1 Introduction

Social trust promotes a vibrant civic culture, facilitates spontaneous cooperation, supports economic markets, and weaves the separate parts of society into a cohesive whole (Cook, 2005; Durkheim, 1933; Granovetter, 1985). However, social trust is at risk as economic inequality divides and disintegrates societies. In recent years, a mounting number of empirical studies have pointed to a negative relationship between income inequality and social trust (Fairbrother & Martin, 2013; Hastings, 2018; Larsen, 2013; Rothstein & Uslaner, 2005; Uslaner, 2002; Uslaner & Brown, 2005). Accordingly, unequal contexts hamper the formation of trust, as they lead to social fractionalization and status competition (Bjørnskov, 2008; Wilkinson & Pickett, 2009). Despite this consensus, it remains unclear at what level of aggregation income inequality and its underlying mechanisms are most relevant to the cultivation of social trust.

In a comprehensive review, Wilkinson and Pickett (2009) speculate that inequality is most important when measured at the societal level, whereas for lower units of aggregation economic development becomes a stronger predictor of various health problems and social ills. The authors reason that the effect of inequality is mostly reflected in the stratification system of the society as a whole and depends less on income differences within smaller areas. Until now, however, empirical support for this “size of the area”-claim exists for health outcomes only. It is vital to our understanding of income inequality to determine if this pattern also generalizes to social trust.

This paper is the first to examine the “size of the area”-claim for social trust using a sample of 216 regions in 22 European countries. To this purpose, I merge regional inequality data (2010–2014) from the Luxembourg Income Study and the OECD database of Regional Income Distribution and Poverty to the European Social Survey (2012–2016). Using a multilevel modelling approach with individuals grouped in regions and regions nested in countries, I, first, analyze the impact of income inequality and economic development on social trust across regions as well as across countries and, second, disentangle the effect of the regional predictors into between-country and within-country components.

The study finds robust evidence for a negative association with income inequality and a positive association with economic development at the regional level. More importantly, the findings support the “size of the area”-claim by Wilkinson and Pickett (2009), but only when excluding the Eastern European countries from the analysis. In the non-Eastern countries, income inequality is a more important predictor at the country level than at the regional level. For economic development, the opposite is true. Differences in economic development within a country relate significantly to social trust, while differences between countries do not. In the Eastern countries, there is no association between regional income inequality and social trust. Thus, the study points to another limitation of the inequality-trust nexus as it suggests that the negative linkage might only hold for economically developed countries with strong democratic institutions.

By analyzing the relative importance of income inequality across the two levels, the study contributes to piecing together the extant evidence on the inequality-trust nexus. Previous work detecting significant relationships has done so predominantly in cross-country comparisons or across US states. By contrast, studies focusing on smaller levels of aggregation in single countries did not replicate the relationship (US counties in Fairbrother & Martin, 2013; Australian neighborhoods in Leigh, 2006a). This paper provides direct evidence that indeed the importance of income inequality for trust decreases at lower contextual units, in our case when moving from countries to regions. At lower aggregation levels, trust is related less to the inequality within the region, but rather to its wealth relative to the rest of society. In tandem, economic development becomes a more crucial predictor of social trust.

The study advances our understanding of the theoretical mechanisms underlying the inequality-trust nexus. Although previous efforts have robustly documented the relevance of social fractionalization and status competition in the context of inequality (Delhey & Dragolov, 2014; Hastings, 2018; Layte & Whelan, 2014; Paskov, 2016; Paskov et al., 2017), it is usually unspecified to what level of aggregation these mechanisms apply. The present findings suggest that social fractionalization might be more strongly reflected in the class divisions of society at large than in social mixing within regional clusters. Likewise, status competition appears to imply social comparison and sensitivity about social standing at the scale of the overall society, rather than among “neighbors” (Wilkinson & Pickett, 2009). In that, the findings underline the importance of societal factors—such as welfare states and democratic institutions—that shape social fractionalization and status competition at the country level.

The present study is also among the first to demonstrate that the negative relationship of income inequality and social trust extends to the European subnational level. European regions provide a theoretically meaningful context as many of our interaction experiences, which shape and reproduce social trust, go beyond local contexts such as districts or neighborhoods, but, at the same time, rarely spread over the entire country. In doing so, my work supports the empirical robustness of recent evidence by Charron and Rothstein (2018) using a different dataset and another indicator for inequality. Crucially, however, it goes beyond their analysis by showing that this effect is accounted for mainly by differences in inequality between countries rather than within countries.

2 Income Inequality and Social Trust: Theories and Hypotheses

People express trust towards others by believing in their trustworthiness under conditions of unknown outcomes (Robbins, 2016). The renowned generalized trust question captures this belief by asking respondents if they think that “most people can be trusted”. Although respondents have different circles of others in mind when they reply to this question, many think about the trustworthiness of anonymous strangers encountered in daily interactions (Delhey et al., 2011). In that, generalized trust differs from particularized trust, which pertains to close-knit communities with high social control (Portes, 1998).

