Skip to main content
Log in

Cherry-picking or frog-kissing? A theoretical analysis of how investors select entrepreneurial ventures in thin venture capital markets

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We propose a formal model that analyzes which entrepreneurial ventures actively seek and subsequently obtain venture capital (VC) financing in thin VC markets. The model shows that in thin VC markets, (1) VC investors will invest in companies in need (frog-kissing) rather than in best performers (cherry-picking), and (2) the best performing ventures will self-select out of the market for VC. These conclusions are in line with the results from the literature, which note that in Europe many entrepreneurial firms do not actively seek VC investment and that VC investors do not appear to possess the same cherry-picking ability that they have in the US.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The VICO dataset was built thanks to the joint effort of nine universities across Europe with the support of the 7th European Framework Program. For more details on the procedures used in the data-gathering process and on all of the variables included in the dataset, see Bertoni and Martí (2011). For more information on the VICO project, please visit the dedicated Web site www.vicoproject.org.

  2. To avoid contaminating our results with the treatment effect of VC, we exclude from this analysis all the observations on the post-VC investment period for the VC-backed companies.

  3. The normalization is obtained by regressing the performance measure against industry, year and age fixed-effects and taking the residuals of the regression as the normalized performance measure.

  4. Similar evidence is obtained when we take into consideration the top quintile.

  5. The effect is even stronger under submodularity because both a and \(\hat{b}\) are below average for companies in the market for VC.

References

  • Bank of England. (2001). Financing of technology-based small firms. Second Report, Domestic Finance Division, Bank of England.

  • Baum, J. A. C., & Silverman, B. S. (2004). Picking winners or building them? Alliance, intellectual, and human capital as selection criteria in venture financing and performance of biotechnology startups. Journal of Business Venturing, 19, 411–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A. N., & Udell, G. F. (1998). The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. Journal of Banking & Finance, 22, 613–673.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoni, F., Colombo, M. G., & Croce, A. (2010). The effect of venture capital financing on the sensitivity to cash flow of firm’s investments. European Financial Management, 16(4), 528–551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoni, F., Colombo, M. G., & Grilli, L. (2011). Venture capital financing and the growth of high-tech start-ups: Disentangling treatment from selection effects. Research Policy, 40, 1028–1043.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoni, F., Colombo, M. G., & Quas, A. (2015a). The patterns of venture capital investment in Europe. Small Business Economics, 45(3), 543–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoni, F., Croce, A., & Guerini, M. (2015b). Venture capital and the investment curve of young high-tech companies. Journal of Corporate Finance, 35, 159–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoni, F., & Martí, J. (2011). Financing entrepreneurial ventures in Europe: The Vico Dataset (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 1904297). Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network.

  • Bertoni, F., & Tykvová, T. (2015). Does governmental venture capital spur invention and innovation? Evidence from young European biotech companies. Research Policy, 44, 925–935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottazzi, L., & Da Rin, M. (2002). Venture capital in Europe and the financing of innovative companies. Economic Policy, 17(34), 229–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J. A., Du, Q., & Hellmann, T. (2015). The effects of government-sponsored venture capital: International evidence. Review of Finance, 19(2), 571–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J. A., Egan, E., & Hellmann, T. (2010). Government sponsored versus private venture capital: Canadian evidence. In J. Lerner & A. Schoar (Eds.), International differences in entrepreneurship, Chapter 10. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buzzacchi, L., Scellato, G., & Ughetto, E. (2013). The investment strategies of publicly sponsored venture capital funds. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(3), 707–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, R. E., & Petersen, B. C. (2002). Capital market imperfections, high-tech investment, and new equity financing. Economic Journal, 112, F54–F72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpentier, C., & Suret, J. M. (2006). Some evidence of the external financing costs of new technology based firms in Canada. Venture Capital, 8, 227–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casamatta, C. (2003). Financing and advising: optimal financial contracts with venture capitalists. Journal of Finance, 58, 2059–2085.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, Y. S. (1983). On the positive role of financial intermediation in allocation of venture capital in market with imperfect information. Journal of Finance, 35, 1543–1568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chemmanur, T. J., Krishnan, K., & Nandy, D. K. (2011). How does venture capital financing improve efficiency in private firms? A look beneath the surface. Review of Financial Studies, 24, 4037–4090.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M. G., Cumming, D. J., & Vismara, S. (2014). Governmental venture capital for innovative young firms. Journal of Technology Transfer,. doi:10.1007/s10961-014-9380-9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M. G., Giannangeli, S., & Grilli, L. (2013). Public subsidies and the employment growth of high-tech start-ups: Assessing the impact of selective and automatic support schemes. Industrial and Corporate Change, 22, 1273–1314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M. G., & Grilli, L. (2010). On growth drivers of high-tech start-ups: The role of founders’ human capital and venture capital. Journal of Business Venturing, 25, 610–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M. G., Grilli, L., & Piva, E. (2006). In search of complementary assets: the determinants of alliance formation of high-tech start-ups. Research Policy, 35, 1166–1199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croce, A., Martí, J., & Murtinu, S. (2013). The impact of venture capital on the productivity growth of European entrepreneurial firms: “Screening” or “value added” effect? Journal of Business Venturing, 28, 489–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cumming, D. J., Grilli, L., & Murtinu, S. (2014). Governmental and independent venture capital investments in Europe: A firm-level performance analysis. Journal of Corporate Finance. doi:10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2014.10.016.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cumming, D. J., & Johan, S. (2009). Pre-seed government venture capital funds. Journal of International Entrepreneurship, 7, 26–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Bettignies, J.-E., & Brander, J. A. (2007). Financing entrepreneurship: Bank finance versus venture capital. Journal of Business Venturing, 22, 808–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckhardt, J. T., Shane, S., & Delmar, F. (2006). Multistage selection and the financing of new ventures. Management Science, 52, 220–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elitzur, R., & Gavious, A. (2011). Selection of entrepreneurs in the venture capital industry: An asymptotic analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 215, 705–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel, D. (2002). The impact of venture capital on firm growth: An empirical investigation. Discussion Paper No. 02-02, Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW), Mannheim.

