Advertisement

Synthese

pp 1–23 | Cite as

On the emergence of minority disadvantage: testing the cultural Red King hypothesis

  • Aydin MohseniEmail author
  • Cailin O’Connor
  • Hannah Rubin
Article

Abstract

The study of social justice asks: what sorts of social arrangements are equitable ones? But also: how do we derive the inequitable arrangements we often observe in human societies? In particular, in spite of explicitly stated equity norms, categorical inequity tends to be the rule rather than the exception. The cultural Red King hypothesis predicts that differentials in group size may lead to inequitable outcomes for minority groups even in the absence of explicit or implicit bias. We test this prediction in an experimental context where subjects divided into groups engage in repeated play of a bargaining game. We ran 14 trials involving a total of 112 participants. The results of the experiments are statistically significant and suggestive: individuals in minority groups in these experiments end up receiving fewer resources than those in majority groups. Combined with previous theoretical findings, these results give some reason to think that the cultural Red King may occur in real human groups.

Keywords

Social epistemology Social justice Evolutionary game theory Experimental economics Red King hypothesis 

Notes

Acknowledgements

This research was supported by NSF Grant 1535139. Thanks to the UC Irvine Social Dynamics seminar for feedback, to the ESSL lab at UC Irvine, to Nicholas Smith, Mike Ashfield, and to Michael McBride. Many thanks to participants at the California Philosophy Workshop for comments, especially Wendy Salkin, Joshua Armstrong, David Plunkett, Gabbrielle Johnson, and Karl Schafer. Thanks also to audiences at the Philosophy, Politics, and Economics Society meeting in New Orleans, the Agent-Based Models in Philosophy conference in Bochum, the Complex Systems seminar in Moscow, Idaho, and the APA Pacific Division meeting in Vancouver. Special thanks to Justin Bruner for inspiration, and for feedback.

References

  1. Adams, J. S., & Freedman, S. (1976). Equity theory revisited: Comments and annotated bibliography. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 9, 43–90.Google Scholar
  2. Arrow, K. J. (1978). Nozick’s entitlement theory of justice. Philosophia, 7(2), 265–279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Axtell, R., Epstein, J. M., & Young, H. P. (2000). The emergence of classes in a multi-agent bargaining model. Papers 9, Brookings Institution-Working Papers.Google Scholar
  4. Bergstrom, C. T., & Lachmann, M. (2003). The red king effect: When the slowest runner wins the coevolutionary race. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 100(2), 593–598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Binmore, K., & Shaked, A. (2010). Experimental economics: Where next? rejoinder. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 73(1), 120–121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Blume, A., DeJong, D. V., Kim, Y.-G., & Sprinkle, G. B. (1998). Experimental evidence on the evolution of meaning of messages in sender–receiver games. The American Economic Review, 88(5), 1323–1340.Google Scholar
  7. Börgers, T., & Sarin, R. (1997). Learning through reinforcement and replicator dynamics. Journal of Economic Theory, 77(1), 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bruner, J., O’Connor, C., Rubin, H., & Huttegger, S. M. (2018). David lewis in the lab: Experimental results on the emergence of meaning. Synthese, 195(2), 603–621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Bruner, J. P. (2017). Minority (dis)advantage in population games. Synthese, 13, 1–15.Google Scholar
  10. Buhrmester, M., Kwang, T., & Gosling, S. D. (2011). Amazon’s mechanical turk: A new source of inexpensive, yet high-quality, data? Perspectives on Psychological Science, 6(1), 3–5. PMID: 26162106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Chen, D. L., Schonger, M., & Wickens, C. (2016). oTree-An open-source platform for laboratory, online, and field experiments. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 9, 88–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Cooper, D. J. (2014). A note on deception in economic experiments. Journal of Wine Economics, 9(2), 111–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Croson, R. (2005). The method of experimental economics. International Negotiation, 10(1), 131–148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Davis, D., & Holt, C. (1993). Experimental economics: Methods, problems, and promise. Estudios Económicos, 8, 179–212.Google Scholar
  15. Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (2010). On inequity aversion: A reply to binmore and shaked. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 73(1), 101–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Freedman, S. M., & Montanari, J. R. (1980). An integrative model of managerial reward allocation. Academy of Management Review, 5(3), 381–390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., et al. (2001). In search of Homo economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. American Economic Review, 91(2), 73–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Hopkins, E. (2002). Two competing models of how people learn in games. Econometrica, 70(6), 2141–2166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Kees, J., Berry, C., Burton, S., & Sheehan, K. (2017). An analysis of data quality: Professional panels, student subject pools, and amazon’s mechanical turk. Journal of Advertising, 46(1), 141–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Nash, J. (1950). The bargaining problem. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 18, 155–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Nozick, R. (1974). Anarchy, state, and utopia. New York basic book. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  23. O’Connor, C. (2017). The cultural red king effect. The Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 41(3), 155–171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. O’Connor, C. (2018a). The evolution of inequity. Oxford: Oxford University Press. (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  25. O’Connor, C. (2018b). Modeling minimal conditions for inequity (pp. unpublished).Google Scholar
  26. O’Connor, C., Bright, L. K. & Bruner, J. P. (2017). The emergence of intersectional disadvantage. Working Paper.Google Scholar
  27. O’Connor, C., & Bruner, J. (2017). Dynamics and diversity in epistemic communities. Erkenntnis, 84, 1–19.Google Scholar
  28. Ogbu, J. U. (1978). Minority education and caste: The American system in cross-cultural perspective. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  29. Paolacci, G., & Chandler, J. (2014). Inside the turk: Understanding mechanical turk as a participant pool. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 23(3), 184–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Rubin, H., & O’Connor, C. (2018). Discrimination and collaboration in science. Philosophy of Science, 85(3), 380–402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Schelling, T. C. (1980). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  32. Sigmund, K., Hauert, C., & Nowak, M. A. (2001). Reward and punishment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 98(19), 10757–10762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Skyrms, B. (1994). Sex and justice. The Journal of philosophy, 91, 305–320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Smith, V. L. (1976). Experimental economics: Induced value theory. The American Economic Review, 66(2), 274–279.Google Scholar
  35. Stewart, Q. T. (2010). Big bad racists, subtle prejudice and minority victims: An agent-based analysis of the dynamics of racial inequality. Annual Meeting of the Population Association of America.Google Scholar
  36. Tajfel, H. (1970). Experiments in intergroup discrimination. Scientific American, 223(5), 96–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Taylor, P. D., & Jonker, L. B. (1978). Evolutionary stable strategies and game dynamics. Mathematical Biosciences, 40(1–2), 145–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Tilly, C., et al. (1998). Durable inequality. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  39. Weibull, J. W. (1997). Evolutionary game theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  40. Wylie, A. (2013). Why standpoint matters. Science and other cultures (pp. 34–56). Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
  41. Young, H. P. (1993). An evolutionary model of bargaining. Journal of Economic Theory, 59(1), 145–168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature B.V. 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Logic and Philosophy of ScienceUniversity of California, IrvineIrvineUSA
  2. 2.Department of PhilosophyUniversity of Notre DameNotre DameUSA

Personalised recommendations