Skip to main content
Log in

Assessing the value of patent portfolios: an international country comparison

  • Published:
Scientometrics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Patent counts have been extensionally used to measure the innovative capacities of countries. However, since economic values of patents may differ, simple patent counts may give misleading rankings, if the patents of one country are on average more valuable than those of another. In the literature several methods have been proposed, which shall adjust for these differences. However, often these do not possess a solid economic micro-foundation and therefore are often ad-hoc and arbitrary procedures. In this paper, we intend to present an adjustment method that is based on the analysis of renewal decisions. The method builds on the theoretical model used in Schankerman and Pakes (1986) and Besson (2008) but goes beyond both approaches in that it recovers the important long tail of the value distribution. It also transfers Besson’s (2008) econometric methodology (applicable to the organisational structures of the US Patent and Trademark Office) also to the European Patent Office which is necessary, since each application here may split up into several national patent documents. The analysis is performed for 22 countries. Exemplarily, we find that in the cohort of 1986 patent applications, Danish patents are about 60% more valuable than the average patent. German patents are a bit below average. Japanese patents are of least value. In the cohort of 1996, Danish patents lose some of their lead but are still more valuable than the average. While German are a bit above average, Japanese patents even fall further behind (possibly due to the economic downturn in since the mid of 1990ies).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The most important difference is that his formulae depend on a hard to measure rate of depreciation rate. This actually occurs also in formulae 3 and 5, but it drops out, when we focus on the patent value instead on the return rate.

  2. There is probably no use in employing more recent data, because the majority of patents expire after 13–14 years (see Table 2). Moving closer to the present will therefore result in a severe increase of the share of censored patent values.

  3. Note that Bessen focuses on the initial return rate. But since this is a somewhat fuzzy concept, we prefer rather to make assumption about the patent value.

  4. Note, however, one subtlety. We do not impose a fixed censoring limit (for example the observed initial return rate is censored, if it takes a value y), but we allow patents to have different censoring values. This more general statement is necessary, because the total renewal costs and thus the according patent values differ by patent office.

  5. This number should roughly correspond to the number of patents that were finally granted, because the number of patents that were granted by the EPO but never appeared at European Patent office should be low.

  6. The latest ISI high-tech list (Legler and Frietsch 2007) provides a classification of both sectors (based on NACE) and goods (based on SITC) according to their technology-intensiveness. Based on the SITC goods classification a concordance to the International Patent Classification (IPC) can be constructed. This concordance table contains 35 particularly technology-intensive fields. The dummies used on this study are fractionalised, which results from the fact that each patent can have several IPC classifications. Suppose for example that a patent has two classification in high-tech-field 1 (HT1), one classification in high-tech-field 2 (HT2) and one classification in a field that does not belong to the ISI high-tech list (LOWTECH), the fractionalised dummy for HT1 would be 0.5, for HT2 it would be 0.25 and for LOWTECH 0.25. The sum over all dummies is therefore unity.

  7. This number is quite large, because the Inpadoc family does not only contain patent documents at different national offices referring to the same invention but also different patents that somehow belong together, e.g., when patents are split up later on in the patenting process.

  8. If we do that by country, e.g., for France, then μ and \( \sigma_{x\beta }^{2} \) are replaced with the corresponding mean and variance in the subsample of French patents.

  9. We should note, however, that using the value adjustment factors to reweight simple patent counts is retrospective, in that they extrapolate structures from the past: they critically depend on both the explanatory variables x as well as the estimated coefficients β. Therefore, whenever either the distribution of the explanatory variables in one country changes (e.g. French patents may be cited more frequently) or the structure of the regression model expressed by the coefficients changes, then the value adjustment factor needs to be re-estimated. In any case, looking at Table 3 tells us that coefficients appear to not to change excessively. Thus, it seems not too critical to extrapolate them to the present. More likely is that changes in the distributions of the explaining variables account for differences in the value adjustment factor. If we, for example, would like to deduce the VAF for patents with priority year 2005, we could take the coefficients from the regression model corresponding to the data from 1996. We would then use them to derive predicted values for 2005. With these at hand, we again use Eq. 2 to derive value adjustment factor. This procedure clearly implies the constancy of coefficients but it allows for changes in the distributions of the explaining factors. In any case, we cannot exclude the existence of a structural change after 1996. It is well known that this is the time of the patent-surge, which might have induced more severe changes in the regression model. However, this remains to be seen when more recent data becomes available.

