Skip to main content
Log in

Institutional Quality and Generalized Trust: A Nonrecursive Causal Model

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the association between institutional quality and generalized trust. Despite the importance of the topic, little quantitative empirical evidence exists to support either unidirectional or bidirectional causality for the reason that cross-sectional studies rarely model the reciprocal relationship between institutional quality and generalized trust. Using data from the World Values Survey, World Bank, and other data sources in an identified nonrecursive structural equation model, results show that generalized trust and institutional quality form a positive reciprocal relationship, where the connection is stronger from generalized trust to institutional quality. The conclusion discusses implications for theory and policy in this area.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Uslaner (2008) for a similar argument. In this article, Uslaner shows that current levels of trust in the US can, to a large extent, be traced back to the 1930s and 1940s. This suggests that at least a part of the trust observed is prior to contemporary government. Moreover, considering that trust tends to be fairly stable across time (e.g., Bjørnskov 2007), then the trust-institutions relationship identified in prior research is, at most, bidirectional and, at least, unidirectional from trust to political-institutions.

  2. The dataset has individual-level information for 66 countries (when considering missing data and the variables I use).

  3. I use multiple imputation techniques found in Stata 10.1 to maintain statistical power and a sizable country level sample. I imputed data for the legal property rights (Belarus, Bosnia, Moldova, and Saudi Arabia) and income inequality (Bosnia, Malta, Netherlands, Saudi Arabia, Serbia, and Slovakia) measures. Note that none of the imputed variables have greater than 10 percent missing cases. Also note that I created 1,000 complete data sets with the missing values filled in with different imputations. The values for the missing data were the mean of the 1,000 values across these data sets. Unlike traditional multiple imputation techniques, I did not take into account uncertainty as represented by the variation across the multiple imputations for each missing value since EQS does not permit such a procedure. I used this procedure instead of the maximum likelihood procedure found in EQS to reduce model complexity.

  4. I ignore particularized trust in the present analysis since the bulk of research in this area is primarily concerned with investigating the relationship between political institutions and generalized trust. For recent research exploring the determinants of particularized trust see Freitag and Traunmüller (2009), Glanville and Paxton (2007), Gleave et al. (2011), and Radnitz et al. (2009).

  5. I also focus on elements of government dealing with fairness and effectiveness since the results of alternative investigatory and confirmatory factor analyses suggest that measures of government should be treated as three separate dimensions: fairness and effectiveness, power-sharing capacity, and universality. This indicates that including, for instance, (a) the Polity IV measure of democracy and the Freedom House measure of political rights (i.e., power-sharing capacity), (b) the World Bank measure of public health expenditures and income inequality (i.e., universality), and (c) the legal property rights and rule of law measures (i.e., fairness and effectiveness) into one dimension is unwarranted. In fact, these indicators should be used only for their respective dimensions. Results available upon request.

  6. It is often more desirable to use tetrachoric or polychoric correlation matrix estimation techniques instead of maximum-likelihood with dichotomous scaled data (Nunnally and Bernstein 1994). This is especially the case for CFAs and only the case for SEMs if the categorical measures are endogenous. Since the categorical indicators in the present article are exogenous, I conducted an alternative CFA with a polychoric correlation matrix estimation procedure. The alternative results parallel those presented here. As a result, I present the maximum-likelihood CFA estimates; results available upon request.

  7. Although small samples are common in the SEM literature (see MacCallum and Austin 2000), there is little consensus on recommended sample sizes. Kline (2005) notes that “…with less than 100 cases, almost any type of SEM analysis may be untenable unless a very simple model is evaluated” (p. 15). In other words, technical problems, such as non-convergence, and issues of statistical power are more likely to occur with small samples. Note, however, that convergence and maximum likelihood solutions were not an issue in any Table 2 model; all coefficients in our final model were statistically significant (see Table 3); and all evaluated models were simple. This suggests that sample size likely did not bias the present findings.

  8. This is a routine practice in the SEM literature to assume zero measurement error for single indicator factors, especially when there are no prior estimates of measurement error in the literature to abstract and assume a reasonable non-zero measurement error. I did, however, analyze the models with varying levels of assumed measurement error estimates, from 0.01 to 0.3, for both generalized trust and monarchy. As expected, measurement error in generalized trust produced underestimation of the β coefficient. Also, as expected, measurement error in monarchy above 0.05 produced weak instrument effects, resulting in either biased estimates, lack of bidirectional or even unidirectional significance between generalized trust and institutional quality, or maximum likelihood convergence issues. These results suggest that some minor unobserved measurement error in the generalized trust and monarchy indicators will not bias the results presented below. For instance, an assumed measurement error of 0.02 for both indicators yielded results similar to those found in Fig. 1.