Previous studies have explained individual variations in trust by adverting to personality traits (Delhey & Newton, 2003), socio-economic success in terms of income or education (Alesina & La Ferrara, 2002), or ascriptive characteristics like ethnicity and gender (Smith, 2010). In contrast, this paper draws on a growing literature that emphasizes the importance of two contextual factors: income inequality and economic development.

2.1 The Regional Context

People cultivate social trust through interaction experiences in their social environment (Hardin, 1993; Van Lange, 2015). Glanville et al. (2013, p. 546) argue that generalized trust is developed in informal social connections with friends, neighbors, and community members. Accordingly, people generalize from their particularized trust in local networks to the trustworthiness of the unfamiliar other (Freitag & Traunmüller, 2009; Welch et al., 2007). Besides that, interactions with unknown strangers also have a strong bearing on social trust. In these interactions, people learn about the goals and motivations of others and form a belief about the trustworthiness of the people around them (Delhey & Newton, 2003).

Regions provide a context for interactions in immediate social networks as well as for encounters with unknown strangers. They embed the local contexts, like neighborhoods and districts, in which people make many of their contact experiences with friends or acquaintances. However, other daily activities—commuting to work or school, visiting friends and family, and spending time on leisure activities—regularly exceed these small units of aggregation (Ziller, 2015). That is, our mobility is seldom limited to a single district or neighborhood, but spreads over larger geographical areas. Simultaneously, meaningful interactions with unknown others rarely scatter across an entire country. Thus, regions provide a meaningful unit of aggregation for analyzing how contextual factors affect contact experiences and shape generalized trust.

A key factor considered to hamper the build-up of social trust is income inequality. A large number of studies have demonstrated that collectives with uneven distributions of disposable income exhibit lower degrees of social trust (Bjørnskov, 2007; Delhey & Newton, 2005; Kawachi et al., 1997; Leigh, 2006b; Neckerman & Torche, 2007).

An oft-quoted mechanism underlying this inequality-trust nexus posits that income inequality leads to social fractionalization and thus increases the social distance of people located at each end of the income distribution (Bjørnskov, 2008). In dispersed contexts, there is less social mixing among people located at different positions in the social ladder. Consequently, individuals will have less contact experiences across the social spectrum and, hence, less opportunities to build-up social trust towards people who are unlike them. Even if social interactions across income groups take place, they are less likely to be fruitful because the lower likelihood of future exchanges reduces incentives for trustworthiness (Hastings, 2018). In a similar vein, it has been argued that social fractionalization amplifies the perceived opposition between the affluent and the less well-off (Fairbrother & Martin, 2013). The higher the economic distance between the two poles of the income distribution (and the more this economic distance translates into a cultural distance between extravagant lifestyles and relative deprivation), the larger the suspicion and the embitterment at the lower end of the social hierarchy (Gallego, 2016). Anticipating resentment by the poor, the affluent will hesitate to trust them, which potentially reinforces the social divide.

A second theoretical mechanism emphasizes that income inequalities raise the salience of competition. According to Wilkinson and Pickett (2009), unequal contexts make individuals more sensitive about their social standing and raise the importance of status differentiation. Comparisons with others and the anxiety of losing out in status competition lead to stress and are connected to a battery of psychosocial ills. In a nutshell, the authors argue that income inequality increases the importance of status hierarchies and the drive for “self-serving individualism”, while it simultaneously undermines social strategies based on reciprocity and cooperation (Wilkinson & Pickett, 2017). In line, previous work attests that status inferiority is strongly experienced across all income groups when income inequality is high (Delhey & Dragolov, 2014; Layte & Whelan, 2014).

Following these arguments, we expect that the higher the regional income inequality, the lower the level of social trust. Past research remains divided on this relationship at the regional level. Charron and Rothstein (2018) find that regions with a higher share of the population being at risk of poverty—a close proxy for income inequality—display less social trust. However, Ziller’s analysis (2015, Table 3) reveals no such evidence using the same indicator.

Next to income inequality, the economic development of a region—typically operationalized by the average GDP per capita—is also considered crucial to the formation of generalized trust. The connection between economic development and trust is viewed as a self-reinforcing cycle, as trust helps to overcome the moral hazard problem and facilitates investment, while growth leads to more economic activities in which trust with strangers can be created (Beugelsdijk et al., 2004; Knack & Zak, 2003; Zak & Knack, 2001). In wealthier regions, there is less to fear from trust betrayal and less to gain from behaving untrustworthy. Therefore, improved standards of living ease interactions with strangers and provide the necessary conditions for social trust to emerge. In line, Beugelsdijk and Van Schaik (2005) identify a correlation between social capital—an index composed of trust and civic participation—and economic development across 54 Western European regions (see also, Tabellini, 2010).

