Skip to main content
Log in

Entrepreneurial universities and overt opportunism

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Entrepreneurial universities are a catalyst for regional economic development and growth. Yet, the entrepreneurial university may not always capture the full gains made by the broader economy due to opportunistic behavior by its faculty scientists. We expand agency theory to address conditions when opportunistic behavior persists in the face of substantial information symmetry and where principals appear to tolerate opportunism despite the authority to sanction their agents. Using a sample of 105 US research universities and 73,603 scientists, we demonstrate that some scientists privately leak discoveries invented while working for their universities. Counter to prior prediction, we find that universities acting as principals often do not retaliate even when having knowledge of such opportunistic behavior and the capability to punish non-complying agents. To extend theory, we examined contexts that exacerbate and alleviate such overt opportunism: High-value discoveries and sizable entrepreneurial activity are associated with greater opportunistic behavior, whereas efforts to empower those who have close professional ties with scientists—their departments and technology commercialization offices—are related to reduced opportunism. To complement our empirical analyses, we provide a stylized mathematical model that shows how agency theory can improve its predictive power once it formally recognizes certain conditions under which agents wield substantial bargaining power over their principals, who in turn seem to tolerate agents’ overt opportunistic behavior.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Overt opportunism refers to agent opportunistic behavior under conditions of substantial information symmetry.

  2. To name a few, TCOs evaluate discoveries for patentability and commercial potential; facilitate the commercialization and protection of intellectual property (IP); negotiate grant-related research and licensing agreements; manage licensing income; forge relationships with scientists, industry and investors; etc. (Markman 2005b).

  3. There were different response rates for the three rounds of structured phone interviews: (1) 91 % (125 of 137), (2) 82 % (117 of 143), and (3) 71 % (105 of 147).

  4. We use the term assignee as employed by the USPTO when assigning ownership of a patent.

  5. The USPTO lists each designated inventor of the patent as the “creator” of the new knowledge embedded within the patent and the assignee as the “owner” of the issued patent.

  6. Because scientists often collaborate with scientists at other research institutions, a patent may be assigned to another university, so it is not one of overt opportunism.

  7. With few exceptions, US-based university faculty is contractually obligated to assign ownership to the university for discoveries made in university-based laboratories.

  8. Our analysis is deterministic, yet (on account of the uncertainty involved) one can equally assume that effort endows the agent with a greater probability of finding an appropriate match for the discovery. Such an approach produces equivalent results at the cost of one more parameter, shifting the emphasis on what drives this probability.

References

  • Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs and economic organization. American Economic Review, 6, 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldridge, T., & Audretsch, D. B. (2010). Does policy influence the commercialization route? Evidence from the National Institutes of Health funded scientists. Research Policy, 39(5), 583–588.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1985). Informational structure of the firm. American Economic Review, 75, 303–307.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthurs, J. D., Hoskisson, R. E., Busenitz, L. W., & Johnson, R. A. (2008). Managerial agents watching other agents: Multiple agency conflicts regarding underpricing in IPO firms. Academy of Management Journal, 51(2), 277–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aschhoff, B., & Grimpe, C. (2014). Contemporaneous peer effects, career age, and the industry involvement of academics in biotechnology. Research Policy, 43, 367–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Association of University Technology Managers. (1999–2008). The AUTM Licensing Survey: Fiscal Year 1999–2008. Norwalk, CT: Association of University Technology Managers.

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Goktepe-Hulten, D. (2015). University Patenting in Europe. In The Chicago Handbook of University Technology Transfer and Academic Entrepreneurship.

