Abstract
State-directed but market-oriented forms of regulation, especially environmental examples like cap-and-trade and ecological offsetting, have proliferated in the past two decades, but sociologists have been slow to theorize these broad institutional shifts. This article offers a framework for explaining these processes of regulatory marketization. First, I argue that institutions of this sort are examples of what I call command-and-commodify regulation, a mode of regulation that distinctively hybridizes economic and authoritative dimensions of power. Second, I explain how and why one example of command-and-commodify regulation, species conservation banking, emerged and remained concentrated in California, but did not so easily develop in other American states. Finally, abstracting from the case, I argue that the concept of market reconstruction is useful for developing a more general theory of the ways that social conflicts and mobilization reconfigure regulatory power and thus give rise to new modes of regulation. Together, a theory of command-and-commodify regulation and market reconstruction may be useful for explaining the development of a wide variety of environmentally focused and other regulatory institutions.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.








Notes
Levin and Espeland (2002), Engels (2006), Schneiberg and Bartley (2008), MacKenzie (2009), and Spaargaren and Mol (2013) are among the few sociologists who take these market-oriented forms of regulation as direct objects of analysis. Tellingly, with the exception of a discussion of tradable quotas used in fisheries, a recent review of sociological scholarship on “The Political Economy of the Environment” (Rudel et al. 2011) does not mention any form of state-directed but market-oriented environmental regulation.
Table 2 catalogs my informants by organizational affiliation and geographic region of expertise.
See Collier County Board of County Commissioners meeting, May 24, 2011, agenda item 10.C. Video archive available at http://www.colliergov.net/index.aspx?page=2280
County-level data on land-use change or economic output in construction, which drives demand for ecological mitigation, is not widely available. At the state level, economic output in the construction industry is robustly correlated with foregoing increases in population, suggesting that county-level population growth is a strong proxy for land development also at that scale. See Table 3 in the Appendix.
Alaska was excluded because of inconsistencies in population data.
To reiterate, like Weber, I do not claim that the dimensions I identify are the only dimensions that power can be exercised along—just that they are two dimensions that are useful for distinguishing between different modes of structuring economic action.
Skeptics of the distinction between authoritative and economic power will argue that these two forms of power are not so different, insomuch as compliance with an authoritative command may be conditioned on an assessment of the costs and benefits of compliance, just as making a “free choice” in a market is conditioned by the structural context that the decision is made within—that is, by considering the costs and benefits of taking one action rather than another (see, e.g., Hale 1935). This is true, but exactly misses the point of Weber’s analytical distinction: that similar ends—economic action of a particular sort—can be achieved by qualitatively different means, that is, by using different modes of domination. One can ask, for example, how and to what extent collapsing the coercion experienced by the serf into the same category as the coercion experienced by the wage laborer offers insight for understanding the distinctive economic institutions that each are embedded within.
Two notes are important here. First, mitigation is only formally allowed after (and never instead of) taking steps first to avoid and then to minimize ecological harm, although distinctions within this hierarchy are clearly subjective (Andrus 1981). Second, “mitigation” or “compensatory mitigation” are the terms used in American environmental policy for the more general concept of “offsetting” as already defined in this article. Readers should thus understand the terms “mitigation” and “offset” as synonymous in this article.
In brief, Section 10 obtains when any non-federal entity (e.g., a private citizen or state government) seeks project approval. Section 7 obtains when a project involves a “federal nexus” (e.g., another federal agency or federal funding). Three things make Section 7 consultations considerably more likely than Section 10 consultations: 1) Compliance with Section 10 is comparatively easy to avoid. In the absence of compulsion to consult with the Services, a private land developer may elect to “shoot, shovel, and shut-up” (Salzman 2005, p. 916) rather than obey the law. 2) Developing a habitat conservation plan under Section 10 is generally arduous, creating incentives to return to (1) above, or to consult under Section 7, if possible. 3) A federal nexus is actually quite common. For example, all projects that have an mpact on “waters of the United States,” must obtain a permit from the US Army Corps of Engineers to comply with the Clean Water Act. This creates a federal nexus.
“Take” is the legal term used in the Endangered Species Act to designate what in colloquial terms would be harm or a disturbance to a protected species and its habitat.
See for example Association of Irritated Residents v. County of Madera (2003) 107 Cal.App.4th 1383.