  • Engel, D., & Keilbach, M. (2007). Firm level implication of early stage venture capital investment: An empirical investigation. Journal of Empirical Finance, 14, 150–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EY (2014). Adapting and evolving, global venture capital insights and trends 2014 report.http://www.ey.com/Publication/vwLUAssets/Global_venture_capital_insights_and_trends_2014/$FILE/EY_Global_VC_insights_and_trends_report_2014.p.

  • European Venture Capital Association (EVCA). (2010). Closing gaps and moving up a gear: The next stage of venture capital’s evolution in Europe. EVCA Venture Capital White Paper.

  • European Venture Capital Association (EVCA). (2014). 2013 European private equity activity: Statistics on fundraising, investments & divestments. Annual Yearbook.

  • Eurostat. (2009). Eurostat indicators of high-tech industry and knowledge—Intensive services. Annex 3—High-tech Aggregation by NACE Rev. 2.

  • Fazzari, S., Hubbard, R. G., & Petersen, B. C. (1988). Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 141–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorman, M., & Sahlman, W. A. (1989). What do venture capitalists do? Journal of Business Venturing, 4, 231–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grilli, L., & Murtinu, S. (2014). Government, venture capital and the growth of European high-tech entrepreneurial firms. Research Policy, 43, 1523–1543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grilli, L., & Murtinu, S. (2015). New technology-based firms in Europe: Market penetration, public venture capital, and timing of investment. Industrial and Corporate Change, 24, 1109–1148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Himmelberg, C. P., & Petersen, B. C. (1994). R&D and internal finance: A panel study of small firms in high-tech industries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76, 38–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hood, N. (2000). Public venture capital and economic development: The Scottish experience. Venture Capital: An International Review, 2(4), 313–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsu, D. H. (2006). Venture capitalists and cooperative start-up commercialization strategy. Management Science, 52, 204–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanniainen, V., & Keuschnigg, C. (2003). The optimal portfolio of start-up firms in venture capital finance. Journal of Corporate Finance, 9, 521–534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, S. N., & Strömberg, P. (2003). Financial contracting theory meets the real world: An empirical analysis of venture capital contracts. Review of Economic Studies, 70, 281–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, S. N., & Strömberg, P. (2004). Characteristics, contracts, and actions: Evidence from venture capitalist analyses. Journal of Finance, 59, 2177–2210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, J. (1995). Venture capitalists and the oversight of private firms. Journal of Finance, 50, 301–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, J. (1999). The government as venture capitalist: The long-run impact of the SBIR program. Journal of Business, 72, 285–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindsey, L. (2008). Blurring firm boundaries: The role of venture capital in strategic alliances. Journal of Finance, 63, 1137–1168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mason, C. M., & Harrison, R. T. (2001). ‘Investment readiness’: A critique of government proposals to increase the demand for venture capital. Regional Studies, 35, 663–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menezes, F. M., & Monteiro, P. (2000). Auctions with endogenous participation. Review of Economic Design, 5, 71–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1981). Optimal auction design. Mathematics of Operations Research, 6, 58–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishimura, J., & Okamuro, H. (2011). Subsidy and networking: The effects of direct and indirect support programs of the cluster policy. Research Policy, 40, 714–727.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2013). Entrepreneurship at a glance 2013. OECD annual report.