  • Audretsch, D. B., Hulsbeck, M., & Lehman, E. E. (2012). Regional competitiveness, university spillovers, and entrepreneurial activity. Small Business Economics, 39(3), 587–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Keilbach, M. (2004). Entrepreneurship capital and economic performance. Regional Studies, 38(8), 949–959.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azagra-Caro, J., Caravol, N., & Lierena, P. (2006). Patent protection at a European research university: Exploratory evidence at the laboratory level. Journal of Technology Transfer, 31(2), 257–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bercovitz, J., & Feldman, M. (2008). Academic entrepreneurs: Organizational change at the individual level. Organization Science, 19, 69–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bercovitz, J., Feldman, M., Feller, I., & Burton, R. (2001). Organizational structure as a determinant of academic patent and licensing behavior: An exploratory study of Duke, Johns Hopkins, and Pennsylvania State University. Journal of Technology Transfer, 26, 21–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J. A., Gianiodis, P. G., & Santoro, M. (2015). Following doctor’s orders: Organizational change as a response to human capital bargaining power. Organization Science, 26(5), 1284–1300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bubela, T., Vishnubhakat, S., & Cook-Deegan, R. (2015). The mouse that trolled: The long and tortuous history of a gene mutation patent that became an expensive impediment to Alzheimer’s research. Journal of Law and the Biosciences. doi:10.1093/jlb/lsv011.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, B. A., Coff, R., & Kryscynski, D. (2012). Re-thinking competitive advantage from human capital: How the concept of firm-specificity has led strategy theorists astray. Academy of Management Review, 37, 376–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coff, R. (1999). When competitive advantage doesn’t lead to performance: The resource-based view and stakeholder bargaining power. Organization Science, 10, 119–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coff, R., & Kryscynski, D. (2011). Drilling for micro-foundations of human capital-based competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 37(5), 1429–1443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conti, A., & Gaule, P. (2011). Is the US outperforming Europe in university technology licensing? A new perspective on the European Paradox. Research Policy, 40(1), 123–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Council for Community and Economic Research. (2008). ACCRA cost of living index. Washington, DC: Council for Community and Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daily, C. M., Dalton, D. R., & Cannella, A. A. (2003). Corporate governance: Decades of dialogue and data. Academy of Management Review, 28, 371–382.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, R. (2008). Business: Stepping out. Nature, 452(7184), 146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Danneels, E. (2007). The process of technological competence leveraging. Strategic Management Journal, 28, 511–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J., Schoorman, F., & Donaldson, L. (1997). Toward a stewardship theory of management. Academy of Management Review, 22, 20–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • DeVol, R. C. (1999). America’s High-tech Economy. Santa Monica, CA: Milken Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Llerena, P., & Labini, M. S. (2006). The relationships between science, technologies, and their industrial exploitation: An illustration through the myths and realities of the so-called’European Paradox’. Research Policy, 35(10), 1450–1464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisenhardt, K. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14, 57–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fini, R., Lacetera, N., & Shane, S. (2010). Inside or outside the IP system? Business creation in academia. Research Policy, 39(8), 1060–1069.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleming, L., & Sorenson, O. (2004). Science as a map in technological search. Strategic Management Journal, 25, 909–928.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, J., & Silberman, J. (2003). University technology transfer: Do incentives, management, and location matter? Journal of Technology Transfer, 28, 17–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • George, G. (2005). Slack resources and the performance of privately held firms. Academy of Management Journal, 48, 661–676.