This may soon change. During the course of the publication of this article, on December 27, 2016, after more than two decades of legal ambiguity, the US Fish and Wildlife Service published a new regulatory rule allowing compensatory mitigation under section 7 of the Endagered Species Act. See https://www.federalregister.gov/documents/2016/12/27/2016-30929/endangered-and-threatened-wildlife-andplants-endangered-species-act-compensatory-mitigation-policy.
See Florida statues section 125.022, available at http://leg.state.fl.us/Statutes/index.cfm.
N = 289 unique cases. However, several cases were coded in multiple states when conflicts spanned borders (e.g., litigation over salmon runs in border rivers), yielding 313 state-based cases. Terms were chosen to focus specifically on federal law because it applies to all states and, because suits often focus on the official biological opinions that Service regulators write, including provisions (or the lack thereof) for mitigation. Outcome categories were in favor of: NGOs: regulators, industry, state, city, landowner, tribes, and military. Search includes all federal district and appellate as well as state appellate cases.
For a nice summary of this debate see White et al. (2016), especially chapter 5.
References
Andrews, K. T., & Seguin, C. (2015). Group threat and policy change: The spatial dynamics of prohibition politics, 1890–1919. American Journal of Sociology, 121, 475–510.
Andrus, C. (1981). U.S. fish and wildlife service mitigation policy. Federal Register, 46, 7656–7663.
Bailey, I., Gouldson, A., & Newell, P. (2011). Ecological modernisation and the governance of carbon: a critical analysis. Antipode, 43, 682–703.
Bakker, K. (2005). Neoliberalizing nature? Market environmentalism in water supply in England and Wales. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 95, 542–565.
Bakker, K. (2009). Neoliberal nature, ecological fixes, and the pitfalls of comparative research. Environment & Planning A, 41, 1781–1787.
Bartley, T. (2007). Institutional emergence in an era of globalization: the rise of transnational private regulation of labor and environmental conditions. American Journal of Sociology, 113, 297–351.
Beck, U. (1992). Risk society: towards a new modernity. London: SAGE.
Beck, U., Giddens, A., & Lash, S. (1994). Reflexive modernization: politics, tradition and aesthetics in the modern social order. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Besky, S. (2013). The Darjeeling distinction. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Block, F. (2013). Relational work and the law: Recapturing the legal realist critique of market fundamentalism. Journal of Law and Society, 40, 27–48.
Brockington, D., & Duffy, R. (2010). Capitalism and conservation: The production and reproduction of biodiversity conservation. Antipode, 42, 469–484.
Büscher, B., Sullivan, S., Neves, K., Igoe, J., & Brockington, D. (2012). Towards a synthesized critique of neoliberal biodiversity conservation. Capitalism Nature Socialism, 23, 4–30.
Buttel, F. H. (2000). Ecological modernization as social theory. Geoforum, 31, 57–65.
California Department of Transportation. (2011). Madera pools restoration and mitigation site. Exemplary Ecosystem Initiative Application.
Campbell, A. L. (2003). How policies make citizens: senior political activism and the American welfare state. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Campbell, J. L., & Lindberg, L. N. (1990). Property rights and the organization of economic activity by the state. American Sociological Review, 55, 634–647.
Carroll, N., Fox, J., & Bayon, R. (Eds.). (2009). Conservation and biodiversity banking: a guide to setting up and running biodiversity credit trading systems. London: Routledge.
Carruthers, B. G., & Ariovich, L. (2004). The sociology of property rights. Annual Review of Sociology, 30, 23–46.
Carton, W. (2014). Environmental protection as market pathology?: Carbon trading and the dialectics of the ‘double movement’. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 32, 1002–1018.
Castree, N. (2008). Neoliberalising nature: the logics of deregulation and reregulation. Environment & Planning A, 40, 131–152.
Clark, B., & York, R. (2005). Carbon metabolism: global capitalism, climate change, and the biospheric rift. Theory and Society, 34, 391–428.
Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.
Dales, J. H. (1968a). Land, water, and ownership. The Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d’Economique, 1, 791–804.
Dales, J. H. (1968b). Pollution, property & prices: an essay in policy-making and economics. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.
Ecosystem Marketplace. (2011). The state of biodiversity markets.
Edelman, L. B. (1992). Legal ambiguity and symbolic structures: organizational mediation of civil rights law. American Journal of Sociology, 97, 1531–1576.
Edelman, L. B., Uggen, C., & Erlanger, H. S. (1999). The Endogeneity of legal regulation: grievance procedures as rational myth. American Journal of Sociology, 105, 406–454.
