Skip to main content

How Interdependent are Cross-Country Happiness Dynamics?

Abstract

We characterize evolution of cross-country happiness dynamics by two important factors. The first one concerns inertia, which we model in a non-linear and stochastic environment to reflect on how an agent’s own past level of happiness adapts to the current level. Second, we allow an explicit role of socio-economic ‘distance’ in facilitating dynamic interdependence among happiness levels. A series of hypotheses are tested on a long-time series data for a sample of twelve European countries. We find that inertia has a strong positive and non-linear effect on countries’ steady-state happiness convergence. The effects are more pronounced when relative income and macroeconomic variables are allowed to determine the correlation structure of happiness. The main novelty is the consideration of spatio-temporal dynamic aspects of happiness where complementarity in the latter across economies is rigorously tested and established. We find that after accounting for the effects of heterogenous socio-economic dynamics, cross-country happiness is indeed complementary: a unit rise in happiness level in one country raises happiness in others. Our analytical model and empirical findings have interesting socio-economic policy implications.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Notes

  1. Throughout the paper the terms ‘life-satisfaction’ and ‘happiness’ will be used interchangeably to represent subjective well-being. The analysis presented in this paper concerns country level happiness/life-satisfaction dynamics.

  2. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing out the relevance of this aspect to our research.

  3. The growth of the happiness indicates temporal dependence on past observations. This can be characterized by both inertia and by the past values of other determinants. Binder and Coad (2010), Bottan and Truglia (2011), and D’Ambrosio and Frick (2012) study different dimensions of inertia and their interdependence dynamics.

  4. A series of influential contributions from Easterlin et al. in the comparison of happiness-income profile across economies and over time provided the much needed motivation for the current work.

  5. Our sincere thanks go to Richard Easterlin and Laura Angelescu who have kindly provided their data set, which lent to the comparison of our own constructed data.

  6. For cross-country panel unit root test we can employ Levin-Lin-Chu (LLC) method where it is assumed that \(\rho\) is the same across all countries: \(\Delta h_{it} = \alpha _i + \rho h_{i,t-1} + \sum _{k=1}^{n} \Delta h_{i,t-k} + \delta _i t + u_{it}\). Here \(\Delta\) is the first difference of \(h_{it}\); \(\delta\) is the coefficient of time trend. In contrast, one can allow \(\rho\) to differ for each \(i\) and accommodate heterogeneity in the form of individual unit root process following Im-Pesaran-Schmidt (IPS) method. In this case, \(H_0: \rho _i\) = 0 for all \(i\) and \(H_1: \rho _i\) \(<\) 0 for at least one \(i\). Under \(H_0\) all happiness series are assumed to be non-stationary processes whereas under alternative hypothesis it implies that at least a fraction of the series in the panel are stationary.

  7. See, Chen and Conley (2001) for detailed description on the conditional mean and variance of spatial VAR.

  8. We sincerely thank Richard Easterlin and Laura Angelescu for kindly sharing their data set for the present study.

  9. While it is possible that the spatial dynamics results might experience marginal change, other inferences—which are based on individual country characteristics would remain unchanged.

  10. Many thanks to the anonymous referee for underlining the importance of the same while interpreting our results.

  11. For robustness check we have also collected data from the World Happiness Database and have re-estimated our models. The results—despite some minor change in values—do not alter the conclusions of the paper.

  12. This division also roughly corresponds to one of the referee’s concerns that the literature proves that there is a strong happiness increases around the age of 60 followed by a major decline after 75’.

  13. Many thanks to a referee who pointed out an error.

References

  • Azomahou, T., & Mishra, T. (2008). Age dynamics and economic growth: Revisiting the nexus in a nonparametric setting. Economics Letters, 99(1), 67–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becchetti, L., Massari, R., & Naticchioni, P. (2013). The drivers of happiness inequality: Suggestions for promoting social cohesion. Oxford Economic Papers, 65(3), 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binder, M., & Coad, A. (2010). An examination of the dynamics of well-being and life events using vector autoregressions. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 76, 352–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (2008). Is well-being U-shaped over the life cycle? Social Science & Medicine, 66, 1733–1749.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottan, N., & Perez-Truglia, R. (2011). Deconstructing the Hedonic Treadmill. Journal of Socio-Economics, 40, 224–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, X., & Conley, T. G. (2001). A new semiparametric spatial model for panel time series. Journal of Econometrics, 105, 59–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choudhary, A., Levine, P., McAdam, P., & Welz, P. (2012). The happiness puzzle: Analytical aspects of the Easterlin paradox. Oxford Economic Papers, 64, 2742.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. E., Frijters, P., & Shields, A. M. (2008). Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature, 46:1, 95144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crespo, Cuaresma J., & Mishra, T. (2011). The role of age-structured education data for economic growth forecasts. Journal of Forecasting, 30(2), 249–267.