H1

The higher income inequality in a region, the lower is the level of social trust.

H2

The higher economic development in a region, the higher is the level of social trust.

2.2 The Country Context

Besides the regional context, trust is also shaped by societal influences at the level of countries. As a case in point, welfare states are mainly organized at this level and contribute decisively to the formation of social trust. For instance, Rothstein and Uslaner (2005) make the case that welfare states create social trust through universal social programs. Universal programs are generally more redistributive and—unlike means-tested programs—do not stigmatize certain socio-economic or ethnic groups (Bjørnskov & Svendsen, 2013; Kevins, 2019). Hence, universal welfare states nurture a sense of a shared fate, and its citizens are more likely to identify as a moral community (Uslaner & Brown, 2005). Further evidence indicates that democratic institutions, independent courts, impartial political institutions, and high-quality public services—all of which mainly operate at the level of nation states—are also associated with higher levels of social and political trust (Bjørnskov, 2007; Delhey & Newton, 2003, p. 99; Giustozzi & Gangl, 2021).

Against this backdrop, the country level is another important unit of aggregation to determine the association of income inequality and social trust. In this sense, social fractionalization may not just apply to regional contexts, in which it becomes a marker of social mixing and heterogeneity, but also to the society as a whole, in which it reflects the systems of class stratification. As national labor markets define the positions on the social ladder and national welfare states seek to reduce the gap between income groups, people might evaluate the social distance not only to others in their region, but with respect to others in their country. Likewise, status competition might not be confined to social comparisons among those living close together, but could take place within the boundaries of a state.

In fact, most of the extant literature on the associations between social trust and income inequality as well as between social trust and economic development has concentrated on the country level (besides those cited above, see also Olivera, 2015; Stephany, 2017; Whiteley, 2000). Thus, Hypothesis 3 and Hypothesis 4 address well-established claims.

H3

The higher income inequality in a country, the lower is the level of social trust.

H4

The higher economic development in a country, the higher is the level of social trust.

This being said, recent studies suggest that identifying the inequality-trust nexus crucially depends on the selected country set. In particular, Uslaner (2016) claims that the association becomes stronger if Eastern European countries with a post-communist legacy are excluded (see also, Uslaner, 2002). Indeed, the Eastern European countries are said to have experienced low levels of social trust during their communist rule (Paldam & Svendsen, 2001), as well as in their transition away from Communism (Bjørnskov, 2007; Sarracino & Mikucka, 2017).Footnote 1 Fidrmuc and Gërxhani (2008) show that the gap between the Eastern and the non-Eastern countries can be attributed to differences in economic development and in the quality of formal and informal institutions.

Besides, the Eastern European countries also appear to exhibit a weaker association of income inequality and social trust. Thus, income inequality would affect trust only once a certain level of economic wealth is reached and high-quality institutions are established. Up to this point, economic growth and the installation of democratic institutions appear to be the main antidotes to societal distrust (Barone & Mocetti, 2016) and play a greater role in alleviating health problems and psychosocial ills (Wilkinson & Pickett, 2009).

2.3 The “Size of the Area”-Claim

Although the importance of income inequality and economic development are well supported by previous research, it remains unclear at what contextual level they matter most for the cultivation of trust. Hastings (2018, p. 82), for instance, recently argued that even if the accumulated evidence on the inequality-trust nexus has evolved to a “stylized fact”, “it is not readily apparent what is the appropriate unit of aggregation to measure income inequality” when analysing its effect on trust.

In turn, the implications of income inequality and economic development across different hierarchical levels have been explored more thoroughly for health outcomes. In a review of more than 150 studies, Wilkinson and Pickett (2006) found that inequality matters most when large areas—such as US states or countries—were used as the unit of aggregation, while the evidence turns less supportive for small areas—such as counties and districts (Rostila et al., 2012; Subramanian & Kawachi, 2004). By contrast, economic development becomes a more powerful predictor in small areas than in large regions. Once the analysis moves to hierarchically lower levels, regions are performing poorly in health outcomes not because of their internal distribution of economic resources, but because they are worse off relatively to the society as a whole.

So far, there is no evidence on whether this “size of the area”-claim generalizes to social trust. However, previous work confirming the negative inequality-trust link has done so mostly in international comparisons, whereas the few studies that have moved to smaller units of aggregation have been unable to identify the negative relationship. Against this backdrop, I expect income inequality to matter more at the level of countries, whereas economic development becomes a stronger predictor for regional units of aggregation. In other words, between-country differences in inequality are more strongly related to social trust than within-country differences in regional inequality. On the other hand, within-country differences in regional economic development matter more to social trust than between-country differences in economic development.