Ellerman, A. D., & Buchner, B. K. (2007). The European Union emissions trading scheme: origins, allocation, and early results. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1, 66–87.
Ellerman, A. D., Joskow, P. L., Schmalensee, R., Montero, J.-P., & Bailey, E. M. (2000). Markets for clean air: the U.S. acid rain program. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Engel, S., Pagiola, S., & Wunder, S. (2008). Designing payments for environmental services in theory and practice: an overview of the issues. Ecological Economics, 65, 663–674.
Engels, A. (2006). Market creation and transnational rule-making: the case of CO 2 emissions trading. In M.-L. Djelic & K. Sahlin-Andersson (Eds.), Transnational governance: Institutional dynamics of regulation (pp. 329–348). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Feldman, T. D., & Jonas, A. E. G. (2000). Sage scrub revolution? Property rights, political fragmentation, and conservation planning in Southern California under the federal endangered species act. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 90, 256–292.
Fligstein, N. (2001). The architecture of markets: an economic sociology of twenty-first-century capitalist societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Fligstein, N., & Dauter, L. (2007). The sociology of markets. Annual Review of Sociology, 33, 105–128.
Foster, J. B., Clark, B., & York, R. (2009). The midas effect: a critique of climate change economics. Development and Change, 40, 1085–1097.
Fourcade, M. (2011). Cents and sensibility: economic valuation and the nature of “nature”. American Journal of Sociology, 116, 1721–1777.
Fourcade, M., & Healy, K. (2007). Moral views of market society. Annual Review of Sociology, 33, 285–311.
Fox, J., & Nino-Murcia, A. (2005). Status of species conservation banking in the United States. Conservation Biology, 19, 996–1007.
Frank, D. J., Hironaka, A., & Schofer, E. (2000). The nation-state and the natural environment over the twentieth century. American Sociological Review, 96–116.
Funk, R. J., & Hirschman, D. (2014). Derivatives and deregulation financial innovation and the demise of glass–Steagall. Administrative Science Quarterly, 59, 669–704.
Gareau, B. J. (2013). From precaution to profit: contemporary challenges to environmental protection in the montreal protocol. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Golub, J. (Ed.). (1998). New instruments for environmental policy in the EU. New York: Routledge.
Gottlieb, R. (2005). Forcing the spring: the transformation of the American environmental movement. Washington D.C.: Island Press.
Guthman, J. (2007). The Polanyian way? Voluntary food labels as neoliberal governance. Antipode, 39, 456–478.
Hale, R. L. (1935). Force and the state: a comparison of “political” and “economic” compulsion. Columbia Law Review, 35, 149.
Hale, R. L. (1943). Bargaining, duress, and economic liberty. Columbia Law Review, 43, 603–628.
Harvey, D. (1996). Justice, nature and the geography of difference (1st ed.). Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell.
Ingram, P., Yue, L. Q., & Rao, H. (2010). Trouble in store: probes, protests, and store openings by Wal-Mart, 1998–20071. American Journal of Sociology, 116, 53–92.
Kaplan, R. (2015). Who has been regulating whom, business or society? The mid-20th-century institutionalization of ‘corporate responsibility’ in the USA. Socio-Economic Review, 13, 125–155.
Kaup, B. Z. (2015). Markets, nature, and society embedding economic & environmental sociology. Sociological Theory, 33, 280–296.
Kettl, D. F. (1993). Sharing power: public governance and private markets. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Kettl, D. F. (2002). The transformation of governance: public administration for twenty-first Century America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Kinderman, D. (2011). ‘Free us up so we can be responsible!’ The co-evolution of corporate social responsibility and neo-liberalism in the UK, 1977–2010. Socio-Economic Review, 10, 29–57.
King, B. G., & Pearce, N. A. (2010). The contentiousness of markets: politics, social movements, and institutional change in markets. Annual Review of Sociology, 36, 249–267.
Klare, K. E. (1988). Workplace democracy and market reconstruction: an agenda for legal reform. Catholic University Law Review, 38, 1.
Lamb, C. (2007). State buys wetland credits to build highway. Sacramento Business Journal. Sunday, March 11, 2007.
Lave, R. (2012a). Bridging political ecology and STS: a field analysis of the Rosgen wars. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 102, 366–382.
Lave, R. (2012b). Fields and streams: stream restoration, neoliberalism, and the future of environmental science. Athens: University of Georgia Press.
Lederer, M. (2012). Market making via regulation: the role of the state in carbon markets. Regulation & Governance, 6, 524–544.
Levien, M. (2013). The politics of dispossession: theorizing India’s “land wars”. Politics & Society, 41, 351–394.
Levin, P., & Espeland, W. N. (2002). Pollution Futures: Commensuration, Commodification, and the Market for Air. In A. J. Hoffman & M. J. Ventresca (Eds.), Orginizations, Policy, and the Natural Environment (pp. 119–147). Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Locke, R. M. (2013). The promise and limits of private power: promoting labor standards in a global economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Lockhart, A. (2015). Developing an offsetting programme: tensions, dilemmas and difficulties in biodiversity market-making in England. Environmental Conservation, 42, 335–344.
Lohmann, L. (2010). Neoliberalism and the calculable world: the rise of carbon trading. In K. Birch & V. Mykhnenko (Eds.), The Rise and Fall of Neoliberalism: The Collapse of an Economic Order? (pp. 77–93). London: Zed Books.
MacKenzie, D. (2009). Making things the same: gases, emission rights and the politics of carbon markets. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34, 440–455.
McCright, A. M., & Dunlap, R. E. (2003). Defeating kyoto: the conservative movement’s impact on U.S. climate change policy. Social Problems, 50, 348–373.
Meckling, J. (2011). Carbon coalitions: business, climate politics, and the rise of emissions trading. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Mercer, D.E., Cooley, D., Hamilton, K. (2011). Taking stock: payments for ecosystem services in the United States. Washington DC: Forest Trends. Available at: http://www.forest-trends.org/documents/files/doc_2673.pdf.
Merton, R. K. (1987). Three fragments from a sociologist’s notebooks: establishing the phenomenon, specified ignorance, and strategic research materials. Annual Review of Sociology, 13, 1–29.
Mol, A. P. J. (2012). Carbon flows, financial markets and climate change mitigation. Environmental Development, 1, 10–24.
Mol, A. P. J., & Sonnenfeld, D. A. (2000). Ecological modernisation around the world: an introduction. Environmental Politics, 9, 1–14.
Mol, A. P. J., & Spaargaren, G. (2000). Ecological modernisation theory in debate: A review. Environmental Politics, 9, 17–49.
Obama, B. (2016). United states health care reform: progress to date and next steps. Journal of the American Medical Association, 316, 525–532.
Polanyi, K. (2001). The great transformation: the political and economic origins of our time. Boston: Beacon Press.
Quinn, S. (2008). The transformation of morals in markets: death, benefits, and the exchange of life insurance policies. American Journal of Sociology, 114, 738–780.
Radin, M. J. (1996). Contested commodities. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Rao, H., Morrill, C., & Zald, M. N. (2000). Power plays: how social movements and collective action create new organizational forms. Research in Organizational Behavior, 22, 237–282.
Rao, H., Yue, L. Q., & Ingram, P. (2011). Laws of attraction regulatory arbitrage in the face of activism in right-to-work states. American Sociological Review, 76, 365–385.
Robertson, M. M. (2004). The Neoliberalization of ecosystem services: Wetland mitigation banking and problems in environmental governance. Geoforum, 35, 361–373.
Robertson, M. M. (2006). The nature that capital can see: science, state, and market in the commodification of ecosystem services. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 24, 367–387.
Roy, W. G. (1997). Socializing capital: the rise of the large industrial corporation in America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Rudel, T. K., Timmons Roberts, J., & Carmin, J. A. (2011). Political economy of the environment. Annual Review of Sociology, 37, 221–238.
Salzman, J. (2005). Creating markets for ecosystem services: notes from the field. New York University Law Review, 80, 870–961.
Schneiberg, M., & Bartley, T. (2001). Regulating American industries: markets, politics, and the institutional determinants of fire insurance regulation. American Journal of Sociology, 107, 101–146.
Schneiberg, M., & Bartley, T. (2008). Organizations, regulation, and economic behavior: Regulatory dynamics and forms from the nineteenth to twenty-first century. Annual Review of Law and Social Science, 4, 31–61.
Sinclair, D. (1997). Self-regulation versus command and control? Beyond false dichotomies. Law & Policy, 19, 529–559.
Sine, W. D., & Lee, B. H. (2009). Tilting at windmills? The environmental movement and the emergence of the U.S. wind energy sector. Administrative Science Quarterly, 54, 123–155.
Small, M. L. (2009). ‘how many cases do I need?’: on science and the logic of case selection in field-based research. Ethnography, 10, 5–38.
Smith, N. (2007). Nature as accumulation strategy. Socialist Register, 2007, 16.
Soule, S. A. (2009). Contention and corporate social responsibility. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Soule, S. A. (2012). Social movements and markets, Industries, and firms. Organization Studies, 33, 1715–1733.
Spaargaren, G., & Mol, A. P. J. (2013). Carbon flows, carbon markets, and low-carbon lifestyles:reflecting on the role of markets in climategovernance. Environmental Politics, 22, 174–193.
Swedberg, R. (2005). Markets in Sociology. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology (2nd ed., pp. 233–253). Princeton: Princeton University Press and Russell Sage Foundation.
Swyngedouw, E. (2005). Dispossessing H2O: the contested terrain of water privatization. Capitalism Nature Socialism, 16, 81–98.
Tietenburg, T. H. (2006). Emissions trading: principles and practice. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.
U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service and National Marine Fisheries Service. (1998). Endnagered speices act consultation handbook: procedures for conducting section 7 consultations and conferences. Washington, D.C.: Fish and Wildlife Service.
Vogel, S. K. (1996). Freer markets, more rules: regulatory reform in advanced industrial countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Vogel, D. (2005). The market for virtue: the potential and limits of corporate social responsibility. Washington DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Vogel, D. (2008). Private global business regulation. Annual Review of Political Science, 11, 261–282.
Vogel, D. (2012). The politics of precaution: regulating health, safety, and environmental risks in Europe and the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Vogel, S. K. (2016). Marketcraft: what does it really take to make a market work? In Woring paper presented at SASE annual conference, June 25, University of California, Berkeley.
Walker, E. T. (2012). Social movements, organizations, and fields: a decade of theoretical integration. Contemporary Sociology: A Journal of Reviews, 41, 576–587.
Walker, E. T., & Rea, C. M. (2014). The political mobilization of firms and industries. Annual Review of Sociology, 40, 281–304.
Walker, E. T., Martin, A. W., & McCarthy, J. D. (2008). Confronting the state, the corporation, and the academy: the influence of institutional targets on social movement repertoires. American Journal of Sociology, 114, 35–76.
Washington State. (1971). State Environmental Policy Act. Laws of Washington, 1st Ex. Sess., ch. 109, p. 623. Olympia: Statute Law Committee.
Weber, M. (1978). Economy and society: an outline of interpretive sociology. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Weber, K., Rao, H., & Thomas, L. G. (2009). From streets to suites: how the anti-biotech movement affected German pharmaceutical firms. American Sociological Review, 74, 106–127.
White, D., Rudy, A., & Gareau, B. (2016). Environments, natures and social theory: Towards a critical hybridity. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Widick, R. (2009). Trouble in the Forest: California’s redwood timber wars. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
World Bank. (2014). State and trends of carbon pricing 2014. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Wunder, S. (2005). Payments for environmental services: some nuts and bolts, volume occasional paper no. 42. Bogor: Center for International Forestry Research.
Zelizer, V. A. R. (1978). Human values and the market: the case of life insurance and death in 19th-century America. American Journal of Sociology, 84, 591–610.
Zelizer, V. A. R. (1994). Pricing the priceless child: the changing social value of children. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zelizer, V. A. R. (2011). Economic lives: how culture shapes the economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Acknowledgements
Special thanks to Thomas Angeletti, Tim Bartley, Jens Beckert, Fred Block, Winston Chou, Guus Dix, Rebecca Emigh, Jenny Goldstein, Neil Gong, Hannah Landecker, Ching Kwan Lee, Yewon Lee, Michael Mann, Bill Roy, Ksenia Varlyguina, Ed Walker, the Theory and Society Editors and reviewers, and the participants of the UCLA Comparative Social Analysis seminar for many helpful comments and ideas that contributed to this article. Anonymous reviewers in a previous review process were also very helpful. The research presented in this article was developed in part under GRO Fellowship Assistance Agreement no. F13A10071 awarded by the US Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). It has not been formally reviewed by EPA. The views expressed in this article are solely those of the author.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix
Appendix
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Rea, C.M. Theorizing command-and-commodify regulation: the case of species conservation banking in the United States. Theor Soc 46, 21–56 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-017-9283-5
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-017-9283-5