  • OECD. (2014). Entrepreneurship at a glance 2014 . OECD annual report.

  • Peneder, M. (2010). The impact of venture capital on innovation behaviour and firm growth. Venture Capital, 12, 83–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revest, V., & Sapio, A. (2012). Financing technology-based small firms in Europe: What do we know? Small Business Economics, 39, 179–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riley, J. G., & Samuelson, W. F. (1981). Optimal auctions. American Economic Review, 71, 381–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sahlman, W. A. (1990). The structure and governance of venture-capital organizations. Journal of Financial Economics, 27(2), 473–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sapienza, H. J. (1992). When do venture capitalists add value? Journal of Business Venturing, 7, 9–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sørensen, M. (2007). How smart is smart money? A two-sided matching model of venture capital. Journal of Finance, 62, 2725–2762.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stuart, T. E., Hoang, H., & Hybels, R. C. (1999). Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of entrepreneurial ventures. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44, 315–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to two anonymous referees and to Silvio Vismara, the Associate Editor of the journal. We also thank for their comments on early versions of this paper: Massimo G. Colombo, Ramy Elitzur, Terttu Luukkonen, Sophie Manigart, Mariana Mazzucato, José Martí Pellón, Tereza Tykvová, Elisa Ughetto, Mike Wright, and the participants to the final VICO conference (Stresa, Italy), the 37th EARIE Annual Conference (Istanbul, Turkey), the 2010 Zvi Griliches Research Summer Seminar in the Economics of Innovation (Barcelona, Spain) and the XXI AiIG annual meeting (L’Aquila, Italy). We acknowledge support from the Venture Fun project promoted by the EU PRIME Network of Excellence, and the VICO project funded under the European FP7 (SSH-2007-1.2.3-G.A. 217485).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fabio Bertoni.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Eq. (6)

Equation (6) follows directly from the theory of auctions with endogenous participation (Menezes and Monteiro 2000). We provide here a proof adapted to our particular framework. If a venture enters into the market for VC, it enters a competition in which, at time t = 2, it will only gain if it gets financed. The selection process of VC, which has been discussed in Sect. 3.3, is known by the entrepreneurs at time t = 1. Let I max be the maximum impact that VC has on all other N − 1 ventures that potentially compete for VC. The cumulative distribution of I max is the following: \(H\left(i \right) = \Pr \left[{I_{\max} < i} \right] = G\left(i \right)^{N - 1}\). The probability density function of I max is thus the following: \(h\left( i \right) = \left( {N - 1} \right)G\left( i \right)^{N - 2} g\left( i \right)\). The entrepreneur knows that \(\tilde{I}\) is the threshold for participation in the market for VC for all players. For \(I_{j} > \tilde{I}\), the expected gain \(V\left( {I_{j} } \right)\) from being in the market for VC for the entrepreneur is the following:

$$V\left({I_{j}} \right) = \underbrace {{\mathop \int \nolimits_{o}^{{\tilde{I}}} I_{j} h\left(i \right){\text{d}}i}}_{{{\text{Expected}}\,{\text{gain}}\,{\text{if}}\,I_{\max} < \tilde{I}}} \,+\, \underbrace {{\mathop \int \nolimits_{{\tilde{I}}}^{{I_{j}}} \left({I_{j} - i} \right)h\left(i \right){\text{d}}i}}_{{{\text{Expected}}\,{\text{gain}}\,{\text{if}}\,I_{\max} > \tilde{I}}}$$
(8)