  9. For model 1, Table 2, I also controlled for gross domestic product, which did not significantly influence generalized trust, but it did, however, affect other relationships in the model. It was highly correlated with both the information technologies and institutional quality dimensions (r > 0.77), which resulted in discriminant validity issues and difficulties in converging on a solution associated with the small sample size (n = 64). As a result, I left gross domestic product out of the analysis since both information technologies and institutional quality capture a large portion of its variance. Results are available upon request.

  10. I analyzed a number of alternative models to further test the sensitivity of the results. First, some of the variables, specifically legal property rights and income inequality, had less than 10% missing cases. In the original analyses, I used multiple imputation techniques found in Stata 10.1 to overcome this issue. To see if the imputed data may have biased the results, I re-analyzed the models in Table 2 using listwise deletion with the missing cases, which yielded an N of 58. The results indicated that none of the key path coefficients deviated from those presented in Tables 2 and 3. Second, I also explored model-based imputation methods available in EQS 6.1 (Bentler 2003). This method replaces a missing score with an imputed value drawn from a full information maximum-likelihood predictive distribution. Although models 2 through 5 had difficulty converging on a solution, the model in Fig. 1 converged, which paralleled the significant positive feedback effect found therein. Third, and finally, I investigated the pairwise deletion option found EQS 6.1, which did not substantively alter the results presented here.

  11. To explore whether 2SLS or generalized method of moments (GMM) is more appropriate for the following instrument validity tests, I used the ivhettest found with ivreg2 in Stata 10.1. Both tests failed to reject the null hypothesis that the disturbance terms are homoskedastic (information technologies instrument, p = 0.11; monarchy instrument, p = 0.88). This indicates that the use of classic 2SLS is efficient and robust.

  12. I use the following syntax in Stat 10.1 for ivreg2 and ivregress, respectively: ivreg2 generalized_trust monarchy (institutional_quality = information_technologies) ivregress 2sls generalized_trust monarchy (institutional_quality = information_technologies).

  13. I use the following syntax in Stat 10.1 for ivreg2 and ivregress, respectively: ivreg2 institutional_quality information_technologies (generalized_trust = monarchy) ivregress 2sls institutional_quality information_technologies (generalized_trust = monarchy).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2005). Understanding institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 969–995.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ahn, T.-K., Ostrom, E., Schmidt, E., & Walker, J. (2003). Trust in two-person games: Game structures and linkages. In E. Ostrom & J. Walker (Eds.), Trust and reciprocity. New York: Russell Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62, 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Ferrara, E. L. (2002). Who trusts others? Journal of Public Economics, 85, 207–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almond, G. A., & Verba, S. (1963). The civic culture: Political attitudes and democracy in five nations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1972). Gifts and exchanges. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 1, 343–367.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asher, H. B. (1983). Causal modeling. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baum, C. F., Schaffer, M. E., & Stillman, S. (2007). IVREG2: Stata module for extended instrumental variables/2SLS, GMM and AC/HAC, LIML and K-class regression. http://ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s425401.html.

  • Bentler, P. M. (2003). EQS 6.1 for windows [Computer Software]. Encino, CA: Multivariate Software.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bentler, P. M., & Raykov, T. (2000). On measures of explained variance in nonrecursive structural equation models. Journal of Applied Psychology, 85, 125–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N., & Jordahl, H. (2006). Free to trust: Economic freedom and social capital. Kyklos, 59, 141–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergh, A., & Bjørnskov, C. (2011). Historical trust levels predict the current size of the welfare state. Kyklos, 64, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C. (2007). Determinants of generalized trust: A cross-country comparison. Public Choice, 130, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C. (2008). Social trust and fractionalization: A possible reinterpretation. European Sociological Review, 24, 271–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C. (2010). How does social trust lead to better governance? An attempt to separate electoral and bureaucratic mechanisms. Public Choice, 144, 323–346.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C., & Posner, D. N. (1998). Social capital: Explaining its origins and effects on government performance. British Journal of Political Science, 4, 686–693.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollen, K. A. (1996). An alternative two stage least squares (2SLS) estimator for latent variable equations. Psychometrika, 61, 109–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollen, K. A. (2001). Two-stage least squares and latent variable models: Simultaneous estimation and robustness to misspecifications. In R. Cudeck, S. Du Toit, & D. Sorbom (Eds.), Structural equation modeling: Present and future. Lincolnwood, IL: Scientific Software International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bollen, K. A., & Curran, P. J. (2006). Latent curve models: A structural equation perspective. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bollen, K. A., & Paxton, P. (1998). Interactions of latent variables in structural equation models. Structural Equation Modeling, 5, 267–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brehm, J., & Rahn, W. (1997). Individual-level evidence for the causes and consequences of social capital. American Journal of Political Science, 41, 999–1023.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CIA. (2006). World factbook 2006. Langley: Central Intelligence Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, K. S., Hardin, R., & Levi, M. (2005). Cooperation without trust?. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. (1971). Polyarchy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delhey, J., & Newton, K. (2005). Predicting cross-national levels of social trust: Global pattern or Nordic exceptionalism? European Sociological Review, 21, 311–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinesen, P. T. (2010). A note on the measurement of generalized trust of immigrants and natives. Social Indicators Research. doi:10.1007/s11205-010-9704-6.

  • Erikson, E., & Parent, J. M. (2007). Central authority and order. Sociological Theory, 25, 245–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ermisch, J., Gambetta, D., Laurie, H., Siedler, T., & Uhrig, S. C. N. (2009). Measuring people’s trust. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 172, 749–769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, H., & Knight, J. (2003). Trust, institutions, and institutional change: Industrial districts and the social capital hypothesis. Politics and Society, 31, 537–566.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foreman-Peck, J. (1995). A history of the world economy. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freitag, M., & Bühlmann, M. (2009). Crafting trust. The role of political institutions in a comparative perspective. Comparative Political Studies, 12, 1537–1566.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freitag, M., & Traunmüller, R. (2009). Spheres of trust: An empirical analysis of the foundations of particularized and generalized trust. European Journal of Political Research, 48, 782–803.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L., Laibson, D. L., Scheinkman, J. A., & Soutter, C. L. (2000, August). Measuring trust. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 811–847.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glanville, J., & Paxton, P. (2007). How do we learn to trust? A confirmatory tetrad analysis of the sources of generalized trust. Social Psychology Quarterly, 70, 230–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleave, E., Robbins, B., & Kolko, B. (2011). Trust in Uzbekistan. International Political Science Review. doi:10.1177/0192512110379491.

  • Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., & Samida, D. (2000). Economic freedom of the world 2000: Annual report. http://www.freetheworld.com.

  • Hair, J. F., Anderson, R. E., Tatham, R. L., & Black, W. (1998). Multivariate cata analysis. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herreros, F. (2004). The problems of forming social capital. Why trust?. New York and Houndmills: Palgrave.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Herreros, F., & Criado, H. (2008). The state and the development of social trust. International Political Science Review, 29, 53–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holm, H. J., & Danielson, A. (2005). Tropic trust versus Nordic trust: Experimental evidence from Tanzania and Sweden. Economic Journal, 115, 505–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu, L., & Bentler, P. M. (1999). Cutoff criteria for fit indexes in covariance structure analysis: Conventional criteria versus new alternatives. Structural Equation Modeling, 6, 1–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart, R. (1988). The renaissance of political culture. American Political Science Review, 82, 1203–1230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart, R. (1990). Culture shift in advanced industrial society. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kashima, E. S., & Kashima, Y. (1998). Culture and language: The case of cultural dimensions and personal pronoun use. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 29, 461–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2003). Governance matters III: Governance indicators for 19962002. World Bank: Policy Research working paper 3106.

