Advertisement

Theory and Decision

, Volume 80, Issue 1, pp 101–123 | Cite as

Incremental willingness to pay: a theoretical and empirical exposition

  • Karine Lamiraud
  • Robert Oxoby
  • Cam Donaldson
Article

Abstract

Applications of willingness to pay (WTP) have shown the difficultly to discriminate between various options. This reflects the problem of embedding in both its specific sense, of options being nested within one another, and its more general sense, whereby respondents cannot discriminate between close substitutes or between more-disparate rivals for the same budget. Furthermore, high proportions of reversals between WTP-value and simple preference based rankings of options are often highlighted. Although an incremental WTP approach was devised to encourage more differentiated answers and a higher degree of consistency among respondents, a theoretical basis for this approach has not been elucidated, and there is little evidence to show that this approach might indeed achieve greater consistency between explicit and implicit rankings inferred from WTP values. We address both these issues. Following our theoretical exposition, standard and incremental approaches were compared with explicit ranking in a study assessing preferences for different French emergency care services. 280 persons, representative of the French adult population, were interviewed. Half received the incremental version, the other half the standard version. Results suggest that the incremental approach provides a ranking of options fully in line with explicit ranking. The standard approach was reasonably consistent with explicit ranking but proved unable to differentiate between the five most preferred providers, as predicted by theory. Our findings suggest that the incremental approach provides results which can be used in priority-setting contexts.

Keywords

WTP Contingent valuation Reference points Embedding effect Incremental approach Emergency care 

Notes

Acknowledgments

We would like to acknowledge colleagues at the Joint Meeting of UK and French Health Economists, Aix en Provence, 11-13th January 2012, and, in particular, Stephen Birch of McMaster University. Although the term ‘marginal approach’ to contingent valuation was coined in earlier works of Donaldson and colleagues in the context of trying to get specific groups of patients involved in preference elicitation exercises to focus on differences between close substitutes, i.e. different ways of treating the same problem, Birch pointed out that the use of this term is problematic, in that it does not reflect the strict interpretation of the term ‘marginal’ in economic theory. Accordingly, we refer to the term ‘incremental’ to emphasize the continued focus of this method on the more general issue of differences between options. We also acknowledge support of Health Chair—a joint initiative by PSL, Université Paris-Dauphine, ENSAE, MGEN and ISTYA under the aegis of the Fondation du Risque (FDR).

Compliance with ethical standards

Conflict of interest

There are no potential conflict of interest.

Ethics

The research was approved by ethic committee at ESSEC Business School.

References

  1. Boardman, A. E., Greenberg, D. H., Vinning, A. R., & Weimer, D. L. (1996). Cost-benefit analysis: Concepts and practice. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
  2. Buchmueller, T. C., Couffinhal, A., Grignon, M., & Perronnin, M. (2004). Access to physician services: Does supplemental insurance matter? Evidence from France. Health Economics, 13, 669–687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Cameron, A. C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2009). Microeconometrics using Stata. College Station, TX: Stata Press.Google Scholar
  4. Carson, R. T., Flores, N. E., & Meade, N. F. (2000). Contingent valuation: Controversies and evidence. Environmental and Resource Economics, 19, 173–210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Dziegielewska, D. A., & Mendelsohn, R. (2007). Does “No” mean “No”? A protest methodology. Environmental and Resource Economics, 38(1), 71–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Diamond, P. A., & Hausman, J. A. (1994). Contingent valuation: Is some number better than no number? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(4), 45–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Hackl, F., & Pruckner, G. J. (2006). Demand and supply of emergency help: An economic analysis of Red Cross services. Health Policy, 77, 326–338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Hausman, J. A. (2012). Contingent valuation: From dubious to hopeless. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(4), 43–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 193–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Kahneman, D., & Knetsch, J. L. (1992). Valuing public goods: The purchase of moral satisfaction. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 22(1), 57–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Luchini, S., Protière, C., & Moatti, J. P. (2003). Eliciting several willingness to pay in a single contingent valuation survey: Application to health care. Health Economics, 12, 51–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Morrison, G. (2000). The endowment effect and expected utility. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 47(2), 183–197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Olsen, J. A. (1997). Aiding priority setting in health care: Is there a role for the contingent valuation method? Health Economics, 6, 603–612.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Olsen, J. A., & Donaldson, C. (1998). Helicopters, hearts and hips: Using willingness to pay to set priorities for public sector health care programmes. Social Sciences and Medicine, 46, 1–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Olsen, J. A., Kidholm, K., Donaldson, C., & Shackley, P. (2004). Willingness to pay for public health care: A comparison of two approaches. Health Policy, 70, 217–228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Olsen, J. A., Donaldson, C., & Shackley, P. (2005). Implicit versus explicit ranking: On inferring ordinal preferences for health care programmes based on differences in willingness-to-pay. Journal of Health Economics, 24, 990–996.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Payne, J. W., Schkade, D. A., Desvousges, W. H., & Aultman, C. (2000). Valuation of multiple environmental programs. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 21(1), 95–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Schkade, D., & Payne, J. (1994). How people respond to contingent valuation questions: A verbal protocol analysis of willingness to pay for an environmental regulation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 26, 88–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1982). The expected utility model: Its variants, purposes, evidence and limitations. Journal of Economic Literature, 20, 529–563.Google Scholar
  20. Shackley, P., & Donaldson, C. (2002). Should we use willingness to pay to elicit community preferences for health care? New evidence from using a marginal approach. Journal of Health Economics, 25, 445–460.Google Scholar
  21. Smith, R. D. (2003). Construction of the contingent valuation market in health care: A critical assessment. Health Economics, 12, 609–628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Van Uden, C. J. T., Winkens, R. A. G., Wesseling, G. J., et al. (2003). Use of out-of-hours services: A comparison between two organisations. Emergency Medicine Journal, 20, 184–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsESSEC Business SchoolCergyFrance
  2. 2.THEMA-University of Cergy PontoiseCergy-Pontoise CedexFrance
  3. 3.Department of EconomicsUniversity of CalgaryCalgaryCanada
  4. 4.Yunus Centre for Social Business & HealthGlasgow Caledonian UniversityGlasgowUK

Personalised recommendations