    Google Scholar 

  • D’Ambrosio, C., & Frick, J. R. (2012). Individual wellbeing in a dynamic perspective. Economica, 79(314), 209423.

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R., MacCulloch, R., & Oswald, A. J. (2003). The macroeconomics of happiness. Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4), 793809.

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R., & MacCulloch, R. (2008). Gross national happiness as an answer to the Easterlin Paradox? Journal of Development Economics, 86, 2242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence. In P. David & M. Reder (Eds.), Nations and huseholds in economic growth: Essays in Honour of Moses Abramovitz. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A., Angelescu, L. (2009). Happiness and Growth the World Over: Time Series Evidence on the Happiness-Income Paradox. IZA Discussion Paper No. 4060.

  • Easterlin, R. A., & Angelescu, Mc Vey L. (2010). The happiness-income Paradox revisited. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 107(52), 22463–22468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, J., & Gijbels, I. (1996). Local polynomial modelling and its applications (341 pp). London: Chapman and Hall.

  • Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A., & Frijters, P. (2004). How important is methodology for the estimates of the determinants of happiness? The Economic Journal, 114(July), 641–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frijters, P., Johnston, D. W., & Shields, M. A. (2011). Life satisfaction dynamics with quarterly life event data. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 113(1), 190211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frijters, P., & Beatton, T. (2012). The mystery of the U-shaped relationship between happiness and age. Journal of Economic Behvaior & organization, 82(23), 525542.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gradstein, M., & Justman, M. (2002). Education, social cohesion, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1192–1204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastie, T. J., & Tibshirani, R. J. (1990). Generalized additive models. New York: Chapman and Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huxley, P., Mishra, T., Ouattara, B., Parhi, M. (2013). Understanding Determinants of Happiness under Uncertainty. Working Papers 02–13, Association Franaise de Cliométrie (AFC).

  • Lindh, T., & Malmberg, B. (2007). Demographically based global income forecasts up to the year 2050. International Journal of Forecasting, 23(4), 553–567.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lu, L., & Gilmour, R. (2004). Culture and conceptions of happiness: Individual oriented and social oriented SWB. Journal of Happiness Studies, 5, 269–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nychka, D., Ellner, S., Gallant, A. R., & McCaffrey, D. (1992). Finding chaos in noisy systems. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series B, 54, 399–426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Okulicz-Kozaryn, A. (2011). Geography of European life satisfaction. Social Indicators Research, 101(3), 435–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rayo, L., & Becker, G. S. (2007). Evolutionary efficiency and happiness. Journal of Political Economy, 115(2), 302–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, P. (1995). Log-periodogram regression of time series with long range dependence. Annals of Statistics, 23, 1048–1072.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shintani, M. (2006). A nonparametric measure of convergence towards purchasing power parity. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 21, 589–604.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shintani, M., & Linton, O. (2003). Is there Chaos in the World economy? A Nonparametric Test using consistent standard errors. International Economic Review, 44(1), 331–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2008). Economic growth and subjective well-being: Reassessing the Easterlin Paradox. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Economic Studies Program, 39(1), 1–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven, R. (2012). Cross-national differences in happiness: Cultural measurement bias or effect of culture? International Journal of Wellbeing, 2(4), 333–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Landeghem, B. (2012). A test for the convexity of human well-being over the life cycle: Longitudinal evidence from a 20-year panel. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81, 571582.

    Google Scholar 

  • Welsch, H. (2006). Environment and happiness: Valuation of air pollution using life satisfaction data. Ecological Economics, 58:4, 801–813.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tapas Mishra.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mishra, T., Parhi, M. & Fuentes, R. How Interdependent are Cross-Country Happiness Dynamics?. Soc Indic Res 122, 491–518 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-014-0692-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-014-0692-9

Keywords

  • Inertia
  • Happiness persistence
  • Relative income
  • Convergence
  • Spatial dynamics