References

  • Allison, J. R., Lemley, M. A., Moore, K. A., & Trunkey, E. D. (2004). Valuable patents. The Georgetown Law Journal, 92, 436–479.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bass, S.D., Kurgan, L.A. (2010). Discovery of factors influencing patent value based on machine learning in patents in the field of nanotechnology. Scientometrics, 82(2), 217–241.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bessen, J. (2008). The value of U.S. patents by owner and patent characteristics. Research Policy, 37, 932–945.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blind, K., Edler, J., Frietsch, R., & Schmoch, U. (2006). Motives to patent empirical evidence from Germany. Research, 35, 655–672.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davison, A. C., & Hinkley, D. V. (1997). Bootstrap methods and their application. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • De la Potterie, B. V., & van Zeebroeck, N. (2008). A brief history of space and time: The scope-year index as a patent value indicator based on families and renewals. Scientometrics, 75, 319–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J., Kortum, S., Lerner, J. (2004). International patenting and the European patent office: A quantitative assessment. Patents, innovation and economic performance: OECD conference proceedings (pp. 27–52), Paris.

  • Frietsch, R., & Schmoch, U. (2009). Transnational patents and international markets. Scientometrics, 82, 185–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gambardella, A., Harhoff, D., & Verspagen, B. (2008). The value of European patents. European Management Review, 5, 69–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimpe, C., Hussinger, K. (2008). Building and blocking the two faces of technology acquisition, ZEW-discussion paper, no. 08-042. Mannheim: Centre for European Economic Research.

  • Grönqvist, C. (2009). The private value of patents by patent characteristics evidence from Finland. Journal of Technology Transfer, 34, 159–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grupp, H., Legler, H., Jungmittag, A., Schmoch, U. (2000). Hochtechnologie 2000. Neudefinition der Hochtechnologie für die Berichterstattung zur technologischen Leistungsfähigkeit. Deutschlands: Karlsruhe/Hannover Fraunhofer ISI.

  • Hall, B. W., Jaffe, A., & Trajtenberg, M. (2005). Market value and patent citations. The Rand Journal of Economics, 36, 16–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff, D., Narin, F., Scherer, F. M., & Vopel, K. (1999). Citation frequency and the value of patented inventions. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 511–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff, D., Scherer, F. M., & Vopel, K. (2003). Citations, family size, opposition and the value of patent rights. Research Policy, 32, 1343–1363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lanjouw, J. O., Pakes, A., & Putnam, J. (1998). How to count patents and value intellectual property the uses of patent renewal and application data. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 46, 405–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lanjouw, J.O., Schankerman, M. (1997). Stylized facts of patent litigation value, scope, ownership, NBER working paper no. 6297. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Lee, Y. G. (2009). What affects a patent’s value? An analysis of variables that affect technological, direct economic, and indirect economic value: An exploratory conceptual approach. Scientometrics, 79, 623–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Legler, H., Frietsch, R. (2007). Neuabgrenzung der Wissenswirtschaft—forschungsintensive Industrien und wissensintensive Dienstleistungen, Bundesministerium fuer Bildung und Forschung (BMBF) (Ed.), Studien zum deutschen Innovationssystem No. 22-2007, Berlin.

  • Merges, R. P. (1999). As many as six impossible patents before breakfast property rights for business concepts and patent system reform. Berkeley Technology Law Journal, 14, 577–616.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, M. (1999). Does science push technology? Patents citing scientific literature. Research Policy, 29, 409–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narin, F. (1995). Patents as indicators for the evaluation of industrial research output. Scientometrics, 34, 489–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narin, F., Noma, E., & Perry, R. (1987). Patents as indicators of corporate technological strength. Research Policy, 16, 143–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam. J. (1996). The value of international patent rights. Ph.D. Thesis. Yale: Yale University.

  • Sampat, B.N., Ziedonis, A.A. (2004). Patent citations and the economic value of patents, in H.F. Moed, W. Glänzel, U. Schmoch (Eds.), Handbook of quantitative science and technology research (pp. 277–300). Elsevier: Research Policy.

  • Schankerman, M. (1998). How valuable is patent protection. Estimates by technology field, Rand Journal of Economics, 29, 77–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schankerman, M., & Pakes, A. (1986). Estimates of the value of patent rights in European countries during the post-1950 period. Economic Journal, 97, 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • van der Drift, J. (1989). Statistics of European patents on legal status and granting data. World Patent Information, 11, 243–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, J. C., Chiang, C. H., & Lin, S. W. (2010). Network structure of innovation: Can brokerage or closure predict patent quality? Scientometrics, 84, 735–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Financial project support of the German Expert Commission Research and Innovation for the work underlying this article is kindly acknowledged. Helpful comments on an earlier version of this article from the 10th EPO-PATSTAT Conference in Vienna are also acknowledged. I am grateful to Nicolai Mallig for the help that he provided on collecting the necessary patent data from the PATSTAT database. Lastly, I would also like to thank an anonymous referee for his valuable suggestions that helped to improve the article.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Torben Schubert.

Appendix

Appendix

Define \( \bar{r}_{j} \) to be the initial return rate associated with a specific patent. The return rate can basically measure any return, no matter if they accrue from selling a protected product or blocking a competitor. Assume that the (non-discounted) return rate at a future point in time τ > 0 can be calculated by \( \overline{{r_{j} }} \cdot \text{e}^{ - d\tau } \), where d ≥ 0 is a deprecation rate. That is we assume that returns resulting from a patent are exponentially damped. Suppose that there are discrete points in time t i , i = 1, 2,…K, where the owner of a patent has to decide, whether he wants to renew. Denote by PV j the total value of patent j and by PV i,j the return that is attributable to the period [t i , t i+1], that is between any two dates, where renewal decisions are necessary. Letting r m be the internal rate of return (possibly but not necessarily equal to observable interest rates), then we can calculate the net present value of a patent accruing to the period [t i , t i+1] as follows:

$$ \begin{aligned} PV_{j,i} &= \int\limits_{{\tau = t_{i}}}^{{t_{i + 1} }} {\overline{{r_{j} }} {e}^{{ - \left( {r^{m} + d}\right)\tau }} d\tau }\\ &= \overline{{r_{j} }} \left({\int\limits_{\tau = 0}^{\infty } {{e}^{{ - \left( {r^{m} + d}\right)\tau }} } d\tau - \int\limits_{{\tau = t_{i + 1} }}^{\infty} {{e}^{{ - \left( {r^{m} + d} \right)\tau }} } d\tau -\int\limits_{\tau = 0}^{{t_{i} }} {{e}^{{ - \left( {r^{m} + d}\right)\tau }} } d\tau } \right)\\ &= \overline{{r_{j} }}\left( {\int\limits_{\tau = 0}^{\infty } {{e}^{{ - \left( {r^{m} +d} \right)\tau }} } d\tau - \int\limits_{{\tau = t_{i + 1}}}^{\infty } {{e}^{{ - \left( {r^{m} + d} \right)\tau }} } d\tau -\int\limits_{\tau = 0}^{\infty } {{e}^{{ - \left( {r^{m} + d}\right)\tau }} } d\tau + \int\limits_{{\tau = t_{i} }}^{\infty }{{e}^{{ - \left( {r^{m} + d} \right)\tau }} } d\tau } \right)\\&= \overline{{r_{j} }} \left( {\int\limits_{{\tau = t_{i}}}^{\infty } {{e}^{{ - \left( {r^{m} + d} \right)\tau }} } d\tau -\int\limits_{{\tau = t_{i + 1} }}^{\infty } {{e}^{{ - \left({r^{m} + d} \right)\tau }} } d\tau } \right)\\ &=\overline{{r_{j} }} \left( {\frac{{{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{i} }} -{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{i + 1} }} }}{{r^{m} + d}}} \right)\\\end{aligned} $$
(3)

Because the returns are steadily decreasing in time (by assumption) and the renewal fees are steadily increasing (as a matter of fact), a patent is renewed, if and only if \( PV_{j,i} \ge c_{i} \text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{i} }} \), where c i is the renewal fees to be paid in period i.

Now, suppose a patent is renewed in time t * but not in the next period, we trivially have \( PV_{j,i^{*} } \ge c_{i^{*} } \text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{j,i^{*}} }} \) and \( PV_{j,i^{*} + 1} \le c_{i^{*} + 1} \text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{j,i^{*} + 1} }} \). Therefore, if the periods t i and t i+1 are close together, then both PV j,i* and PV j,i*+1 do not differ by much, and we do not lose much in replacing both conditions by the following relationship:

$$ PV_{j,i^{*} } \approx c_{i^{*} } \text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{j,i^{*} } }} $$
(4)

Using 3 and 4, setting t 1 = 0 and solving for the initial return rate yields

$$ \overline{{r_{j} }} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {c_{1} \frac{{r^{m} + d}}{{1 - \text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{2} }} }}} \right)} & {lapsed} & {after} & {t_{1} } \\ {\left( {c_{2} \text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{2} }} \frac{{r^{m} + d}}{{\text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{2} }} - \text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{3} }} }}} \right)} & {lapsed} & {after} & {t_{2} } \\ \ldots & \ldots & \ldots & \ldots \\ {\left( {c_{K} \text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{K} }} \frac{{r^{m} + d}}{{\text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{K} }} - \text{e}^{{ - r^{m} t_{K + 1} }} }}} \right)} & {lapsed} & {after} & {t_{K} } \\ \end{array} } \right. $$
(5)

Plugging Eq. 5 into Eq. 3 yields Eq. 1 in Chapter 3.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Schubert, T. Assessing the value of patent portfolios: an international country comparison. Scientometrics 88, 787–804 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11192-011-0454-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11192-011-0454-2

Keywords

Navigation