Skip to main content
Log in

Pure hyperbolic discount curves predict “eyes open” self-control

  • Published:
Theory and Decision Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The models of internal self-control that have recently been proposed by behavioral economists do not depict motivational interaction that occurs while temptation is present. Those models that include willpower at all either envision a faculty with a motivation (“strength”) different from the motives that are weighed in the marketplace of choice, or rely on incompatible goals among diverse brain centers. Both assumptions are questionable, but these models’ biggest problem is that they do not let resolutions withstand re-examination while being challenged by impulsive alternatives. The economists’ models all attempt to make a single equilibrium preference predictable from a person’s prior incentives. This was the original purpose of these models’ hyperboloid (“β–δ”) delay discount functions, which have been widely justified by the assumption that a person’s intertemporal inconsistency (impulsiveness) can be accounted for by the arousal of appetite for visceral rewards. Although arousal is clearly a factor in some cases of intertemporal inconsistency, it cannot be blamed for others, and furthermore does not necessarily imply hyperboloid discounting. The inadequacy of β–δ functions is particularly evident in models of internal self-control. I have reviewed several of these models, and have argued for a return to pure hyperbolic discount function as originally proposed, the relatively high tails of which can motivate a recursive process of self-prediction and thereby the formation of self-enforcing intertemporal contracts. Such a process does not require a separately motivated faculty of will, or incompatible goals among brain centers; but it also does not permit the prediction of unique preferences from prior incentives.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Ainslie G. (1974) Impulse control in pigeons. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 21: 485–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G. (1975) Specious reward: A behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control. Psychological Bulletin 82: 463–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G. (1991) Derivation of “rational” economic behavior from hyperbolic discount curves. American Economic Review 81: 334–340

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G. (1992) Picoeconomics: The strategic interaction of successive motivational states within the person. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G. (2001) Breakdown of will. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G. (2007) Can thought experiments prove anything about the will?. In: Spurrett D., Ross D., Kincaid H., Stephens L. (eds) Distributed cognition and the will: Individual volition and social context. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G. (2010a) Procrastination, the basic impulse. In: Andreou C., White M. (eds) The thief of time: Philosophical essays on procrastination. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 11–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G. (2010b) Hyperbolic discounting versus conditioning and framing as the core process in addictions and other impulses. In: Ross D., Kincaid H., Spurrett D., Collins P. (eds) What is addiction?. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G. (2011) “Free will” as recursive self-prediction: Does a deterministic mechanism reduce responsibility?. In: Poland J., Graham G. (eds) Addiction and responsibility. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G., Haendel V. (1983) The motives of the will. In: Gottheil E., Druley K., Skodola T., Waxman H. (eds) Etiology aspects of alcohol and drug abuse. Charles C. Thomas, Springfield, pp 119–140

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G., Herrnstein R. (1981) Preference reversal and delayed reinforcement. Animal Learning and Behavior 9: 476–482

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G., Monterosso J. (2003) Building blocks of self-control: Increased tolerance for delay with bundled rewards. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 79: 83–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie G., Monterosso J. (2004) A marketplace in the brain?. Science 306: 421–423

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ariely D., Wertenbroch K. (2002) Procrastination, deadlines, and performance: Self-control by pre-commitment. Psychological Science 13(3): 219–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumeister R. F., Gailliot M., DeWall C. N., Oaten M. (2006) Self-regulation and personality: How interventions increase regulatory success, and how depletion moderates the effects of traits on behavior. Journal of Personality 74: 1773–1801

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bechara A. (2006) Broken willpower: Impaired mechanisms of decision-making and impulse control in substance abusers. In: Sebanz N., Prinz W. (eds) Disorders of volition. MIT, Cambridge, pp 399–418

    Google Scholar 

  • Benabou R., Pycia M. (2002) Dynamic inconsistency and self-control: A planner–doer interpretation. Economics Letters 77: 419–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénabou R., Tirole J. (2004) Willpower and personal rules. Journal of Political Economy 112: 848–886

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J., Bisin A. (2005) Modeling internal commitment mechanisms and self-control: A neuroeconomics approach to consumption-saving decisions. Games and Economic Behavior 52: 460–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentall R. P., Lowe C. F., Beasty A. (1985) The role of verbal behavior in human learning II: Developmental differences. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 43: 165–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berns G. S., Laibson D., Loewenstein G. (2007) Intertemporal choice: Toward an integrative framework. Neuroeconomics 11: 482–488

    Google Scholar 

  • Bickel W. K., Odum A. L., Madden G. J. (1999) Impulsivity and cigarette smoking: Delay discounting in current, never, and ex-smokers. Psychopharmacology 146: 447–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodner, R., & Prelec, D. (1997). The diagnostic value of actions in a self-signaling model. Paper delivered at the Norwegian Research Council Working Group on addiction, Oslo, Norway, May 26, 1995, MIT working paper.

  • Bodner R., Prelec D. (2001) The diagnostic value of actions in a self-signaling model. In: Brocas I., Carillo J. D. (eds) Collected essays in Psychology and economics. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Bratman E. M. (1999) Faces of intention: Selected essays on intention and agency. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Brocas I., Carrillo D. J. (2008) The brain as a hierarchical organization. American Economic Review 98: 1312–1346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter S. T., Tiffany B. L. (2001) The cue-availability paradigm: The effects of cigarette availability on cue reactivity in smokers. Experimental and Clinical Psychophamacology 9: 183–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coller, M., Harrison, G. W., & Rutström, E. E. (2010). Latent process heterogeneity in discounting behavior. Oxford economic papers.

  • Cropper M. L., Aydede S. K., Portney P. R. (1992) Rates of time preference for saving lives. American Economic Review 82: 469–472

    Google Scholar 

  • Dar R., Stronguin F., Marouani R., Krupsky M., Frenk H. (2005) Craving to smoke in orthodox Jewish smokers who abstain on the Sabbath: A comparison to a baseline and a forced abstinence workday. Psychopharmacology 183: 294–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darcheville J. C., Riviere V., Wearden J. (1993) Fixed interval performance and self-control in infants. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 60: 239–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deluty M. Z., Whitehouse W. G., Millitz M., Hineline P. (1983) Self-control and commitment involving aversive events. Behavioral Analysis Letters 3: 213–219

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster J. (1979) Ulysses and the Sirens: Studies in rationality and irrationality. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Field M., Duka T. (2001) Smoking expectancy mediates the conditioned responses to arbitrary smoking cues. Behavioural Pharmacology 12: 183–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick S., Loewenstein G., O’Donoghue T. (2002) Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature 40: 351–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freud, S. (1915/1956). The unconscious. In J. Strachey & A. Freud (Eds.), The standard edition of the complete psychological works of Sigmund Freud (Vol. 14, pp. 161–215). London: Hogarth Press.

  • Fudenberg D., Levine D. K. (2006) A dual-self model of impulse control. American Economic Review 96: 1449–1476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Levine, D. (2010). Timing and self-control. Working paper.

  • Garner D. M., Wooley S. C. (1991) Confronting the failure of behavioral and dietary treatments of obesity. Clinical Psychology Review 11: 767

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garvey, A. J., Kinnunen, T., Quiles, Z. N., & Vokonas, P. S. (2002). Smoking cessation patterns in adult males followed for 35 years. Poster presented at the Society for Research on Nicotine and Tobacco Annual Meetings, Savannah, GA. http://www.hsdm.harvard.edu/pdf-files/Dr._Garvey.pdf.