H5

Social trust is more strongly associated with income inequality at the country level than at the regional level.

H6

Social trust is more strongly associated with economic development at the regional level than at the country level.

3 Data and Methods

3.1 Data

For the individual level data, I draw on the European Social Survey. The ESS is generally regarded as a high-quality data source with rigorous methodological standards. Most crucially, it provides information about the regions in which respondents reside using the Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics (NUTS) classification scheme. In this study, I merge the ESS dataset with harmonized measures of inequality and income at the country- and regions-level, which I constructed from the Luxembourg Income Study and the OECD database of Regional Income Distribution and Poverty. To merge the datasets, I choose a reference year in the period 2010–2014 for each country, depending on the availability of income inequality data. I then match this data to the next ESS wave following the reference year, allowing for a maximum of a two-year gap between data sources (Table 1).Footnote 2

Table 1 Overview of countries, regional levels, and data sources

The NUTS scheme consists of three subdivisions, which differ according to the size of regions.Footnote 3 I grouped respondents to the lowest level of aggregation for which both data on inequality as well as data from the ESS was available. With the exception of Slovenia, which is divided into two regions according to the NUTS-2 scheme, the number of regions per country ranges between 5 and 21.Footnote 4 The median population size of the included regions was 1.4 million, and the mean was 2.7 million. The mean population size of the NUTS-1, NUTS-2, and NUTS-3 regions was 5.0, 2.0, and 0.5 million. The average number of respondents per region was 188.7.

3.1.1 Social Trust

Social trust is measured in the ESS by three items. The three items capture responses on a scale from 0 to 10 to the following questions: “Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted, or that you can't be too careful in dealing with people?” (trustworthiness); “Do you think that most people would try to take advantage of you if they got the chance, or would they try to be fair?” (fairness); “Would you say that most of the time people try to be helpful or that they are mostly looking out for themselves?” (helpfulness). I condense the three items into an additive index (α = 0.77) and rescale the index to a range from 0 (low trust) to 10 (high trust). Some scholars have expressed concerns about the inclusion of fairness and helpfulness, arguing that they might not tap on generalized trust specifically (Bauer & Freitag, 2018; Uslaner, 2002). For this reason, I repeat the main analysis for the single trust item in Online Appendix A. In the remainder, I follow the bigger part of the literature (Dinesen, 2011; Reeskens & Hooghe, 2008), which takes the strong correlation among the three items as indication for a similar latent construct.

3.1.2 Contextual Variables: Income Inequality and Economic Development

The prime data source for the contextual variables is the Luxembourg Income Study (LIS). The LIS acquires and harmonizes data sets from high- and middle-income countries with the objective of facilitating cross-country comparisons. Although the data is not made available on a regular basis for all countries covered and varies with regard to the level of regional disaggregation, LIS offers the most comprehensive and finest-grained source for regional income data. I calculated Gini coefficients and the GDP per Capita based on measures of disposable household income. In LIS, disposable household income is a harmonized variable summarizing household income from labor, capital, pensions, and non-pension public social benefits, net of income taxes and social contributions. The LIS guidelines for creating comparable income variables across waves and countries recommend, first, to recode extreme values at the top and the bottom of the income distribution, second, to correct for the household size by dividing income by the square root of the number of household members (LIS equivalence scale), and third, to weight the data by the household weight [hpopwgt] multiplied by the number of household members [nhhmem] (see also, Savoia, 2019).Footnote 5 I follow these three steps to construct regional and country measures for income inequality (Gini) and economic development (GDP p.C.) and rescale them to a range from 0 to 1.

Some of the countries in the ESS are either not included in the LIS dataset with respective waves (Belgium, Sweden) or do not use regional clusters matching the ones used in the ESS (France, Netherlands, Norway, Slovenia). To prevent a loss of data points due to missing waves and countries, we add observations from the Regional Income Distribution and Poverty dataset of the OECD to the dataset constructed from LIS.Footnote 6 To assess the fit between the LIS and the OECD data, Online Appendix B identifies a strong correlation (r = 0.9) using the data points that are available from both sources.Footnote 7

3.1.3 Control Variables

Previous work suggests that trust is related to a number of sociodemographic characteristics and contextual factors (Bjørnskov, 2007; Kevins, 2019). To statistically control for these factors, the analysis includes the following variables at the individual level: gender, age, education (according to 5-level ISCED), income (measured by feelings about household income from 0 “living comfortably on present income” to 3 “very difficult on present income”), marital status (“married”,”separated or divorced”, “widowed”, “never married”), employment status (“paid work”, “unemployed”, “retired”, “other”), household size (grouped to “1”, “2”,”3–5” and “more than 5”), religiosity (from 0 “not at all religious” to 10 “very religious”), ethnic minority (dummy variable), foreign born (dummy variable), and victim crime (dummy variable indicating if the respondent or a member of the household had been victim of a burglary or assault in the last five years). In addition, I included as regional-level controls: population density (retrieved from Eurostat), share of ethnic minorities (calculated from ESS), and share of foreign-born (calculated from ESS).Footnote 8 Table 3 in the Appendix shows the descriptive statistics for the main variables used in the analysis. After listwise deletion of missing cases, the dataset covers a sample of 38.951 respondents, nested in 216 regions from 22 countries.

3.2 Estimation Strategy

To account for the hierarchically nested structure of observations, I apply multilevel modelling (Snijders & Bosker, 2012). Multilevel modelling accounts for the non-independence of observations in clusters and allows us to disaggregate the effect of upper-level variables in a between (-countries) and a within (-countries, but between-regions) component. In particular, we look at individuals i, who are grouped in regions j, with regions being nested in countries k. Since, the substantive interest of this study lies in examining the effect of upper-level variables (income inequality and economic development), the multilevel model includes random country-level and region-level intercepts. The model is described by the three formulas:

$${y}_{ijk}= {\beta }_{0jk}+{{\beta }_{1jk}x}_{ijk}+{e}_{ijk}$$
(1)
$${\beta }_{0jk}= {\gamma }_{00k}+{\gamma }_{01k}{w}_{jk}+{u}_{0jk}$$
(2)
$${\gamma }_{00k}= {\delta }_{000}+ {\delta }_{001}{z}_{k}+{v}_{ook}$$
(3)

The outcome variable trust \({y}_{ijk}\) is a function of the grand mean \({\delta }_{000}\), a set of individual-level control variables \(x\), regional-level variables \(w\) and country-level variables \(z\). The random part of the model corresponds to the region-specific random effects \({u}_{0jk}\sim N(0,{\sigma }_{uo}^{2})\), the country-specific random effects \({v}_{ook}\sim N(0,{\sigma }_{vo}^{2})\), and the residuals \({e}_{ijk}\sim N(0,{\sigma }_{e}^{2})\).

I ran three models. All of them include individual-level controls and regional-level controls, and differ only with regard to measures of income inequality and economic development, which are entered at different contextual levels. In Model (1), I test Hypotheses 1 and 2 by including measures of income inequality and economic development at the regional level \(({w}_{jk})\) in the level two specification. In Model (2), I test Hypotheses 3 and 4 by entering grand-mean centered country predictors of income inequality and economic development \(({z}_{k})\) at the third level.

Although Model (1) tests if the inequality-trust linkage extends to European regions, it does not tell us if differences between regions are mainly driven by the differences between countries or the differences of regions within a country. In other words, in Model (1) the effect of the regional predictors can be understood as a weighted average of an effect at level 2 and an effect at level 3. The former (the within effect) captures the difference in income inequality of a region relative to the other regions in a country, while the latter (the between effect) captures the difference between more and less unequal countries (Bell et al., 2018; Enders & Tofighi, 2007). To disentangle the two effects, Model (3) enters a regional-level predictor centered around the country mean \({(w}_{jk}-\overline{{z }_{k}})\) and a country-level predictor centered around the grand mean \((\overline{{z }_{k}}-\overline{z })\) for both contextual variables. By centering the regional-level variable on the cluster mean, the model eliminates country-level variance and derives a measure for the within-country effect. Likewise, the coefficient on the third level gives us an estimate of how between-country differences in income inequality and economic development affect social trust.Footnote 9 From this, we can infer if the predictors are more strongly associated with social trust on the regional level or on the country level (Hypotheses 5 and 6).

The analysis applies post-stratification weights (based on age, gender, education, and region) at the individual level and inverse probability weights to correct for the fact that countries are represented with different sample sizes.

4 Results

4.1 Descriptive Overview

Figure 1 provides a first glance at the regional Gini coefficients for the 216 regions in the dataset.Footnote 10 The map confirms established insights about country differences in inequality, as the Scandinavian countries exhibit comparatively lower levels of inequality than the Southern and Eastern European countries. Nevertheless, Fig. 1 also shows a considerable variation of inequality within each country. Specifically, the within-country standard deviation (2.50) of the regional Gini coefficients is only slightly lower than their between-country standard deviation (2.89).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Inequality by region. Regional Gini coefficients for 216 European regions. The Figure shows the values of the Gini coefficient retrieved from the Luxembourg Income Study and OECD database of Regional Income Distribution and Poverty for the years reported in Table 1