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giuliani, E., Morrison, A., Pietrobelli, C., & Rabellotti, R. (2010). Who are the researchers that are collaborating with industry? An analysis of the wine sectors in Chile, South Africa, and Italy. Research Policy, 39(6), 748–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giuri, P., et al. (2007). Inventors and invention processes in Europe: Results from the PatVal-EU survey. Research Policy, 36(8), 1107–1127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimaldi, R., Kenney, M., Siegel, D. S., & Wright, M. (2011). 30 years after Bayh–Dole: Reassessing academic entrepreneurship. Research Policy, 40(8), 1045–1057.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guerrero, M., & Peña-Legazkue, I. (2013). The effect of intrapreneurial experience on corporate venturing: Evidence from developed economies. International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 9(3), 397–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guerrero, M., & Urbano, D. (2013). Academics’ start-up intentions and knowledge filters: An individual perspective of the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 43, 57–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, J. R., Lin, Z., Carroll, G. R., & Carley, K. M. (2007). Simulation modeling in organizational and management research. Academy of Management Review, 32, 1229–1245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. J., & Richard, R. (1985) Alternative methods for evaluating the impact of interventions: An overview. Journal of econometrics, 30(1–2), 239–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hess, A. M., & Rothaermel, F. T. (2011). When are assets complementary? Star scientists, strategic alliances, and innovation in the pharmaceutical industry. Strategic Management Journal, 32, 895–909.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Johnson, R. A., & Grossman, W. (2002). Conflicting voices: The effects of institutional ownership heterogeneity and internal governance on corporate innovation strategies. Academy of Management Journal, 45, 697–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. F. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, P. H., Thomson, R., & Yong, J. (2011). Estimating the patent premium: Evidence from the Australian inventor survey. Strategic Management Journal, 32, 1128–1138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones-Evans, D., Klofsten, M., Andersson, E., & Pandya, D. (1999). Creating a bridge university and industry in small European countries: The role of the Industrial Liaison Office. R&D Management, 29, 47–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kenney, M., & Patton, D. (2009). Reconsidering the Bayh–Dole Act and the current university invention ownership model. Research Policy, 38, 1407–1422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kistruck, G. M., Sutter, C. J., Lount, R. B., & Smith, B. R. (2013). Mitigating principal-agent problems in base-of-the-pyramid markets: An identity spillover perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 56(3), 659–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klofsten, M., & Jones-Evans, D. (2000). Comparing academic entrepreneurship in Europe-The case of Sweden and Ireland. Small Business Economics, 14(4), 299–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotha, R., George, G., & Srikanth, K. (2013). Bridging the mutual knowledge gap: Coordination and the commercialization of university science. Academy of Management Journal, 56, 498–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindenberg, S., & Foss, N. (2011). Managing joint production motivation: The role of goal framing and governance mechanisms. Academy of Management Review, 36, 500–525.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lissoni, F., Llerena, P., McKelvey, M., & Sanditiv, B. (2008). Academic patenting in Europe: New evidence from the KEINS database. Research Evaluation, 17(2), 87–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowe, R. A., & Ziedonis, A. A. (2006). Overoptimism and the performance of entrepreneurial firms. Management Science, 52, 173–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney, J. T. (2005). Economic foundations of strategy. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Makadok, R., & Coff, R. (2009). Both market and hierarchy: An incentive-systems theory of hybrid governance forms. Academy of Management Review, 34(2), 297–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markman, G. D. (2015). Backdoor entrepreneurship. In D. B. Audretsch, C. S. Hayter, & A. N. Link (Eds.), Concise guide to entrepreneurship, technology, and innovation. Cambridge, MA: Edward Elgar Publishers.