  • Kline, R. B. (2005). Principles and practice of structural equation modeling (2nd ed.). New York, NY: Guilford Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S. (1992). Civic norms, social sanctions, and voter turnout. Rationality and Society, 4, 133–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S. (2002). Social capital and the quality of government: Evidence from the states. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 772–785.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 1251–1288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S., & Zak, P. J. (2002). Building trust: Public policy, interpersonal trust, and economic development. Supreme Court Economic Review, 10, 91–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumlin, S., & Rothstein, B. (2005). Making and breaking social capital: The impact of welfare state institutions. Comparative Political Studies, 38, 339–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). Trust in large organizations. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 87, 333–338.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lederman, D., Loayza, N., & Menéndez, A. M. (2002). Violent crime: Does social capital matter? Economic Development and Cultural Change, 50, 509–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Letki, N. (2006). Investigating the roots of civic morality: Trust, social capital, and institutional performance. Political Behavior, 28, 305–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levi, M. (1998). A state of trust. In V. Braithwaite & M. Levi (Eds.), Trust and governance. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1977). Democracy in plural societies. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacCallum, R. C., & Austin, J. T. (2000). Applications of structural equation modeling in psychological research. Annual Review of Psychology, 51, 201–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, A. S., & Mitamura, T. (2003). Are surveys on trust trustworthy? Social Psychology Quarterly, 66, 62–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muller, E. N., & Seligson, M. A. (1994). Civic culture and democracy: The question of causal relationships. American Political Science Review, 88, 635–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munck, G. L., & Verkuilen, J. (2002). Conceptualizing and measuring democracy: Evaluating alternative ideas. Comparative Political Studies, 35, 5–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray, M. P. (2006). The bad, the weak, and the ugly: Avoiding the pitfalls of instrumental variables estimation. SSRN.

  • Nannestad, P. (2008). What have we learned about generalized trust, if anything? Annual Review of Political Science, 11, 413–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunnally, J. C., & Bernstein, I. H. (1994). Psychometric theory (3rd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, M., & Taylor, A. M. (2003). Global capital markets: Growth and integration. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Cox, J., Walker, J., Castillo, A. J., Coleman, E., Holahan, R., et al. (2009). Trust in private and common property experiments. Southern Economic Journal, 75, 957–975.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paxton, P. (2002). Social capital and democracy: An interdependent relationship. American Journal of Sociology, 67, 254–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paxton, P. (2007). Association memberships and generalized trust: A multilevel model across 31 countries. Social Forces, 86, 47–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Radnitz, S., Wheatley, S., & Zürcher, C. (2009). The origins of social capital: Evidence from a survey of post-soviet central Asia. Comparative Political Studies, 42, 707–732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reeskens, T., & Hooghe, M. (2008). Cross-cultural measurement equivalence of generalized trust. Evidence from the European Social Survey (2002 and 2004). Social Indicators Research, 85, 515–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, B. (2011). Neither government nor community alone: A test of state-centered models of generalized trust. Rationality and Society (forthcoming).

  • Robbins, B., & Grigoryeva, M. (2010a). Technology: A bane or boon for cross-national levels of generalized trust? In A. Gerbasi & D. Latusek (Eds.), Trust and technology in a ubiquitous modern environment: Theoretical and methodological perspectives. Hershey, PA: IGI Global.

  • Robbins, B., & Grigoryeva, M. (2010b). Information technology, political institutions, and generalized trust: An empirical assessment using structural equation models. International Journal of Dependable and Trustworthy Information Systems, 1(2), 55–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, B., & Pettinicchio, D. (2011). Social capital, economic development, and homicide: A cross-national investigation. Social Indicators Research. doi:10.1007/s11205-011-9785-x.

  • Rothstein, B. (2000). Trust, social dilemmas and collective memories. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 12, 477–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein, B., & Stolle, D. (2003). Social capital, impartiality and the welfare state: An institutional approach. In M. Hooghe & D. Stolle (Eds.), Generating social capital. NewYork, NY: Palgrave.

  • Rothstein, B., & Stolle, D. (2008). How political institutions create and destroy social capital: An institutional theory of generalized trust. Comparative Politics, 40(4), 441–459.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein, B., & Uslaner, E. M. (2005). All for all: Equality, corruption, and social trust. World Politics, 58, 41–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sapienza, P., Toldra, A., & Zingales, L. (2007). Understanding trust. NBER working paper no. 13387, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). Cambridge, MA.

  • Sovey, A., & Green, D. (2011). Instrumental variables estimation in political science: A reader’s guide. American Journal of Political Science, 55, 188–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staiger, D., & Stock, J. (1997). Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica, 65, 557–586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J., & Yogo, M. (2005). Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. In D. W. K. Andrews & J. H. Stock (Eds.), Identification and inference for econometric models: Essays in honor of Thomas Rothenberg. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sturgis, P., & Smith, P. (2010). Assessing the validity of generalized trust questions: What kind of trust are we measuring? International Journal of Public Opinion Research, 22, 74–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabachnick, B. G., & Fidell, L. S. (1996). Using multivariate statistics. New York: Harper Collins College Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini, G. (2007). Institutions and culture. IGIER working paper series no. 330.

  • Thöni, C., Tyran, J.-R., & Wengström, E. (2009). Microfoundations of social capital. Univ. of Copenhagen Dept. of Economics discussion paper no. 09–24. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1491500.

  • Tilly, C. (1975). The formation of national states in western Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tocqueville, A. D. (2000 [1863]). Democracy in America. University of Chicago Press.

  • Torpe, L,. & Lolle, H. (2010). Identifying social trust in cross-country analysis: Do we really measure the same? Social Indicators Research. doi:10.1007/s11205-010-9713-5.

  • Tsai, M.-C., Laczko, L., & Bjornskov, C. (2011). Social diversity, institutions and trust: A cross-national analysis. Social Indicators Research, 101, 305–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uslaner, E. M. (2002). The moral foundations of trust. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uslaner, E. M. (2008). Where you stand depends upon where your grandparents sat: The inheritability of generalized trust. Public Opinion Quarterly, 72, 725–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Oorschot, W., & Arts, W. (2005). The social capital of European welfare states. The crowding out hypothesis revisited. Journal of European Social Policy, 15, 5–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1921 [1978]). Economy and society. University of California Press.

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P., & Knack, S. (2001). Trust and growth. Economic Journal, 111, 207–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank Maria Grigoryeva, Jerald Herting, Edgar Kiser, and Margaret Levi for helpful conversations. I also gratefully acknowledge Alex Michalos and the anonymous reviewers for valuable suggestions and comments. Any errors, as always, are my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Blaine G. Robbins.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Sensitivity Analysis I: Instrument Validity

I conducted a number of tests in Stata 10.1 using the ivregress and ivreg2 commands to determine the relevance of the instrumental variables (Baum et al. 2007).Footnote 11 Instruments must first and foremost be correlated with Y and uncorrelated with ε in the following equation:

$$ Y = \beta_{1} X_{1} + \beta_{2} W_{1} + \varepsilon $$

where Y is the dependent variable of interest, X 1 is the troublesome causal variable, and W 1 is a vector of non-troublesome covariates. If, however, possible instruments are uncorrelated with Y and/or correlated with ε then these instruments are invalid and should be discarded. I find that information technologies are significantly correlated with generalized trust (r = 0.38, p < 0.05) and uncorrelated with the error term (r = 0.03, p > 0.05) in the equation below:

$$ {\text{Generalized Trust}} = \beta_{1} *{\text{Institutional Quality}} + \beta_{2} *{\text{Monarchy}} + \varepsilon $$

This suggests that the information technologies dimension is a promising instrument for institutional quality (Murray 2006). Furthermore, the first-stage regression analysis reveals that the partial R 2 for institutional quality, where information technologies is the instrumental variable, has a relatively high value of 0.59.Footnote 12 A test of underidentification (i.e., Anderson LM test) reveals that p = 0.000, suggesting that I can reject the null hypothesis that the equation is underidentified. That is, the model is identified. Moreover, the Cragg-Donald F statistic [(1, 61) = 88.00] is well above the typical single endogenous regressor cut-off value of 10.0 (Staiger and Stock 1997; Stock and Yogo 2005), which shows that I can reject the null hypothesis that information technologies are weak. Thus, information technologies do not suffer from a weak-instrument problem. In regards to over-identification, no formal tests, such as Sargan’s or Hansen J statistic, are necessary since the equation is exactly identified (i.e., the number of instruments does not exceed the number of endogenous variables). Finally, checking the Fig. 1 Lagrange Multiplier (LM) in EQS 6.1 revealed that the overall model chi-square would not significantly decrease if a fixed-to-zero path from information technologies to generalized trust was freely estimated. This provides more evidence for information technologies as an instrument and that the model in Fig. 1 is properly specified. (Table 4).

Table 4 Results of confirmatory factor analysis for measures

In regards to monarchy, I find that it is significantly correlated with institutional quality (r = 0.49, p < 0.05) and uncorrelated with the error term (r = 0.12, p > 0.05) in the equation below, suggesting that it is a promising instrument:

$$ {\text{Institutional Quality}} = \beta_{1} *{\text{Generalized Trust }} + \beta_{2} *{\text{Information Technologies }} + \varepsilon $$

The first-stage regression analysis also reveals that the partial R 2 for generalized trust, where monarchy is the instrumental variable, has a relatively low value of 0.16.Footnote 13 Although this suggests that monarchy may be a weak instrument, the Cragg-Donald F statistic [(1, 61) = 11.11] is above the typical single endogenous regressor 10.0 cut-off value, indicating that monarchy is not a weak instrument. The Anderson LM test for underidentification shows that I can reject the null hypothesis that the equation is underidentified (p = 0.0017). Once again, no tests are necessary to determine over-identification since the equation is exactly identified. Finally, the Fig. 1 Lagrange Multiplier (LM) paralleled those for the information technologies instrument: the overall model chi-square would not significantly decrease if a fixed-to-zero path from monarchy to institutional quality was freely estimated. All of this provides firm diagnostic evidence, beyond the theoretical and historical reasons outlined in the paper, for monarchy as an instrument.

1.2 Sensitivity Analysis II: Alternative Instruments

I also examined a number of alternative IVs for generalized trust. Recent studies by Bergh and Bjørnskov (2011), Bjørnskov (2010) and Tabellini (2007) propose such IVs. Drawing on Kashima and Kashima (1998), Tabellini argues that countries where respect for individual rights is weak also have languages that permit dropping of the personal pronoun, or “pro-dropping.” This suggests that a greater emphasis on collective identity and common rights will occur in countries where “pro-dropping” is forbidden, which should increase generalized trust. The second instrument, used by Bjørnskov, is the average temperature in the coldest month of the year. The theoretical and historical argument here is that a country with harsh winters creates a greater demand for individuals and small groups to depend on strangers outside of their particularized social network for survival. Those in need during cold winters would likely receive help from strangers, while those in countries with milder winters could exclusively rely on their immediate family and friends for survival. The result is a historical development of generalized trust in those societies with colder winters.

I subject these alternative instruments to the same diagnostic test outlined above. “Pro-dropping” is coded as a binary variable, where “1” equals a license to pro-drop in the country’s official language, while “0” equals otherwise. The temperature instrument is a continuous variable that measures a country’s average temperature (Celsius) in the coldest month of the year. When using these alternative IVs, the key results paralleled those presented in Fig. 1, yet failed many of the diagnostic tests. The alternative IVs suffered from (a) underidentification (only temperature, p = 0.70); (b) weak instrument problems where the Cragg-Donald F statistic was well below the typical cut-off value of 10.0 (pro-drop, F = 6.9; temperature, F = 0.14; both, F = 3.38); (c) weak partial-R 2 (pro-drop, R 2 = 0.10; temperature, R 2 = 0.002; both, R 2 = 0.10); and (d) significantly correlated disturbance terms in the SEM (only if pro-drop was in the equation). In addition, pro-drop was significantly correlated with the error term (ε) in the following equation:

$$ {\text{Institutional Quality}} = \beta_{1} *{\text{Generalized Trust}} + \beta_{2} *{\text{Information Technologies }} + \varepsilon $$

I also examined diagnostics with the alternative instruments coupled with monarchy. The best combination of instruments was monarchy and pro-drop. Although the instruments produced identification (p = 0.001) and a moderate partial-R 2 of 0.22, the overall model fit was worse than model 1 in Table 2, the Cragg-Donald F statistic was below the cut-off value of 10.0 (F = 8.23), the Sargan test statistic suggested overidentification (p = 0.02), and the generalized trust and institutional quality disturbance terms were significantly correlated. As a result, these instruments were excluded from the analysis in favor of monarchy.

In the end, monarchy was chosen because of theoretical and historical reasons, which were also supported empirically: all alternative instruments failed other tests and explained less model variation in comparison to monarchy (i.e., monarchy yielded the lowest model IFI, CFI, SRMR and RMSEA) but generated similar results to those found in Fig. 1 with respect to the feedback loop between institutional quality and generalized trust. Results for all of the above analyses, as always, are available upon request.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Robbins, B.G. Institutional Quality and Generalized Trust: A Nonrecursive Causal Model. Soc Indic Res 107, 235–258 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-011-9838-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-011-9838-1

Keywords

Navigation