To split up the variation in social trust according to the three hierarchical levels, I calculate Intraclass Correlation Coefficients (ICCs). The ICC of the null model (i.e., an empty model without individual or contextual predictors) calculates how much of the total variance in an outcome variable can be attributed to the variation within clusters and the variation between clusters. In the three-level model, two ICCs can be derived and meaningfully interpreted. The first \(I{CC}_{1}\) determines how much of the total residual variance is made up by the random effects at level 2 (regions) and level 3 (countries). Using the notation \({\tau }_{0}^{2}=Var({u}_{0jk})\), \({\varphi }_{0}^{2}=Var({v}_{ook})\), and \({\sigma }_{e}^{2}=Var({e}_{ijk})\), \(I{CC}_{1}\) corresponds to:

$$I{CC}_{1}=\frac{{\tau }_{0}^{2}+{\varphi }_{0}^{2}}{{\tau }_{0}^{2}+{\varphi }_{0}^{2}+{\sigma }_{e}^{2}}=0.191$$
(4)

19.1% of the total variance of social trust can be explained by the groupings of individuals into higher-level units. The second \(I{CC}_{2}\) states how much of this higher-level variation is accounted for by country groupings (level 3) relative to region groupings (level 2). Sticking to the notation above, \(I{CC}_{2}\) amounts to:

$$I{CC}_{2}=\frac{{\varphi }_{0}^{2}}{{\tau }_{0}^{2}+{\varphi }_{0}^{2}}=0.862$$
(5)

Thus, countries account for 86.2% and regions for 13.8 (100–86.2) % of the higher-level variation in social trust. From these numbers, we can infer that most of the between-person variation in social trust is explained by the clustering of individuals into countries. Nevertheless, there are also considerable regional differences in social trust at the subnational level. To visualize the variation in trust across countries and regions, Fig. 2 plots the estimated random effects for each country and Fig. 3 plots the estimated random effects for each region in the six countries with the highest range of random effects.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Random effects by country. Estimated random effects at the country-level (null model). The zero line corresponds to a predicted value of 5.26 for social trust (scaled from [0;10]). Error bars show 95% CI

Fig. 3
figure 3

Random effects by region. Estimated random effects at the regions-level (null model). Error bars show 95% CI. The figure reports the six countries with the highest range of random effects. Online Appendix C shows the random effects of all countries. Sorted from left top to right bottom by range of random effects

Figure 2 reproduces the established pattern as many Nordic countries rank relatively high (Delhey & Newton, 2005) and many Southern and Eastern countries are in the lower third of the graph (Pichler & Wallace, 2007). Overall, the average trust scores of most countries fall within a 2.5 interval. The range of the regional averages within each country is comparatively smaller, but varies considerably between countries. In some countries (e.g., AT, DK, CZ) there is less than a 0.5 point difference between the average scores of the most and the least trusting region. In other countries (e.g., SK, IT, RU), regions differ more strongly from another, although even the largest distance between regional averages (in RU: 1.34) stays below the spread of the country averages (see also, Charron & Rothstein, 2018).

Figure 4 presents a first overview of the relationship between income inequality and social trust. The figure plots average trust scores against regional Gini coefficients, distinguishing between Eastern European and non-Eastern European countries.Footnote 11 What is striking is that the relationship between income inequality and social trust is positive in the former country group, whereas it is clearly negative in the non-Eastern countries. Thus, a first visual inspection suggests that the negative inequality-trust nexus does not apply to Eastern European regions. To account for this, the main analysis reports estimates of the contextual variables once across all countries (Models 1a, 2a, and 3a) and once interacted with a dummy variable for Eastern Europe (Models 1b, 2b, and 3b).

Fig. 4
figure 4

Trust-inequality scatter. Regional Gini Coefficients retrieved from the Luxembourg Income Study and the OECD database of Regional Income Distribution and Poverty for the years reported in Table 1. Regional Averages for Social Trust reported for 202 regions with more than 30 observations per region. Eastern Europe = CZ, EE, HU, LT, PL, SI, SK, RU

4.2 Main Analysis

Table 2 presents the results of the main analysis. Models (1a) and (1b) study the effects of income inequality and economic development on social trust at the regional level. Models (2a) and (2b) zoom in on the country level. Models (3a) and (3b) disentangle the within-country and between-country components of the regional variables. Online Appendix E supplements the full output including the control variables.

Table 2 Multilevel models: main results

Across all countries, Model (1a) reveals that social trust is negatively related to income inequality and positively related to economic development at the regional level, providing direct support for Hypothesis 1 and Hypothesis 2. Model (1b) inserts interaction effects for Eastern European countries with Gini region and GDP p.C. region, respectively. In the non-Eastern countries, the effects postulated in Hypothesis 1 and Hypothesis 2 are reproduced. However, both effects are nullified in the Eastern countries.Footnote 12

Models (2a) and (2b) shift the focus to the country level-predictors. Over all countries, specification (2a) shows that the association between inequality and trust is negative but statistically insignificant, whereas economic development is strongly associated with social trust. It is only in Model (2b) that we detect evidence for a negative inequality-trust linkage across the non-Eastern countries. Again, this effect is annihilated in the Eastern country sample.Footnote 13 In turn, when splitting up the sample in Model (2b), the effect of GDP p.C. at the country level vanishes in both country sets.