  • Markman, G. D., Gianiodis, P. T., & Buchholtz, A. C. (2009a). Factor market rivalry. Academy of Management Review, 34(3), 423–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markman, G. D., Gianiodis, P. T., & Phan, H. P. (2008). Fulltime faculty or part-time entrepreneurs. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 55, 29–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markman, G. D., Gianiodis, P. T., & Phan, H. P. (2009b). Supply-side innovation and technology commercialization. Journal of Management Studies, 46(4), 625–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markman, G. D., Gianiodis, P. T., Phan, H. P., & Balkin, D. B. (2005a). Speed to market as a success factor in technology transfer. Research Policy, 34, 1058–1075.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markman, G. D., Phan, H. P., Balkin, D. B., & Gianiodis, P. T. (2005b). Entrepreneurship and university-based technology transfer. Journal of Business Venturing, 20(2), 241–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meek, W. R., & Wood, M. S. (2016). Navigating a sea of change: Identity misalignment and adaptation in academic entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice.

  • Mehrota, V. (2011). Angel agents: What we can (and cannot) learn from the Pierre Lefaucheux’s stewardship of Regie Renault. Academy of Management Perspectives, 25(2), 14–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merges, R. P., & Nelson, R. R. (1990). On the complexity economics of patent scope. Columbia Law Review, 90, 839–912.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mian, S. A., Fayolle, A., & Lamine, W. (2012). Building sustainable regional platforms for incubating science and technology businesses: Evidence form US and French science and technology parks. The International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Innovation, 13, 235–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, D., & Sardois, C. (2011). Angel agents: Agency theory reconsidered. Academy of Management Perspectives, 25(2), 6–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen-Smith, J., & Powell, W. W. (2001). To Patent or not: Faculty decisions and institutional success at technology transfer. Journal of Technology Transfer, 26, 99–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perkmann, M., et al. (2013). Academic engagement and commercialization: A review of the literature on university-industry relations. Research Policy, 42(2), 423–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pitsakis, K., Souitaris, V., & Nicolaou, N. (2015). The peripheral halo effect: Do academic spinoffs influence universities’ research income? Journal of Management Studies, 52(3), 321–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothaermel, F. T., Agung, S., & Jiang, L. (2007). University entrepreneurship: A taxonomy of the literature. Industrial and Corporate Change, 16, 691–791.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S. (2001). Technology opportunities and new firm creation. Management Science, 47, 205–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S. (2004). Academic entrepreneurship: University spinoffs and wealth creation. London: Edgar Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, S. P. (2005). Agency theory. In K. S. Cook & D. S. Massey (Eds.), Annual review of sociology (Vol. 31, pp. 263–284). Palo Alto, CA: Annual Reviews.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharma, A. (1997). Professional as agent: Knowledge asymmetry in agency exchange. Academy of Management Review, 22, 758–798.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52, 737–783.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, D. S. (2006). Technology entrepreneurship: Institutions and agents involved in university technology transfer (Vol. 1). London: Edgar Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, D. S., & Wright, M. (2015). Academic entrepreneurship: Time for a rethink? British Journal of Management, 26(4), 582–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sieger, P., Zellweger, T., & Aquino, K. (2013). Turning agents into psychological principals: Aligning interests of non-owners through psychological ownership. Journal of Management Studies, 50, 361–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabachnick, B., & Fidell, L. (1996). Using multivariate statistics (3rd ed.). New York: Harper Collins College Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tartari, V., Perkmann, M., & Salter, A. (2014). In good company: The influence of peers on industry engagement by academic scientists. Research Policy, 43(7), 1189–1203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thursby, J. G., Fuller, A. W., & Thursby, M. C. (2009). U.S. faculty patenting: Inside and outside the university. Research Policy, 38, 14–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toole, A. A., & Czarnitzki, D. (2010). Commercializing Science: Is there a university “brain drain” from academic entrepreneurship? Management Science, 56, 1599–1614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Urbano, D., & Guerrero, M. (2013). Entrepreneurial universities: Socio-economic impacts of academic entrepreneurship in a European region. Economic Development Quarterly, 27(1), 40–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldrige, J. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross-section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter T. Gianiodis.

Appendix: Mathematical model that simulates the licensing strategies of a scientist

Appendix: Mathematical model that simulates the licensing strategies of a scientist

Broadly, a scientist can pursue two strategies; she can either license her invention privately (via bypassing), or through a TCO (via disclosure). For brevity, we henceforth refer to these strategies as bypassing and disclosure, respectively, and we present a model that assesses these strategies by focusing on the effort that the TCO and scientist must exert to match the invention to the licensing partner that garners the most value added. Our aim is in delineating the payoffs behind each strategy by accounting for the parameters that we have introduced. This approach allows for precise comparisons that indirectly substantiate the causal links between the main variables and the hypotheses. We find that: (I) more autonomous TCOs are associated with less bypassing; (II) higher royalty payments to scientist’s are associated with less bypassing; (III) highly professional TCOs can offer a lower share of royalties to their scientists; (IV) entrepreneurial environments are associated with greater bypassing; (V) inventions of great value are not revealed to the TCO.

Assume a rational, forward-looking, profit-maximizing scientist and a TCO of similar characteristics. The scientist has created a prototype of an invention whose full potential is difficult to assess. The profits from licensing the invention depend not only on the prototype’s initial value, but also on the value added that a licensing firm can affix to the original. However, in finding the firm that can affix the most value-added one must exert some effort.

