Skip to main content
Log in

The Resource-Based Theory of the Firm and Firm Survival

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the determinants of firm survival. We use hazard models to test a number of hypotheses mainly drawn from the Resource-Based Theory of the Firm. According to the Resource-Based View the ability of a firm to develop distinct capabilities enhances its ability to adapt to the changing competitive environment and improves its survival prospects. The results confirm that firms that develop firm-specific assets through advertising and making R&D (independently of the technological intensity of the industry) enjoy better survival prospects. Furthermore, failure risk increases up to about 20 years of trading, and then decreases to later rise in line with liability of “adolescence” and “senescence.”

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Acs Z. J., Audretsch D. B., 1989, Births and Firm Size Southern Economic Journal 56: 467–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almus M., Nerlinger E. A., 1999, Growth of New Technology-Based Firms: Which Factors Matter? Small Business Economics 13: 141–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch D. B., 1991, New Firm Survival and the Technological Regime The Review of Economics and Statistics 73: 441–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch D. B., 1995, Innovation and Industry Evolution MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch D. B., Mahmood T., 1994, The Rate of Hazard Confronting New Firms and Plants in U.S. Manufacturing Review of Industrial Organization 9: 41–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch D. B., Santarelli E., Vivarelli M., 1999, Start Up Size and Industrial Dynamics: Some Evidence from Italian Manufacturing International Journal of Industrial Organization 17: 965–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barney J., 1991, Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage Journal of Management 17: 34–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Baum J. A. C., 1989, Liabilities of Newness, Adolescence, and Obsolescence: Exploring Age Dependence in the Dissolution of Organizational Relationships and Organizations Proceedings of the Administrative Science Association of Canada 10: 1–10

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernard A. B., Eaton J., Jensen J. B., Kortum S. S., 2003, Plants and Productivity in International Trade American Economic Review 93: 1268–1290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braconier H., Ekholm K., 2000, Swedish Multinational and Competition from High and Low wage Locations Review of International Economics 8: 448–461

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruderl J., Schussler R., 1990, Organizational Mortality: The Liabilities of Newness and Adolescence Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 530–547

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo J. L., 2006, Testing Gibrat’s Law for Small, Young and Innovating Firms Small Business Economics 26: 117–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll G., Hannan M., (2000), The Demography of Corporations and Industries Princeton University Press Princeton, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Cefis E., Marsili O., 2006, Innovation Premium and the Survival of Entrepreneurial Firms in the Netherlands In: Santarelli E., (ed.), Entrepreneurship, Growth, and Innovation: The Dynamics of Firms and Industries Springer New York, 183–198

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Caves R.E., 1998, Industrial Organization and New Findings on the Turnover and Mobility of Firms Journal of Economic Literature 36: 1947–1982

    Google Scholar 

  • Cleves M. A., Gould W. W., Gutiérrez R. G., 2004, An Introduction to Survival Analysis Using STATA Stata Corporation College Station, Texas

    Google Scholar 

  • Cressy R., 2006, Why Do Most Firms Die Young? Small Business Economics 26: 103–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comanor W. S., Wilson T. A., 1967, Advertising, Market Structure and Performance Review of Economics and Statistics 49: 423–440

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D. R., 1972, Regression models and life tables Journal of Royal Statistical Society 34: 187–220

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, T. and M. J. Roberts, 1991, ‚Variation in producer turnover across US manufacturing industries.’ in P. A. Geroski and J. Schwalbach (eds.), Entry and Market Contestability: An International Comparison, Basil-Blackwell

  • Dunne T., Roberts M. J., Samuelson L., 1989, The Growth and Failure of US Manufacturing Plants Quarterly Journal of Economics 104: 671–698

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ericson R., Pakes A., 1995, Markov Perfect Industry Dynamics: A Framework for Empirical Work Review of Economic Studies 62: 53–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fichman M., Levinthal D., 1991, Honeymoons and the Liability of Adolescence: A New Perspective on Duration Dependence in Social and Organizational Relationships Academy of Management Review 16: 442–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman J., Carroll G., Hannan M., (1983), The Liability of Newness – Age Dependence in Organizational Death Rates American Sociological Review 48: 692–710

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geroski P., 1995, What Do We Know about Entry? International Journal of Industrial Organization 13: 421–440

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gimeno J., Folta T., Cooper A., Woo C., 1997, Survival of the Fittest? Entrepreneurial Human Capital and the Persistence of Underperforming Firms Administrative Science Quarterly 42: 750–783

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grambsch P. M., Therneau T. M., 1994, Proportional Hazards Tests and Diagnostics Based on Weighted Residuals Biometrika 81: 515–526

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hannan M., 1998, Rethinking Age Dependence in Organizational Mortality: Logical Formalizations American Journal of Sociology 104: 126–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D., Stahl K., Woywode M., 1998, Legal form, Growth and Exit of West German Firms Journal of Industrial Economics 46: 453–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hymer S., 1976, The International Operations of National Firms MIT Press Cambridge. MA

    Google Scholar 

  • International Journal of Industrial Organization, 1995, Special Issue on post-entry performance of firms, vol. 13

  • Jovanovic B., 1982, Selection and Evolution of Industry Econometrica 50: 649–670

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalbfleisch, J. D. and Prentice R. L., 1980, The Statistical Analysis of Failure Time Data. John Wiley & Sons

  • Kiefer N. M., 1988, Economic Duration Data and Hazard Functions Journal of Economic Literature 6: 646–670

    Google Scholar 

  • Klette T., 1996, R&D, Scope Economies and Plant Performance Rand Journal of Economics 27: 502–522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levinthal D., 1997, Adaptation on Rugged Landscapes Management Science 43: 934–950

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mata J., Portugal P., 1994, Life Duration of New Firms Journal of Industrial Economics 42: 227–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mata J., Portugal P., 2002, The Survival of New Domestic and Foreign Owned Firms Strategic Management Journal 23: 323–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mata J., Portugal P., Guimaraes P., 1995, The Survival of New Plants: Start-up Conditions and Post-Entry Evolution International Journal of Industrial Organization 35: 607–627

    Google Scholar 

  • Melitz M. J., 2003, The Impact of Trade in Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity Econometrica 71: 1695–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R., Winter S., 1982, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change Harvard University Press Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Norton W. I. Jr., Moore W. T., 2006, The Influence of Entrepreneurial Risk Assessment on Venture Launch or Growth Decisions Small Business Economics 26: 215–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi S., 2006, Sectoral Differences in Plant Start-up Size in the Finnish Economy Small Business Economics 26: 39–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segarra A., Callejón M., 2002, New firms’ survival and market turbulence: new evidence from Spain Review of Industrial Organization 20: 1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegfried J. J., Evans L. B., (1992), Entry and exit in United States Manufacturing Industries from 1977 to 1982 In Audretsch D. W., Siegfried J. J., (Eds.), Empirical Studies in Industrial Organization: Essays in Honor of Leonard W. Weiss Kluwer Academic Publishers Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Stinchcombe F., (1965), Social Structure and Organizations In March J., (ed.): Handbook of Organizations Rand McNally Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutton, J., 1991, Sunk Costs and Market Structure. The M.I.T. Press

  • Wagner J., 1994, The Post-Entry Performance of New Firms in German Manufacturing Industries Journal of Industrial Economics 42: 141–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wernerfelt B., 1984, A Resource-Based View of the Firm Strategic Management Journal 18: 509–533

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Silviano Esteve-Pérez.

Appendix

Appendix

TABLE A.1 Variable definitions (Source: ESEE) (All variables are time-varying covariates)

Dgrsize

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm has more than 200 workers and 0 if otherwise

Adv

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm advertising expenditure is positive and 0 if otherwise

Intec

Variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to a low- technological intensity industry, the value of 2 if the firm belongs to a medium-technological intensity industry, and 3 if the firm belongs to a high-technological intensity industry (see Table A.2)

Rdgroup

Variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm neither buys nor makes R&D, the value of 2 if the firm buys R&D, and the value of 3 if the firm makes R&D.

Intrd11

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to a low-technological intensity industry and it neither makes nor buys R&D and 0 if otherwise

Intrd12

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to a low-technological intensity industry and it buys but does not make R&D and 0 if otherwise

Intrd13

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to a low-technological intensity industry and it makes R&D and 0 if otherwise

Intrd21

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to an intermediate-technological intensity industry and it neither makes nor buys R&D and 0 if otherwise

Intrd22

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to a medium-technological intensity industry and it buys but does not make R&D and 0 if otherwise

Intrd23

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to a medium-technological intensity industry and it makes R&D and 0 if otherwise

Intrd31

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to a high-technological intensity industry and it neither makes nor buys R&D and 0 if otherwise

Intrd32

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to a high-technological intensity industry and it buys but does not make R&D and 0 if otherwise

Intrd33

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm belongs to a high-technological intensity industry and it makes R&D and 0 if otherwise

Pro

Variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s labor productivity belongs to the first third of the sample labor productivity distribution, the value of 2 if the firm’s labor productivity belongs to the second third of the productivity distribution, and the value of 3 if the firm’s productivity belongs to the upper third of the labor productivity distribution

Pro1

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s productivity belongs to the first third of the labor productivity distribution

Pro2

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s productivity belongs to the second third of the labor productivity distribution

Pro3

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s productivity belongs to the upper third of the labor productivity distribution

Pcmi

The price cost margin is approximated by the value of gross output minus variable costs of production, divided by the value of gross output. The gross value of output is computed as sales + stock variation + other revenues. The variable cost of production is computed as intermediate consumption (raw material and services) + labor costs. The variable pcmi takes the value of 1 if the firm’s price-cost margin is negative, the value of 2 if the firm’s price-cost margin is greater than or equal to 0 and lower than or equal to 10%, the value of 3 if the firm’s price-cost margin is greater than 10% and lower than or equal to 25%, and takes the value of four if the firm’s price cost margin is greater than 25%

Pcmi1

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s price cost margin is negative

Pcmi2

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s price-cost margin is greater than or equal to 0 and lower than or equal to 10%

Pcmi3

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s price-cost margin is greater than 10% and lower than or equal to 25%

Pcmi4

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s price cost margin is greater than 25%

Expint

Variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm does not export, the value of 2 if the firm’s export intensity is greater than 0% and lower than or equal to 25%, and takes the value of 3 if firm’s export intensity is greater than 25%,

Expint1

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm does not export and 0 if otherwise

Expint2

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s export intensity (ratio of export over sales) is greater than 0% and lower than or equal to 25%

Expint3

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s export intensity (ratio of export over sales) is greater than 25%

Limited

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm is a limited liability company and 0 if it has any other legal structure

Pkext

Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm’s capital is participated by foreign capital and 0 if otherwise

  TABLE A.2 Industrial technological intensity (NACE−93 industrial classification)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Esteve-Pérez, S., Mañez-Castillejo, J.A. The Resource-Based Theory of the Firm and Firm Survival. Small Bus Econ 30, 231–249 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-006-9011-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-006-9011-4

Keywords

Jel Classifications

Navigation