu, Sheng Wu, and Xinyue Zhao were responsible for conceptualization, methodology, formal analysis, software, data curation, investigation, and writing—original draft. Haodong Chen, Guobao Wang, Zhigang Song, and Yuqing Fan contributed to funding acquisition, supervision, and writing—review and editing. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hao Liu.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Not applicable.

Consent for publication

Not applicable.

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Responsible Editor: Nicholas Apergis

Publisher's note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1 We solve this model by backward induction and first consider the retailer’s decision. The Hessian matrix of \({\pi }_{r}^{DM}\) about \(p,v\) is \([\begin{array}{cc}-2& k\\ k& -2\end{array}]\). Since \(0<k<\sqrt{3}\), we can easily deduce that \({\pi }_{r}^{DM}\) is joint concave in \(p,v\). Let \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{DM}}{\partial p}=0\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{DM}}{\partial v}=0\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{DM}}{\partial v}=0\), we have \(p(w,e)=\frac{-w{k}^{2}+2a+2e+2w}{4-{k}^{2}}\), \(v(w,e)=-\frac{ak+ek-kw}{4-{k}^{2}}\).

Substituting \(p(w,e)\) and \(v(w,e)\) into \({\pi }_{r}^{DM}\), the Hessian matrix of \({\pi }_{r}^{DM}\) about \(w,e\) is \([\begin{array}{cc}-\frac{4}{4-{k}^{2}}& \frac{2}{4-{k}^{2}}\\ \frac{2}{4-{k}^{2}}& -2\end{array}]\). Obviously, its sequential principal minors are \(|{H}_{1}|=-\frac{4}{4-{k}^{2}}<{0}\), \(|{H}_{2}|=\frac{2(19-4{k}^{2})}{{(4-{k}^{2})}^{2}}>{0}\), respectively. Hence, we know that \({\pi }_{r}^{DM}\) is joint concave in \(w\) and \(e\). Let \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{m}^{DM}}{\partial w}=0\frac{\partial {\pi }_{m}^{DM}}{\partial e}=0\), we get \({w}^{DM}=\frac{4a+3c-a{k}^{2}-c{k}^{2}}{7-2{k}^{2}}\), \({e}^{MD}=\frac{a-c}{7-2{k}^{2}}\). From this, we can obtain \({p}^{DM}\), \({v}^{DM}\), \({\pi }_{m}^{DM}\), \({\pi }_{r}^{DM}\).

Proof of Lemma 2 We solve this model by backward induction and first consider the manufacturer’s decision. Let \(p=w+y\), we derive that the Hessian matrix of \({\pi }_{m}^{DR}\) about \(w,e\) is \(\left[\begin{array}{cc}-2& 1\\ 1& -2\end{array}\right]\). Obviously, \({\pi }_{m}^{DR}\) is joint concave in \(w\) and \(e\). Let \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{m}^{DR}}{\partial w}=0\frac{\partial {\pi }_{m}^{DR}}{\partial e}=0\), we get \(w\left(y,v\right)=\frac{2a}{3}+\frac{c}{3}-\frac{2y}{3}+\frac{2kv}{3}\), \(e\left(y,v\right)=\frac{2a}{3}+\frac{c}{3}-\frac{2y}{3}+\frac{2kv}{3}\). Substituting \(w\left(y,v\right)\) and \(e\left(y,v\right)\) into \({\pi }_{r}^{DR}\), we get the Hessian matrix of \({\pi }_{r}^{DR}\) with respect to \(y,v\) is \(\left[\begin{array}{cc}-\frac{4}{3}& \frac{2k}{3}\\ \frac{2k}{3}& -2\end{array}\right]\). Since \(0<k<\sqrt{3}\), we can easily induce that \({\pi }_{r}^{DR}\) is joint concave in \(y,v\). Let \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{DR}}{\partial y}=0\), \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{DR}}{\partial v}=0\), we obtain \({y}^{DR}\), \({v}^{DR}\). From this, we get \({w}^{DR},{e}^{DR},{p}^{DR},{\pi }_{m}^{DR},{\pi }_{r}^{DR}\)

The proofs of Lemmas 3 and 4 are similar to Lemmas 1 and 2. Hence, we omit them.

Proof of Corollary 1 We can derive \(\frac{\partial {e}^{DM}}{\partial k}\text{=}\frac{4k(a-c)}{{(2{k}^{2}-7)}^{2}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {e}^{DR}}{\partial k}\text{=}\frac{2k(a-c)}{{({k}^{2}-6)}^{2}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {v}^{DM}}{\partial k}=\frac{(a-c)(2{k}^{2}+7)}{{(2{k}^{2}-7)}^{2}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {v}^{DR}}{\partial k}=\frac{({k}^{2}+6)(a-c)}{{({k}^{2}-6)}^{2}}>0\).

Proof of Corollary 2 (1) In \(ML\), we can derive

$$\begin{array}{c}\frac{\partial {e}^{CM}}{\partial {l}_{m}}=\frac{(4-{k}^{2})(a-c)(1-{l}_{r})}{{(4{l}_{m}+8{l}_{r}-4{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-{k}^{2}{l}_{m}-2{k}^{2}{l}_{r}+2{k}^{2}+{k}^{2}{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-7)}^{2}}>0,\\ \frac{\partial {e}^{CM}}{\partial {l}_{r}}=\frac{(4-{k}^{2})(a-c)({2}-{l}_{m})}{{(4{l}_{m}+8{l}_{r}-4{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-{k}^{2}{l}_{m}-2{k}^{2}{l}_{r}+2{k}^{2}+{k}^{2}{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-7)}^{2}}>0,\\ \begin{array}{c}\frac{\partial {v}^{CM}}{\partial {l}_{m}}=\frac{k(4-{k}^{2})(a-c){(1-{l}_{r})}^{2}}{{(4{l}_{m}+8{l}_{r}-4{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-{k}^{2}{l}_{m}-2{k}^{2}{l}_{r}+2{k}^{2}+{k}^{2}{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-7)}^{2}}>0,\\ \frac{\partial {v}^{CM}}{\partial {l}_{r}}=\frac{k(a-c)}{{(4{l}_{m}+8{l}_{r}-4{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-{k}^{2}{l}_{m}-2{k}^{2}{l}_{r}+2{k}^{2}+{k}^{2}{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-7)}^{2}}>0\end{array}\end{array}$$

(2) In RL, we can derive \(\frac{\partial {e}^{CR}}{\partial {l}_{r}}=\frac{({3}-3{l}_{m})(a-c)(1-{l}_{m})}{{({k}^{2}+6{l}_{m}+3{l}_{r}-3{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-6)}^{2}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {e}^{CR}}{\partial {l}_{m}}=\frac{{k}^{2}(a-c)}{{({k}^{2}+6{l}_{m}+3{l}_{r}-3{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-6)}^{2}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {v}^{CR}}{\partial {l}_{m}}=\frac{k({6}-3{l}_{r})(a-c)}{{({k}^{2}+6{l}_{m}+3{l}_{r}-3{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-6)}^{2}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {v}^{CR}}{\partial {l}_{r}}=\frac{k({3}-3{l}_{m})(a-c)}{{({k}^{2}+6{l}_{m}+3{l}_{r}-3{l}_{m}{l}_{r}-6)}^{2}}>0\).

Proof Proposition 1 In ML, we can rewrite \({w}^{CM}\) and \({w}^{DM}\) as \({w}^{CM}=c+\frac{(a-c)(4-{k}^{2}){(1-{l}_{m})}^{2}(1-{l}_{r})}{(1-{l}_{m}-{l}_{r})[(4-{k}^{2})(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})-1]}\), \({w}^{DM}=c+\frac{(4-{k}^{2})(a-c)}{7-2{k}^{2}}\). So, to compare \({w}^{CM}\) and \({w}^{DM}\), we only need to compare their second part. Let \({\theta }_{1}=\frac{\frac{(a-c)(4-{k}^{2}){(1-{l}_{m})}^{2}(1-{l}_{r})}{(1-{l}_{m}-{l}_{r})[(4-{k}^{2})(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})-1]}}{\frac{(4-{k}^{2})(a-c)}{7-2{k}^{2}}}\) and \(\delta =\frac{1}{4-{k}^{2}}\), we can get \({\theta }_{1}=\frac{(2-\delta ){(1-{l}_{m})}^{2}(1-{l}_{r})}{(1-{l}_{m}-{l}_{r})[(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})-\delta ]}\). If \({l}_{r1}=\frac{2+{l}_{m}{}^{2}\delta -{l}_{m}{}^{2}-2{l}_{m}\delta -\sqrt{{l}_{m}{}^{2}{(2-{l}_{m})}^{2}{(1-\delta )}^{2}+4{(1-{l}_{m})}^{2}}}{2(2-{l}_{m})}<{l}_{r}<\frac{2+{l}_{m}{}^{2}\delta -{l}_{m}{}^{2}-2{l}_{m}\delta \text{+}\sqrt{{l}_{m}{}^{2}{(2-{l}_{m})}^{2}{(1-\delta )}^{2}+4{(1-{l}_{m})}^{2}}}{2(2-{l}_{m})}\), we have \({\theta }_{1}>1\), that is, \({w}^{CM}>{w}^{DM}\). However, we can derive \(\frac{2+{l}_{m}{}^{2}\delta -{l}_{m}{}^{2}-2{l}_{m}\delta \text{+}\sqrt{{l}_{m}{}^{2}{(2-{l}_{m})}^{2}{(1-\delta )}^{2}+4{(1-{l}_{m})}^{2}}}{2(2-{l}_{m})}-\frac{1}{2}>\frac{2-(2-{l}_{m})+{l}_{m}{}^{2}\delta -{l}_{m}{}^{2}-2{l}_{m}\delta +2(1-{l}_{m})}{2(2-{l}_{m})}>0\). Therefore, if \({l}_{r1}<{l}_{r}\le 50\%\), then \({w}^{CM}>{w}^{DM}\) and \({w}^{CM}\le {w}^{DM}\) otherwise.

(2) In RL, we can rewrite \({w}^{CM}\) and \({w}^{DR}\) as \({w}^{CR}=c+\frac{(a-c)(1-{l}_{m})\{2[(2{l}_{r}-3){l}_{m}-{l}_{r}+1]+{l}_{m}(1-{l}_{r})\}}{(1-{l}_{m}-{l}_{r})[3(1-{l}_{m})(2-{l}_{r})-{k}^{2}]}\), \({w}^{DR}=c+\frac{2(a-c)}{6-{k}^{2}}\). To compare \({w}^{CR}\) and \({w}^{DR}\), we only need to compare their second part.

Let \({\theta }_{2}=\frac{\frac{(a-c)(1-{l}_{m})\{2[(2{l}_{r}-3){l}_{m}-{l}_{r}+1]+{l}_{m}(1-{l}_{r})\}}{(1-{l}_{m}-{l}_{r})[3(1-{l}_{m})(2-{l}_{r})-{k}^{2}]}}{\frac{2(a-c)}{6-{k}^{2}}}\). By \({\theta }_{2}=1\), we have \({l}_{m1}=\frac{\frac{3}{2}{l}_{m}{}^{2}+[\frac{1}{2}+\frac{1}{2}(\frac{1}{2}{k}^{2}-6)-\frac{3}{2}{k}^{2}+4]{l}_{r}-\frac{1}{2}+(8-\frac{1}{2}{k}^{2})\frac{1}{2}+\frac{3}{2}{k}^{2}-8-\sqrt{\Delta }}{\frac{3}{2}{l}_{r}({k}^{2}-4)-1+(16-{k}^{2})\frac{1}{2}+4({k}^{2}-4)-{k}^{2}}\), \({l}_{m2}=\frac{\frac{3}{2}{l}_{m}{}^{2}+[\frac{1}{2}+\frac{1}{2}(\frac{1}{2}{k}^{2}-6)-\frac{3}{2}{k}^{2}+4]{l}_{r}-\frac{1}{2}+(8-\frac{1}{2}{k}^{2})\frac{1}{2}+\frac{3}{2}{k}^{2}-8+\sqrt{\Delta }}{\frac{3}{2}{l}_{r}({k}^{2}-4)-1+(16-{k}^{2})\frac{1}{2}+4({k}^{2}-4)-{k}^{2}}\), where \(\Delta ={(\frac{1}{2}-3)}^{2}{(1-{l}_{r})}^{2}\frac{1}{4}{k}^{2}+\frac{3}{2}(1-{l}_{m})(-\frac{1}{2}{l}_{r}{}^{2}+\frac{15}{2}{l}_{r}-\frac{15}{2}){k}^{2}+\frac{9}{4}{({l}_{r}{}^{2}-3{l}_{r}+4)}^{2}\). Therefore, if \(\mathrm{max}(\mathrm{min}({l}_{m1},{l}_{m2}),0)<{l}_{m}\le \mathrm{min}(\mathrm{max}({l}_{m1},{l}_{m2}),50\%)\), then \({w}^{CR}>{w}^{DR}\) and \({w}^{CR}\le {w}^{DR}\) otherwise.

The proof of Proposition 1 (3) and (4) is similar to Proposition 1 (1) and (2), we omit it.

Proof Proposition 2 In ML, we have \({e}^{CM}-{e}^{DM}=\frac{(a-c)((4-{k}^{2})[2-(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})])}{(7-2{k}^{2})[(4-{k}^{2})(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})-1]}\).

Since \((4-{k}^{2})[2-(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})]>0\), we have \({e}^{CM}-{e}^{DM}> \text{0}\). Similarly, it can be proved that \({e}^{CR}-{e}^{DR} \, \text{>} \, {0}\).

In RL, we have \({v}^{CM}-{v}^{DM}=\frac{k(a-c)((4-{k}^{2})(1-{l}_{r}){l}_{m}+{l}_{r})}{(7-2{k}^{2})[(4-{k}^{2})(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})-1]}\).

Since \((4-{k}^{2})(1-{l}_{r}){l}_{m}+{l}_{r}>0\), we have \({v}^{CM}-{v}^{DM}> \text{0}\). Similarly, it can be proved that \({v}^{CR}-{v}^{DR}\text{>}{0}\).

Proof Proposition 3 In ML, let \(\delta =\frac{1}{4-{k}^{2}}\), by \({\pi }_{sc}^{CM}>{\pi }_{sc}^{DM}\), we have \(0<{l}_{r}<\frac{(1-{l}_{m}){\delta }^{2}+({l}_{m}{}^{2}+{l}_{m}-2)\delta -3{l}_{m}{}^{2}+4{l}_{m}+\sqrt{[{(1-{l}_{m})}^{2}\delta -3{l}_{m}{}^{2}+4{l}_{m}]{(2-\delta )}^{2}\delta }}{(3-2{l}_{m}){\delta }^{2}+({l}_{m}{}^{2}+4{l}_{m}-8)\delta -3{l}_{m}{}^{2}+4{l}_{m}}={l}_{r2}\).

In RL, let \(\gamma =\frac{{k}^{2}}{3}\), by \({\pi }_{sc}^{CR}>{\pi }_{sc}^{DR}\), we have \(0<{l}_{m}<\frac{(1-{l}_{r}){\gamma }^{2}+({l}_{r}{}^{2}+{l}_{r}-2)\gamma -3{l}_{r}{}^{2}+4{l}_{r}+\sqrt{[{(1-{l}_{r})}^{2}\gamma -3{l}_{r}{}^{2}+4{l}_{r}]{(2-\gamma )}^{2}\gamma }}{(3-2{l}_{r}){\gamma }^{2}+({l}_{r}{}^{2}+4{l}_{r}-8)\gamma -3{l}_{r}{}^{2}+4{l}_{r}}={l}_{m3}\).

Proof of Proposition 4 We have \({\pi }_{m}^{CM}-{\pi }_{m}^{DM}=\frac{{(a-c)}^{2}((4-{k}^{2})(1-{l}_{r}){l}_{m}+{l}_{r})}{(7-2{k}^{2})[(4-{k}^{2})(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})-1]}>0\), that is, \({\pi }_{m}^{CM}>{\pi }_{m}^{DM}\) for any \({l}_{m}\) and \({l}_{r}\).

Proof Proposition 5 We have \({\pi }_{r}^{CR}-{\pi }_{r}^{DR}=\frac{12(a-c)(1-{l}_{m}){l}_{r}+{l}_{m}{k}^{2}{(a-c)}^{2}}{4[3(1-{l}_{m})(2-{l}_{r})-{k}^{2}](6-{k}^{2})}>0\), that is, \({\pi }_{r}^{CR}>{\pi }_{r}^{DR}\) for any \({l}_{m}\) and \({l}_{r}\).