The first term of Eq. (8) derives from the fact that if \(I_{\hbox{max} } < \tilde{I}\), no other firm will be in the market for VC and entrepreneurs will internalize all the value I j . The second term in (8) derives from the fact that if \(I_{\hbox{max} } > \tilde{I}\), the entrepreneur will have to share some of the value creation with the VC because of competition in the auction. If I max > I j , the venture will not be financed by VC and will not receive any benefit from being in the market for VC. Both terms of V(I j ) are strictly increasing in I j . The equilibrium level of \(\tilde{I}\) is thus unique and such that \(V\left( {\tilde{I}} \right) = s\). Integrating the first term of (8) (the other being null) leads to the following:

$$V\left({\tilde{I}} \right) = \mathop \int \nolimits_{0}^{{\tilde{I}}} \tilde{I}h\left(i \right){\text{d}}i = \tilde{I}\left({N - 1} \right)\mathop \int \nolimits_{0}^{{\tilde{I}}} G\left(i \right)^{N - 1} g\left(i \right){\text{d}}i = \tilde{I}G\left({\tilde{I}} \right)^{N - 1}$$
(9)

By equating Eq. (9) to s, we obtain the following:

$$\tilde{I} = \frac{s}{{G\left({\tilde{I}} \right)^{N - 1}}}.$$

Which proves Eq. (6). \(\blacksquare\)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 1

For this proof, we use the same notation as in the previous Appendix sub-section. If a venture j enters into the market for VC, it enters a competition in which, at time t = 2, it will gain from IVC if I j  > I max or, else, will gain from GVC with a probability π. Let \(\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}\) be the threshold impact to be on the market for VC. For \(I_{j} > \tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}\), the expected gain from being in the market for VC for the entrepreneur is the following:

$$V_{\text{GVC}} \left({I_{j}} \right) = \underbrace {{\mathop \int \nolimits_{o}^{{\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}}} I_{j} h\left(i \right){\text{d}}i + \mathop \int \nolimits_{{\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}}}^{{I_{j}}} \left({I_{j} - i} \right)h\left(i \right){\text{d}}i}}_{{{\text{Expected}}\,{\text{gain}}\,{\text{from}}\,{\text{IVC}}}} + \,\underbrace {{\pi \mathop \int \nolimits_{{I_{j}}}^{+ \infty} \varphi I_{j} h\left(i \right){\text{d}}i,}}_{{{\text{Expected}}\,{\text{gain}}\,{\text{from}}\,{\text{GV}}}}$$
(10)

where the first two terms in (10) are similar to those in Eq. (8) and the last term represents the expected benefit from GVC. It is easy to prove that the three terms are strictly increasing with I j, which means that the equilibrium level of \(\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}\) is thus unique and such that \(V_{\text{GVC}} \left( {\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}} } \right) = s\). Integrating the first and last term of \(V_{\text{GVC}} \left( {\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}} } \right)\) (the second being null) leads to the following:

$$V_{\text{GVC}} \left({\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}} \right) = \mathop \int \nolimits_{o}^{{\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}}} \tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}} h\left(i \right){\text{d}}i + \pi \mathop \int \nolimits_{{\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}}}^{+ \infty} \varphi \tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}} h\left(i \right){\text{d}}i = \tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}} \left({G\left({\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}} \right)^{N - 1} + \pi \varphi \left({1 - G\left({\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}} \right)^{N - 1}} \right)} \right).$$
(11)

The equilibrium level of \(\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}\) is thus obtained by equating (11) to s. It is easy to prove that \(\pi \varphi = 0 \to \tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}} = \tilde{I}\) and that \(\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}\) is decreasing in \(\pi \varphi\). These two results, combined, prove that: \(\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}} < \tilde{I}\).

Finally, in presence of a GVC, Eq. (7) becomes as follows:

$$\varPi_{\text{VC}}^{{{\text{With\,GVC}}}} = \underbrace {{E\left[{I_{1} - I_{2}} \right]}}_{{{\text{Profit\,if}}\,n > 1}}\underbrace {{\left({1 - G\left({\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}} \right)^{N} - G\left({\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}} \right)^{N - 1} \left({1 - G\left({\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}}} \right)^{N}} \right)} \right)}}_{{{\text{Probability}}\,{\text{that}}\,n > 1}} > \varPi_{\text{VC}}^{{{\text{Without\,GVC}}}},$$
(12)

where the first term of (12) is the same as in Eq. 7 (because it only depends on N and on the distributional properties of I), and the second term is greater than in Eq. 7 because \(\tilde{I}_{\text{GVC}} < \tilde{I}\).\(\blacksquare\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bertoni, F., D’Adda, D. & Grilli, L. Cherry-picking or frog-kissing? A theoretical analysis of how investors select entrepreneurial ventures in thin venture capital markets. Small Bus Econ 46, 391–405 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-015-9690-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-015-9690-9

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation