Small Business Economics

, Volume 37, Issue 2, pp 167–185 | Cite as

Entrepreneurship and the theory of taxation

Article

Abstract

A review of the literature on firm taxation reveals that the economics of entrepreneurship has not sufficiently been taken into consideration. We discuss how this affects conclusions derived from standard models of capital taxation when applied to entrepreneurial income. Some defining features of entrepreneurship important for analyzing the effects of taxation of owner-managed firms are identified. These include the lack of a well-functioning external market for entrepreneurial effort, limited access to external capital and complementarities between entrepreneurial innovation, effort and capital. Due to these constraints, the entrepreneurial project is tied to the individual owner–manager. The entrepreneur is unable to decouple saving decisions from investment decisions, and makes joint decisions on the supply of effort and capital. The return from successful entrepreneurial ventures can therefore not be readily divided into labor and capital income, in deep contrast to what is typically assumed in taxation theory. It is argued that when distinct attributes of entrepreneurship are taken into account, certain conclusions of capital taxation models may no longer hold, including the neutrality of capital taxation in owner-managed firms. Cost of capital formulas derived from the behavior of public firms could underestimate distortions when applied to the investment behavior of entrepreneurial firms. For tax purposes and otherwise, it becomes useful to analyze return to entrepreneurial activity as income of a distinct factor of production. In this context, conceptual issues and the difficulties of measuring entrepreneurial income are discussed.

Keywords

Capital income taxation Dual income taxation Entrepreneurship Innovation Institutions Labor supply New firm creation Optimal factor taxes Taxation Tax policy 

JEL Classifications

H21 H25 L5 L26 M13 O31 E25 G32 

References

  1. Achleitner, A. K., Allmendinger, J., Grupp, H., Harhoff, D., Llerena, P., Luther, J., et al. (2009). Research, innovation and technological performance in Germany. Berlin: Commission of Experts for Research and Innovation (EFI).Google Scholar
  2. Agell, J., Englund, P., & Södersten, J. (1998). Incentives and redistribution in the welfare state: The Swedish tax reform. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  3. Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323–351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Apel, M., & Södersten, J. (1999). Personal taxation and investment incentives in a small open economy. International Tax and Public Finance, 6(1), 79–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Auerbach, A. J. (1979). Share valuation and corporate equity policy. Journal of Public Economics, 11(3), 291–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Auerbach, A. J. (2002). Taxation and corporate financial policy. In A. J. Auerbach & M. S. Feldstein (Eds.), Handbook of public economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1251–1292). Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  7. Bank, S. A., & Cheffins, B. R. (2008). Tax and the separation of ownership and control. In W. Schön (Ed.), Tax and corporate governance (pp. 111–161). Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Baumol, W. J. (2004). Education for innovation: Entrepreneurial breakthroughs versus corporate incremental improvements. In A. B. Jaffe, J. Lerner, & S. Stern (Eds.), Innovation policy and the economy (Vol. 5, pp. 33–56). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  9. Baumol, W. J. (2010). The microtheory of innovative entrepreneurship. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Becker, G. S. (1962). Investment in human capital: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 70(1), 9–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Bianchi, M., & Henrekson, M. (2005). Is neoclassical economics still entrepreneurless? Kyklos, 58(4), 353–377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Bitler, M. P., Moskowitz, T. J., & Vissing-Jørgensen, A. (2005). Testing agency theory with entrepreneur effort and wealth. Journal of Finance, 60(2), 539–576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Blanchflower, D. G. (2004). Self-employment: More may not be better. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 11(2), 15–73.Google Scholar
  14. Bradford, D. F. (1981). The incidence and allocation effects of a tax on corporate distributions. Journal of Public Economics, 15(1), 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Brockhaus, R. H., Sr. (1980). Risk taking propensity of entrepreneurs. Academy of Management Journal, 23(3), 509–520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Bruce, D., & Gurley T. (2004). Taxes and entrepreneurial entry: An empirical investigation using longitudinal tax return data. In Proceedings of the 97th annual conference on taxation (pp. 336–343). Washington D.C.: National Tax Association.Google Scholar
  17. Cagetti, M., & De Nardi, M. (2006). Entrepreneurship, frictions, and wealth. Journal of Political Economy, 114(5), 835–870.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Carroll, R., Holtz-Eakin, D., Rider, M., & Rosen, H. S. (2000a). Income taxes and entrepreneurs’ use of labor. Journal of Labor Economics, 18(2), 324–351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Carroll, R., Holtz-Eakin, D., Rider, M., & Rosen, H. S. (2000b). Entrepreneurs, income taxes, and investment. In J. B. Slemrod (Ed.), Does Atlas shrug? The economic consequences of taxing the rich (pp. 427–455). New York: Russell Sage.Google Scholar
  20. Carroll, R., Holtz-Eakin, D., Rider, M., & Rosen, H. S. (2001). Personal income taxes and the growth of small firms. In J. M. Poterba (Ed.), Tax policy and the economy (Vol. 15, pp. 121–148). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  21. Chetty, R., Frederiksen, A., Friedman, J. N., Olsen, T., & Pistaferri, L. (2009). The effect of adjustment costs and institutional constraints on labor supply elasticities: Evidence from Denmark. Working Paper, University of California at Berkeley.Google Scholar
  22. Chetty, R., & Saez, E. (2005). Dividend taxes and corporate behavior: Evidence from the 2003 dividend tax cut. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(3), 791–833.Google Scholar
  23. Chetty, R., & Saez, E. (2006). The effects of the 2003 dividend tax cut on corporate behavior: Interpreting the evidence. American Economic Review, 96(2), 124–129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Chetty, R., & Saez, E. (2007). An agency theory of dividend taxation. NBER Working Paper No. 13538.Google Scholar
  25. Cnossen, S. (2000). Taxing capital income in the Nordic countries: A model for the European Union? In S. Cnossen (Ed.), Taxing capital in the European Union (pp. 180–213). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  26. Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(4), 386–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Cullen, J. B., & Gordon, R. H. (2007). Taxes and entrepreneurial risk-taking: Theory and evidence for the US. Journal of Public Economics, 91(7–8), 1479–1505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Davis, S. J., & Henrekson, M. (2005). Tax effects on work activity, industry mix and shadow economy size: Evidence from rich-country comparisons. In R. Gómez-Salvador, A. Lamo, B. Petrongolo, M. Ward, & E. Wasmer (Eds.), Labour supply and the incentives to work in Europe (pp. 44–104). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  29. Dietz, M. D. (2005). Capital income taxation, new firm creation, and the size distribution of firms. Working Paper, University of St. Gallen.Google Scholar
  30. Domar, E. D., & Musgrave, R. A. (1944). Proportional income taxation and risk-taking. Quarterly Journal Economics, 58(3), 388–422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Eggert, W., & Genser, B. (2005). Dual income taxation in EU member countries. CESifo DICE Report, 3(1), 41–47.Google Scholar
  32. Genser, B., & Reutter, A. (2007). Moving towards dual income taxation in Europe. FinanzArchiv, 63(3), 436–456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Gentry, W. M., & Hubbard, R. G. (2000). Tax policy and entry into entrepreneurship. American Economic Review, 90(2), 283–287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Gentry, W. M., & Hubbard, R. G. (2004). Entrepreneurship and household saving. Advances in Economic Analysis & Policy, 4(1), 1053.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. George, H. (1879/1911). Progress and poverty, Everyman edition. London: J. M. Dent.Google Scholar
  36. Gollin, D. (2002). Getting income shares right. Journal of Political Economy, 110(2), 458–474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Hall, R. E., & Jorgenson, D. W. (1967). Tax policy and investment behavior. American Economic Review, 57(3), 391–414.Google Scholar
  38. Hansson, Å. (2009). Are small business owners more successful in avoiding taxes: Evidence from Sweden. Working Paper 2009:6, Department of Economics, Lund University.Google Scholar
  39. Harberger, A. (1962). The incidence of the corporate income tax. Journal of Political Economy, 70(3), 215–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Heaton, J., & Lucas, D. (2000). Portfolio choice and asset prices: The importance of entrepreneurial risk. Journal of Finance, 55(3), 1163–1198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Holtz-Eakin, D., Joulfaian, D., & Rosen, H. S. (1994a). Sticking it out: Entrepreneurial survival and liquidity constraints. Journal of Political Economy, 102(1), 53–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Holtz-Eakin, D., Joulfaian, D., & Rosen, H. S. (1994b). Entrepreneurial decisions and liquidity constraints. RAND Journal of Economics, 25(2), 334–347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Holtz-Eakin, D., Rider, M., & Rosen, H. S. (2001). Personal income taxes and the growth of small firms. In J. M. Poterba (Ed.), Tax policy and the economy (Vol. 15, pp. 121–148). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  44. Hubbard, R. G. (1997). How different are income and consumption taxes? American Economic Review, 87(2), 138–142.Google Scholar
  45. Jensen, M. C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. American Economic Review, 76(2), 323–329.Google Scholar
  46. Jorgenson, D. W. (1963). Capital theory and investment behavior. American Economic Review, 53(2), 247–257.Google Scholar
  47. Jorgenson, D. W. (1967). The theory of investment behavior. In R. Ferber (Ed.), Determinants of investment behavior (pp. 129–188). New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  48. Jorgenson, D. W., & Landau, R. (1993). Tax reform and the cost of capital: An international comparison. Washington, D.C.: Brookings.Google Scholar
  49. Kanbur, S. M. R. (1982). Entrepreneurial risk taking, inequality, and public policy: An application of inequality decomposition analysis to the general equilibrium effects of progressive taxation. Journal of Political Economy, 90(1), 1–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Kanniainen, V., Kari, S., & Ylä-Liedenpohja, J. (2007). Nordic dual income taxation of entrepreneurs. International Tax and Public Finance, 14(4), 407–426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Kaplow, L. (1995). Taxation and risk taking: A general equilibrium perspective. NBER Working Paper No. 3709.Google Scholar
  52. Keuschnigg, C., & Dietz, M. D. (2007). A growth oriented dual income tax. International Tax and Public Finance, 14(2), 191–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Keuschnigg, C., & Nielsen, S. B. (2004). Start-ups, venture capitalists, and the capital gains tax. Journal of Public Economics, 88(5), 1011–1142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Keuschnigg, C., & Ribi, E. (2009). Profit taxation and finance constraints. Working Paper 05, Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen.Google Scholar
  55. Keynes, J. M. (1921). A treatise on probability. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  56. Kihlstrom, R. E., & Laffont, J. J. (1979). A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm formation based on risk aversion. Journal of Political Economy, 87(3), 719–748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. King, M. A. (1974). Taxation and the cost of capital. Review of Economic Studies, 41(1), 21–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. King, M. A. (1977). Public policy and the corporation. London: Chapman-Hall.Google Scholar
  59. King, M. A., & Fullerton, D. (Eds.). (1984). The taxation of income from capital: A comparative study of the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden and West Germany. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  60. Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  61. Kleven, H. J., & Schultz, E. A. (2009). Estimating reported income responses using Danish tax reforms. Working paper, Department of Economics, London School of Economics.Google Scholar
  62. Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company.Google Scholar
  63. Lazear, E. P. (2004). Balanced skills and entrepreneurship. American Economic Review, 94(2), 208–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Lindhe, T., Södersten, J., & Öberg, A. (2004). Economic effects of taxing different organizational forms under a dual income tax. International Tax and Public Finance, 11(4), 469–485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Marx, K. (1891). Wage labour and capital. English translation of pamphlet published in German in Neue Rheinische Zeitung, 264–267 & 269, April 5–8 and 11, 1849.Google Scholar
  66. McClelland, D. C. (1961). The achieving society. Princeton, NJ: Van Nostrand.Google Scholar
  67. Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48(3), 261–297.Google Scholar
  68. Morck, R. K., & Yeung, B. (2005). Dividend taxation and corporate governance. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(3), 163–180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Nordhaus, W. D. (2004). Schumpeterian profits in the American economy: Theory and measurement. NBER Working Paper No. 104333.Google Scholar
  70. Norqvist, G. (2008). An argument against Obama’s tax plan. Politico.com. Accessed on November 7, 2008 from http://www.politico.com/news/stories/0708/11670.html.
  71. OECD (2009). OECD Annual National Accounts, Vol. 2, 1970–2007. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
  72. Poterba, J. M. (2004). Taxation and corporate payout policy. American Economic Review, 94(2), 171–175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Prescott, E. C. (2004). Why do Americans work so much more than Europeans? Quarterly Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 28, 2–13.Google Scholar
  74. Ricardo, D. (1817). On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (3rd ed.). London: John Murray.Google Scholar
  75. Rosen, H. S. (2005). Entrepreneurship and taxation: Empirical evidence. In V. Kanniainen & C. Keuschnigg (Eds.), Venture capital, entrepreneurship and public policy (pp. 251–280). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  76. Rydqvist, K., Spizman, J., & Strebulaev, I. (2009). The evolution of aggregate stock ownership: a unified explanation. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7356.Google Scholar
  77. Saez, E. (2009). Do tax filers bunch at kink points? Evidence, elasticity estimation, and salience effects. Working Paper, University of California at Berkeley.Google Scholar
  78. Schultz, T. W. (1961). Investment in human capital. American Economic Review, 51(1), 1–17.Google Scholar
  79. Schultz, T. W. (1979). Concepts of entrepreneurship and agricultural research. Kaldor Memorial Lecture, Iowa State University, October.Google Scholar
  80. Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  81. Shaviro, D. (2004). Replacing the income tax with a progressive consumption tax. Tax Notes, 103(14), 91–101.Google Scholar
  82. Sillamaa, M. A., & Veall, M. (2001). The effect of marginal tax rates on taxable income: A panel study of the 1988 tax flattening in Canada. Journal of Public Economics, 80(3), 341–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. Sinn, H. W. (1991a). The vanishing Harberger triangle. Journal of Public Economics, 45(3), 271–300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Sinn, H. W. (1991b). Taxation and the cost of capital: The ‘old’ view, the ‘new’ view and another view. In D. F. Bradford (Ed.), Tax policy and the economy (Vol. 5, pp. 25–54). Cambridge, MA: NBER.Google Scholar
  85. Slemrod, J. (2007). Cheating ourselves: The economics of tax evasion. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(1), 25–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. Sørensen, P. B. (1994). From the global income tax to the dual income tax: Recent tax reforms in the Nordic countries. International Tax and Public Finance, 1(1), 57–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  87. Sørensen, P. B. (2001). The Nordic dual income tax: In or out? Invited speech given at the meeting of the OECD Working Party No. 2 on Fiscal Affairs in Paris.Google Scholar
  88. Sørensen, P. B. (2005). Neutral taxation of shareholder income. International Tax and Public Finance, 12(6), 777–801.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Sørensen, P. B. (2008). The taxation of business income in Sweden: Commissioned report. Stockholm: Ministry of Finance.Google Scholar
  90. Sørensen, P. B. (2009). Dual income taxes: A Nordic tax system. Working Paper, Economic Policy Research Unit, University of Copenhagen.Google Scholar
  91. SOU 2002:52 (2002). Beskattning av småföretagare. Del 1. 3:12-reglerna. Report, 3:12-utredningen. Stockholm: Fritzes.Google Scholar
  92. Stiglitz, J. E. (1973). Taxation, corporate financial policy, and the cost of capital. Journal of Public Economics, 2(1), 1–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  93. Stiglitz, J. E. (1988). Economics of the public sector (2nd ed.). New York, NY: Norton.Google Scholar
  94. Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5(1), 224–232.Google Scholar
  95. Wall Street Journal (2008). Socking it to small business: The Obama plan is an incentive to hire fewer workers. Review & Outlook, October 21. Accessed on September 15, 2009 from http://online.wsj.com/article/SB122455021772252457.html.
  96. Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  97. Zodrow, G. R. (2006). Capital mobility and source-based taxation of capital income in small open economies. International Tax and Public Finance, 13(2), 269–294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN)StockholmSweden
  2. 2.Harris School of Public PolicyUniversity of ChicagoChicagoUSA

Personalised recommendations