Proof of Lemma 5 Let \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{sc}^{C}}{\partial p}=0\), \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{sc}^{C}}{\partial v}=0\), \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{sc}^{C}}{\partial e}=0\), we have \({p}_{sc}^{C}=c+\frac{2(a-c)}{3-{k}^{2}}{e}_{sc}^{C}=\frac{a-c}{3-{k}^{2}}{v}_{sc}^{C}=\frac{k(a-c)}{3-{k}^{2}}\). From this, we get \({\pi }_{sc}^{C}=\frac{{(a-c)}^{2}}{3-{k}^{2}}\).

Proof Proposition 6 (1) We can derive \(\frac{\partial {e}_{sc}^{C}}{\partial k}=\frac{2k(a-c)}{{(3-{k}^{2})}^{2}}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {v}_{sc}^{C}}{\partial k}=\frac{({k}^{2}+3)(a-c)}{{(3-{k}^{2})}^{2}}>0\).

(2) We can derive \({v}_{sc}^{C}-{v}^{CM}=\frac{k(a-c)((4-{k}^{2})(1-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})+{l}_{r})}{(3-{k}^{2})[(4-{k}^{2})(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})-1]}>0\), \({e}_{sc}^{C}-{e}^{CM}=\frac{(a-c)((4-{k}^{2})(2+{l}_{m}-2{l}_{r}-{l}_{m}{l}_{r}))}{(3-{k}^{2})[(4-{k}^{2})(2-{l}_{m})(1-{l}_{r})-1]}>0\), that is, \({v}_{sc}^{C}>{v}^{CM}\) and \({e}_{sc}^{C}>{e}^{CM}\).

Similarly, it can be proved that \({v}_{sc}^{C}>{v}^{CM}\) and \({e}_{sc}^{C}>{e}^{CR}\).

Proof Proposition 7 (1) In ML, for the manufacturer is in the dominant position, we first consider the retailer’s decisions. Let \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{TC}}{\partial p}=0\) \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{r}^{TC}}{\partial v}=0\), we have \(p(w,e)=\frac{-(2(a+e)-(-2+{k}^{2})w)(-1+{l}_{\text{m}})+(-2+{k}^{2})(-c+w){l}_{\text{r}}}{(-4+{k}^{2})(-1+{l}_{\text{m}})}\), \(v(w,e)=\frac{-k(a+e-w)(-1+{l}_{\text{m}})+k(-c+w){l}_{\text{r}}}{(-4+{k}^{2})(-1+{l}_{\text{m}})}\).

To reach the level of profit in the integration situation, there should be \(p(w,e)={p}_{sc}^{C},v(w,e)={v}_{sc}^{C}\). From this, we get \({e}^{TC}={e}^{C},{w}^{TC}=c\). Since the manufacturer is dominant, it can have all the profits obtained by the coordination, and the retailer can have the reserved profits. By \({\pi }_{r}^{TC}-S={\pi }_{r}^{CM}\), we obtain \({S}^{TC}\).

(2) In RL, for the retailer is in the dominant position, we first consider the manufacturer’s decisions. Let \(\frac{\partial {\pi }_{m}^{TC}}{\partial e}=0\), we have \(e(p,v)=\frac{{l}_{m}(p-w)+(c-w)({l}_{r}-1)}{2(1-l){r}}\). To reach the level of profit in the case of integration, there should be \(p={p}_{sc}^{C},v={v}_{sc}^{C},e(p,v)={e}_{sc}^{C}\). From this, we get \({w}^{TC}=\frac{-c{k}^{2}+2a+c}{3-{k}^{2}}\). Since the retailer is dominant, it can have all the profits obtained by the coordination, and the manufacturer can have the reserved profits. By \({\pi }_{m}^{TC}-S={\pi }_{m}^{CR}\), we obtain \({S}^{TC}\).

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liu, H., Wu, S., Zhao, X. et al. The impact of cross-shareholding under different power structures considering green investment and green marketing. Environ Sci Pollut Res 30, 22249–22261 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-022-23423-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-022-23423-9

Keywords

Navigation