The results confirm Hypothesis 4, but provide only partial evidence for Hypothesis 3 as the negative inequality-trust linkage holds only across the non-Eastern countries. This squares with previous research arguing that the linkage is stronger if the Eastern European countries are excluded from the analysis (Uslaner, 2002). Online Appendix F shows that this negative moderation effect can only be partially reproduced by splitting the country sample according to GDP p.C., indicating that the differences across country groups cannot be entirely accounted for by different levels of economic development.

Finally, Models (3a) and (3b) disentangle the regional effects into within-country and between-country differences. In Model (3a), we find evidence that within-country differences in economic inequality are significantly associated to social trust, while between-country differences are not. Turning to economic development, the model provides positive evidence for within- and between-country effects. Affluent countries are more trusting than poor countries; and high-income regions are more trusting than low-income regions, controlling for country differences.

Moving to Model (3b), we recover the negative impact of Gini between as well as the within-country component. That is, in non-Eastern Europe between-country differences and within-country differences in inequality matter for social trust. In terms of magnitude, however, Gini between is more than three times larger than Gini within. This is visualized in the upper panel of Fig. 5, which illustrates the predicted values for social trust at different levels of Gini within and Gini between, holding the other variable and the control variables at the mean. The upper panel of Fig. 5 shows that the slope of Gini between is considerably steeper than the one of Gini within. Regarding the size of the effects, an increase of 0.25 in Gini within—that is a Gini coefficient 0.05 higher than the country average—decreases the trust score by 0.22, whereas the same increase in Gini between leads to a decrease of 0.72 in social trust. In a nutshell, although the analysis finds within-country differences in inequality to be meaningfully associated with social trust, the between-country difference is distinctly stronger (Hypothesis 5).

Fig. 5
figure 5

Predicted values: multilevel model. Predicted values estimated from Model (3b) at mean of other variables. The x-axis corresponds to the difference between the regional value and the country average for the rescaled Gini within- and GDP within-variables, or to the difference between a country value and the grand mean for the rescaled Gini between- and GDP between-variables. A 0.25 increase in the rescaled Gini (GDP p.C.) corresponds to a 0.05 (14.325) increase in Gini (GDP p.C.)

In the non-Eastern countries, GDP between turns insignificant, but the within-country difference in economic development still significantly relates to trust (Hypothesis 6). What is more, the within-country difference is also quantitatively more important than the (insignificant) between-country difference, as can be seen from the slopes of the two variables in the lower panel in Fig. 5. A 0.25 increase in GDP within leads to an increase in the trust score of 0.45, whereas the same increase in GDP between implies a 0.3 (insignificantly) higher trust score.Footnote 14

These results align with the intuition of the “size of the area”-claim and suggest that economic development is more important at lower levels of aggregation, whereas income inequality matters more in higher-level aggregates.

5 Discussion and Conclusion

Economic inequalities increasingly threaten the social fabric of European societies. In recent years, the academic community has robustly documented the influence of economic factors on trust, a central indicator for social cohesion. But at what level of aggregation do economic factors matter for social trust? This paper reexamines the trust-inequality nexus across 216 European regions in 22 countries and, in doing so, sheds light on its magnitude at different hierarchical levels.

The paper finds support for a negative association of income inequality and social trust across European regions. This finding chimes with recent evidence by Charron and Rothstein (2018), who likewise detect a negative association across European regions using another dataset and a different indicator for income inequality, the risk of poverty rate (see also, Ziller, 2015, whose analysis however does not reveal a negative association between this indicator and social trust). In analyzing this relationship at a different hierarchical level than most previous studies, my work adds to the empirical robustness of inequality-trust nexus.

Most importantly, however, the paper goes beyond prior work by disentangling the effect of income inequality on social trust into its between-country component and its within-country component. In doing so, the paper shows that, despite the sizeable impact of the within-country component of regional inequality, most of the variation in social trust is accounted for by differences in inequality between countries. In other words, the effect of income inequality on the regional level can be attributed rather to differences between countries than to differences of the regions within countries. For economic development, we observe the opposite pattern. The within-country component of GDP per capita relates significantly to social trust, whereas differences in economic development between countries do not.

This phenomena is in line with the “size of the area”-claim by Wilkinson and Pickett (2009). The authors hypothesized that income inequalities matter most at upper contextual levels, whereas in small aggregates absolute income becomes a more decisive predictor. Past research has documented this pattern for health and psychological outcomes (Rostila et al., 2012), but the present analysis is the first to demonstrate this pattern for social trust across two hierarchical levels.

By doing so, the paper helps to synthesize conflicting evidence from studies zooming in on the inequality-trust nexus at different contextual levels. While international comparisons have overwhelmingly produced affirmative evidence at the country level (Barone & Mocetti, 2016; Bjørnskov, 2008; Delhey & Newton, 2005; Olivera, 2015; Rothstein & Uslaner, 2005; Stephany, 2017), studies that have moved to smaller aggregates—like neighborhoods, counties, or districts—have failed to do so (Fairbrother & Martin, 2013; Leigh, 2006a). In line, the present study demonstrates that the association between income inequality and social trust becomes weaker, as the analysis moves from countries to regions. Extrapolating from this finding, we would expect the relative importance of income inequality to decline even further in smaller aggregates. This conjecture, however, requires testing by comparative research at even lower levels of aggregation, which might also reveal effects of local inequality that were not captured by regional clusters.

This finding also holds implications for the established theoretical mechanisms underlying the inequality-trust nexus: social fractionalization and status competition. Although abundant research has tested these mechanisms in the context of income inequality (Delhey & Dragolov, 2014; Hastings, 2018; Layte & Whelan, 2014; Paskov, 2016; Paskov et al., 2017), it remains unclear to what level of aggregation they apply. The results suggest that social fractionalization and status competition might more strongly relate to the inequality of the income distribution as a whole rather than the inequality experienced in local contexts. While this is a step towards the theoretical refinement of these mechanisms, future research needs to assess their strength at different contextual levels directly by means of carefully designed survey questions.

Concluding that income inequality matters more on the national level naturally leads us to emphasize the merits of the welfare state and other societal institutions, which reduce social fractionalization and alleviate the socio-psychological ills from status competition. Eventually, also supranational institution such as the European Union might harm or foster social trust towards fellow citizens. Inasmuch as its policies shape inequality not just across, but also within countries, the European Union could also be a driving force of social cohesion in its member states.

The present paper has identified another limitation of the inequality-trust nexus. Thus, negative linkages at the regional and the country level only hold in a set of non-Eastern European countries (Uslaner, 2002, 2016). Previous studies have already pointed out that Eastern European countries are marked by low levels of social trust (Bjørnskov, 2007; Sarracino & Mikucka, 2017) and that these can be mostly ascribed to weak economic development and a low quality of formal and informal institutions (Fidrmuc & Gërxhani, 2008). On top of that, my analysis indicates that this country group also exhibits a categorically different inequality-trust pattern. To further explore this pattern, I follow recent insights that income inequality matters especially in wealthy countries (Barone & Mocetti, 2016; Wilkinson & Pickett, 2009). I find partial evidence that economic development conditions the inequality-trust association. This highlights the need for future investigations to examine the importance of democratic institutions not only for the absolute level of trust (Charron & Rothstein, 2018), but also as a moderator of the inequality-trust nexus.

Importantly, the context of European regions naturally limits the availability of clusters at the third level (22 European countries). Thus, reservations with regard to the precision of the estimates at the macro (country) level and the accuracy of their standard errors may arise (Bryan & Jenkins, 2016; Stegmueller, 2013). In this light, the country-level estimates should be interpreted with caution and against the background of the extant literature, which has so far convincingly demonstrated this relationship in cross-country analyses using broader sets of (developed) countries across the globe.

A natural progression to this work needs to incorporate the dimension of time to identify causal relationships between income inequality and social trust at different levels of aggregation. Indeed, a handful of recent studies has queried causal interpretations suggesting that the link holds in cross-sectional analyses exclusively, whereas changes in inequality are unrelated to changes in trust over time (Bergh & Bjørnskov, 2014; Fairbrother & Martin, 2013; Olivera, 2015). The robustness of this claim, however, seems to hinge strongly on the country sample.Footnote 15 Whereas Fairbrother and Martin (2013) focus on US states and Olivera (2015) looks at European countries, Barone and Mocetti (2016) find evidence for a causal linkage in a broader set of developed countries (see also, Graafland & Lous, 2019). Given the cross-sectional nature of the dataset, the analysis at hand does not permit us to conclude that the contextual variables affect social trust, instead of the other way around. Nevertheless, my work is informative to this discussion, since it addresses a related theoretical point asking to which level of aggregation the relationship and its potential mechanisms might apply.

If the debate is to be moved forward, research will also need to explore in how far the effect of income inequality on social trust might differ for socio-economic groups (Ravazzini & Chávez-Juárez, 2018). Even though past work suggests that all income groups suffer from inequality (Layte & Whelan, 2014), it might well be that the affluent are more prone to inequalities at the country level, whereas for the less well-off social comparisons within smaller units are more important.