  • Green L., Fisher E. B. Jr., Perlow S., Sherman L. (1981) Preference reversal and self-control: Choice as a function of reward amount and delay. Behavior Analysis Letters 1: 43–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Green L., Fristoe N., Myerson J. (1994) Temporal discounting and preference reversals in choice between delayed outcomes. Psychonomic Bulletin and Review 1: 386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green J., Myerson L. (2004) A discounting framework for choice with delayed and probabilistic rewards. Psychological Bulletin 130: 769–792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green L., Myerson J., Holt D. D., Slevin J. R., Estle S. J. (2004) Discounting of delayed food rewards in pigeons and rats: Is there a magnitude effect?. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 81: 39–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green L., Myerson J., Macaux E. W. (2005) Temporal discounting when the choice is between two delayed rewards. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 31: 1121–1133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gul F., Pesendorfer W. (2001) Temptation and self-control. Econometrics 69(6): 1403–1435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gul F., Pesendorfer W. (2004) Self-control, revealed preference and consumption choice. Review of Economic Dynamics 7: 243–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson C. (2009) Thinking about addiction: Hyperbolic discounting and responsible agency. Rodopi, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison G. W., Lau M. I., Williams M. B. (2002) Estimating individual discount rates for Denmark: A field experiment. American Economic Review 92: 1606–1617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harvey C. M. (1994) The reasonableness of non-constant discounting. Journal of Public Economics 53: 31–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heidhues P., Koszegi B. (2009) Futile attempts at self-control. Journal of the European Economic Association 7: 423–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helzer J. E., Burnham A., McEvoy L. T. (1991) Alcohol abuse and dependence. In: Robins L. N., Regier D. A. (eds) Psychiatric disorders in America: The epidemiologic catchment area study. Free Press, New York, pp 81–115

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrnstein R. (1961) Relative and absolute strengths of response as a function of frequency of reinforcement. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 4: 267–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrnstein, R. J. (1997). In H. Rachlin & D. I. Laibson (Eds.), The matching law: Papers in psychology and economics. New York: Sage.

  • Heyman G. M. (1996) Resolving the contradictions of addiction. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 19: 561–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyman M. G. (2009) Addiction: A disorder of choice. Harvard University Press, Harvard

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofmeyr A., Ainslie G., Charlton R., Ross D. (2010) The relationship between addiction and reward bundling: An experiment comparing smokers and non-smokers. Addiction 106: 402–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holton R. (2009) Determinism, self-efficacy, and the phenomenology of free will. Inquiry 52: 412–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsiaw, A. (2009). Goal-setting, social comparison and self-control. Retrieved January 25, 2010, from Princeton University, Department of Economics website: https://www.princeton.edu/economics/seminar-schedule-by-prog/behavioral-f09/Hsiaw-Paper.pdf .

  • James W. (1890) Principles of psychology. Holt, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kable J. W., Glimcher P. W. (2007) The neural correlates of subjective value during intertemporal choice. Nature Neuroscience 10: 1625–1633

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby K. N. (1997) Bidding on the future: Evidence against normative discounting of delayed rewards. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 126: 54–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby K. N. (2006) The present values of delayed rewards are approximately additive. Behavioral Processes 72: 273–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby K. N., Guastello B. (2001) Making choices in anticipation of similar future choices can increase self-control. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied 7: 154–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby K. N., Herrnstein R. J. (1995) Preference reversals due to myopic discounting of delayed reward. Psychological Science 6: 83–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby K. N., Marakovic N. (1995) Modeling myopic decisions: Evidence for hyperbolic delay-discounting within subjects and amounts. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 64: 22–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans T. C. (1960) Stationary ordinal utility and impatience. Econometrica 47: 263–291

    Google Scholar 

  • Koszegi B., Rabin M. (2009) Reference dependent consumption plans. American Economic Review 99: 909–936

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D. (1994). Hyperbolic discounting and consumption. PhD thesis, MIT.

  • Laibson D. (1997) Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics 62: 443–479

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein G. (1996) Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 35: 272–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein G. F. (1999) A visceral account of addiction. In: Elster J., Skog O.-J. (eds) Getting hooked: Rationality and addiction. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. F., & O’Donoghue, T. (2004). Animal spirits: Affective and deliberative processes in economic behavior. CAE working paper #0414. http://ssrn.com/abstract=539843.

  • Loewenstein, G. F., & O’Donoghue, T. (2007). The heat of the moment: Modeling interactions between affect and deliberation. http://www.cramton.umd.edu/workshop/papers/loewenstein-odonoghue-heat-of-the-moment.pdf.

  • Marshall A. (1921) Industry and trade. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazur J. E. (1986) Choice between single and multiple delayed reinforcers. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 46: 67–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazur J. E. (1987) An adjusting procedure for studying delayed reinforcement. In: Commons M. L., Mazur J. E., Nevin J. A., Rachlin H. (eds) Quantitative analyses of behavior V: The effect of delay and of intervening events on reinforcement value. Erlbaum, Hillsdale

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazur J. E., Biondi D. R. (2009) Delay-amount tradeoffs in choices by pigeons and rates: Hyperbolic versus exponential discounting. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 91(2): 197–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McClennen E. F. (1990) Rationality and dynamic choice. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McClennen E. F. (1997) Pragmatic rationality and rules. Philosophy and Public Affairs 26: 210–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McClure S. M., Ericson K. M., Laibson D. I., Loewenstein G., Cohen J. D. (2007) Time discounting for primary rewards. The Journal of Neuroscience 27: 5796–5804

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McClure S. M., Laibson D. I., Loewenstein G., Cohen J. D. (2004) The grasshopper and the ant: Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards. Science 306: 503–507

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mijovic-Prelec D., Prelec D. (2010) Self-deception as self-signaling: A model and experimental evidence. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Science 365(1538): 227–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mischel W., Moore B. (1980) The role of ideation in voluntary delay for symbolically-presented rewards. Cognitive Therapy and Research 4: 211–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monterosso J., Ainslie G. (1999) Beyond discounting: Possible experimental models of impulse control. Psychopharmacology 146: 339–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muraven M. (2006) Conserving self-control strength. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 91: 524–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muraven M., Baumeister R. (2000) Self-regulation and depletion of limited resources: Does self-control resemble a muscle?. Psychological Bulletin 126: 247–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musau, A. (2009). Modeling alternatives to exponential discounting. Munich Personal Repec Archive (MPRA) paper no. 16416, June 2. http://mpra.ub.unimuenschen.de/16416/.

  • Navarick D. J. (1982) Negative reinforcement and choice in humans. Learning and Motivation 13: 361–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donoghue T., Rabin M. (1999) Doing it now or later. The American Economic Review 89(1): 103–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donoghue T., Rabin M. (2000) The economics of immediate gratification. Journal of Behavioral Decision-Making 13: 233–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donoghue T., Rabin M. (2001) Choice and procrastination. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116: 121–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps E. S., Pollack R. A. (1968) On second-best national saving and game-equilibrium growth. Review of Economic Studies 35: 185–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pine A., Shiner T., Seymour B., Dolan R. (2010) Dopamine, time, and impulsivity in humans. The Journal of Behavioral Neuroscience 30(26): 8888–8896

    Google Scholar 

  • Rachlin H. (1995) Self-control: Beyond commitment. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 18: 109–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rachlin, H. (2005). Problems with internalization. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28(5), 658–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Read D., Loewenstein G., Rabin M. (1999) Choice bracketing. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 19: 171–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P. A. (1937) A note on measurement of utility. Review of Economic Studies 4: 155–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling T. C. (1980) The intimate contest for self-command. The Public Interest 60: 94–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Smart R. G. (1975) Spontaneous recovery in alcoholics: A review and analysis of the available research. Drug and Alcohol Dependence 1: 277–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sonuga-Barke E. J. S., Lea S. E. G., Webley P. (1989) Children’s choice: Sensitivity to changes in reinforce density. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 51: 185–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strotz R. H. (1956) Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization. Review of Economic Studies 23: 166–180

    Google Scholar 

  • Telser L. G. (1980) A theory of self-enforcing agreements. Journal of Business 53: 27–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler R., Shefrin H. (1981) An economic theory of self-control. Journal of Political Economy 89: 392–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trope Y., Fishback A. (2000) Counteractive self-control in overcoming temptation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 79: 493–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wertenbroch K. (1998) Consumption self-control by rationing purchase quantities of virtue and vice. Marketing Science 17: 317–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George Ainslie.

Additional information

This material is the result of work supported with resources and the use of facilities at the Department of Veterans Affairs Medical Center, Coatesville, PA, USA. The opinions expressed are not those of the Department of Veterans Affairs or of the US Government. I thank Glenn Harrison, Don Ross, Jon Monterosso, and an anonymous referee for comments on earlier drafts, and Lynne Debiak for the artwork.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ainslie, G. Pure hyperbolic discount curves predict “eyes open” self-control. Theory Decis 73, 3–34 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-011-9272-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-011-9272-5

Keywords

Navigation