With that in mind, allow a scientist, denoted by i, to have created a working prototype of an invention. As discoveries are initially quite rudimentary, they require further development, without which a scientist can expect only a discounted stream of future royalties R if any. However, when a discovery is licensed to a firm and developed into a usable component or final product, it can yield a greater stream of future royalties V, where V > R, to the licensor; be it the scientist or the TCO. Because firms are endowed with varying capabilities to convert discoveries into products licensors exert effort e to find suitable licensees, where the more effort licensors put into finding a suitable firm the greater the return V to the licensor.Footnote 8

Focusing on inventions for which R is greater than any transaction cost that the TCO/scientist faces; if a scientist pursues a bypassing strategy she fully appropriates the licensing proceeds π because the TCO and the university are not a party in the deal. If, on the other hand, she discloses the innovation to the TCO she garners only a share α of π; the remaining rent 1 − α goes to the TCO/university.

Since there may exist asymmetric information as to the prototype’s prospects, we denote the invention value (as viewed by the TCO) as γR, where γ ∊ R + models how proficient (compared to the scientist) the TCO is in finding a licensee that can increase the invention’s value added. The more autonomous the TCO is, and the stronger its ties with the business and scientific community, the greater the value of γ. Furthermore, regardless of licensing strategy licensors incur a search cost (denoted by c) for finding a licensee. This cost is a negative function of R (i.e. it is easier to license attractive inventions) and a positive function of e.

Focusing on bypassing, i a scientist’s profits from privately licensing her invention are,

$$\pi_{i} = V_{i} - c_{i} ,$$
(1)

Equation (1) expresses π i in terms of i’s search cost (c i ) and future stream of royalties (V i ) where V i is expressed as,

$$V_{i} = e_{i}^{\zeta } R^{1 - \zeta } .$$
(2)

Equation (2) captures V i as an increasing function of the effort e i that a scientist i exerts in finding a licensee, and R. Since ζ ∊ (0, 1) is the share of effort in the final discounted stream of royalties V, we use ζ to capture the extent to which the market is entrepreneurial. Highly entrepreneurial markets allow scientists to privately license their invention with less effort, where the optimal effort can be found as, \(e_{i}^{*} = \arg \,\max_{{e_{i} }} \pi_{i}\)

We model a scientist’s search cost for finding a licensee as,

$$c_{i} = e_{i} - R^{0.5}$$
(3)

In (3) c i is a positive function of e i , correspondingly decreasing with R, albeit in a diminishing fashion. In symmetric terms, for the disclosure strategy Eqs. (1)–(3) become

$$\pi_{\text{TLO}} = \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {V_{\text{TLO}} - c_{\text{TLO}} } \right),$$
(1′)
$$V_{\text{TLO}} = e_{\text{TLO}}^{\zeta } \left( {\gamma R} \right)^{1 - \zeta } ,$$
(2′)
$$c_{\text{TLO}} = e_{\text{TLO}} - \left( {\gamma R} \right)^{0.5}$$
(3′)

While \(e_{\text{TLO}}^{*} = \arg \max_{{e_{\text{TLO}} }} \pi_{\text{TLO}}\), solving the model, we find,

$$e_{i}^{*} = R\zeta^{{\frac{1}{1 - \zeta }}} ,\quad e_{TLO}^{*} = R\zeta^{{\frac{1}{1 - \zeta }}} .$$
(4)

Equation (4) suggests that increasing R, ζ increases the e of both agents. The same holds true for the TCO in terms of γ, i.e. autonomous TCOs exert more effort. We can use (4) in deriving π i and the payoff from the disclosure strategy, which is α(V TLO − c TLO). In turn, we can subtract the one from the other and examine the conditions under which disclosure provides a greater payoff than bypassing. In the parlance of game theory the difference between the two payoffs delineates when one strategy dominates the other. This difference, which is equal to

$$R^{0.5} \left( {\left( {1 - \alpha \gamma } \right)\zeta^{{\frac{1}{1 - \zeta }}} \left( {1 - \zeta^{ - 1} } \right)} \right) - \left( {1 - \alpha \gamma^{0.5} } \right),$$
(5)

can outline the conditions that lead the scientist to disclose her technology to the TCO or not. In simple terms, when (5) is positive disclosure is the dominant strategy. A first look at (5) reveals that the derivatives of Eq. (5) with respect to α and γ are in both cases strictly positive. This positive relationship seems to validate claims (I) and (II), i.e. TCOs that are more autonomous are associated with less bypassing, and higher payments of royalties to scientists are equally associated with less bypassing.

Furthermore, on account of the positive derivatives of (5) with respect to α and γ, via the implicit function theorem we can immediately note that there exists a negative relationship between γ and α. This negative relationship accords with claim (III), which suggests that highly professional TCOs can offer a lower share of royalties to their scientists.

Notwithstanding the above, the derivative of Eq. (5) with respect to R is not straightforward to assess. For this reason, we rearrange (5) as to determine the R for which disclosure is optimal, i.e.

$$R > \left( {\frac{{1 - \alpha \gamma^{0.5} }}{{\left( {1 - \alpha \gamma } \right)\zeta^{{\frac{1}{1 - \zeta }}} \left( {1 - \zeta^{ - 1} } \right)}}} \right)^{2} .$$
(6)

In order to uncover the relationship between the value of the invention and disclosure we plot Eq. (6) in Fig. 1. Without loss of generality, and in order to focus on the area where disclosure is dominant, Fig. 1 is plotted for a limited range of the main exogenous variables i.e. a ∊ (0, 1), γ ∊ (.9, 2), and ζ = .1.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Depiction of dominant disclosure strategy. This graph denotes the value of the licensing proceeds (R), as given by Eq. 6, which will induce disclosure, in terms of the share of the proceeds that accrue to the faculty scientist (α) and the degree of TCO autonomy (γ). Axis labels: Axis R denotes the discounted stream of future royalties; axis α denotes the share of the licensing proceeds that accrue to the scientist; axis γ denotes the degree of TCO autonomy

How changes in ζ affect Fig. 1: In Fig. 1 disclosure takes place in the area that has been labeled “This is the area in which we see faculty disclosure”. Only in this encircled parameter space Eq. (5) is positive, which is the prerequisite for disclosure being the dominant strategy. Increasing ζ diminishes the area for which disclosure is dominant by shifting it to the right. Hence, as claim (IV) suggests, entrepreneurial environments are associated with greater bypassing.

Two things are immediately apparent from Fig. 1. First, disclosure is possible only if γ > 1. Second, the area under which disclosure is dominant is not really affected by the size of R. Thus, when γ > 1 (depending on the α) inventions of all types of R will be disclosed. The latter point is due to the symmetry that we have (for simplicity) imposed on the model by assuming that both agents face similarly structured costs. In reality, there exist transaction costs that only the scientist has to incur. For example, when bypassing the scientist has to acquire a costly new set of skills (that the TCO already has) e.g. learning how to patent and how to find a licensee.

Even without replicating the math, the assumption of asymmetric transaction costs suggests that (in Fig. 1) the encircled area for which disclosure is dominant must shift to the left. In short, the scientist should be willing to disclose her invention to TCOs that have a γ less than one, and are willing to offer an α that is lower than the one depicted by the encircled part of Fig. 1. As in this region there exists a positive relationship between R and α, the more valuable an invention is the greater the α that is required to induce the scientist to reveal such an invention to the TCO. Therein lays the problem. As α faces an upper bound (because faculty scientists can appropriate only part of the licensing proceeds) for very valuable inventions, there is no α that can induce disclosure. Hence, on par with claim (V), inventions of great value are not revealed to the TCO.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gianiodis, P.T., Markman, G.D. & Panagopoulos, A. Entrepreneurial universities and overt opportunism. Small Bus Econ 47, 609–631 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-016-9753-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-016-9753-6

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation