Abstract
Starting from the assumption that decision situations in economic contexts are characterized by fundamental uncertainty, this article argues that the decision-making of intentionally rational actors is anchored in fictions. “Fictionality” in economic action is the inhabitation in the mind of an imagined future state of the world and the beliefs in causal mechanisms leading to this future state. Actors are motivated in their actions by the imagined future and organize their activities based on these mental representations. Since these representations are not confined to empirical reality, fictional expectations are also a source of creativity in the economy. Fictionality opens up a way to an understanding of the microfoundations of the dynamics of the economy. The article develops the notion of fictional expectations. It discusses the role of fictional expectations for the dynamics of the economy and addresses the question of how fictional expectations motivate action. The last part relates the notion of fiction to calculation and social macrostructures, especially institutions and cultural frames. The conclusion hints at the research program developing from the concept of fictional expectations.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
Notes
This is not to deny the crucial role of routine behavior also in economic contexts (Camic 1986; Tappenbeck 1999, p. 48). The discussion here, however, refers only to a type of action in which actors are reflexive in the sense that they make decisions based on a deliberate consideration of alternatives, weighted against each other with regard to the desirability of their expected outcomes.
Though fictional expectations do exist in all spheres of social life, I would hypothesize that they are more volatile in economic contexts of capitalist societies, because behavior in this sphere is less normatively regulated. This contingency of expectations is a foundation for the innovativeness of capitalist economies but is also a cause of its restlessness and susceptibility to crises stemming from rapid fluxes in expectations.
In part, this is a problem of lack of thoroughness of economic analysis (Hellwig 1998, p. 719ff.). However, the problem cannot be reduced to superficiality of analysis. In practical terms, actors are simply overburdened and therefore cannot take all relevant information into account (Elster 2009). And with regard to novelty, the necessary information for optimizing decisions is simply not available at the time of decision making (Dequech 2003).
According to Neil Fligstein (2001, p. 112), the identities of actors—that is, their interpretation of the structures of the world—are not fixed but emerge in the process of social interaction. Sabel and Zeitlin (1997, p. 15) argue that actors define “themselves strategically in the very act of constituting their context” because context is not objectively given but established through the definition of the situation carried out by the actors who are acting in these structures. The economics of conventions (Favereau and Lazega 2002) assumes the simultaneous presence of different conventions, making it necessary for actors to decide which convention holds in a specific situation, a decision that takes place in the action process and is potentially conflictual.
Script following and imagination can also take place in situations with certainty and risk. Traditional action (Weber [1922] 1978) or wishful thinking would be examples. Given the assumption of intentional rationality these cases are not further explored here.
In discussions of the financial crisis the term “fictional” is often used to describe fraudulent misrepresentations of economic facts. It is important to note that this is not how the term is used here.
Because of this, literary texts wear their fictionality on their sleeve, while non-literary fictions hide it. As Wolfgang Iser (1993, pp. 12–13) emphasizes: “In the self-disclosure of its fictionality, an important feature of the fictional text comes to the fore: it turns the whole of the world organized in the text into an ‘as-if’ construction”.
Fictionality, moreover, allows the attribution of qualities to goods that exist only as imaginaries. This is of crucial importance in understanding the sources of consumer demand, especially in economies that are saturated in functional terms. Examples of where this aspect of imaginaries can be studied particularly well are the valuation of antiques, art, wine, and so on. This aspect of fictionality is not discussed in this article. See, however, Beckert (2011).
With hindsight, such point predictions mostly turn out to be wrong. However, based on the theoretical considerations developed here, it would be a categorical mistake to mock such forecasts for being wrong. They are necessarily wrong because the future cannot be foreseen. The much more interesting perspective is to analyze the functions of such forecasts (and other forms of fictional expectations) for structuring action in the present.
As Volkmann (2001, p. 15) elaborates with reference to Wolfgang Iser, the act of fictionalizing converts the diffuseness of the imaginary into a gestalt. Fictionalizing “provides the imaginary with a determinacy that it would otherwise not possess” (ibid.).
Research on narrative representations is also important in historiography (Anderson 1983). Since this research refers to the past it is not considered here. Our interest here lies in stories used to depict future events imaginatively.
That expectations under conditions of uncertainty are fictions also finds confirmation in the status of the ratings of rating agencies. After ratings had proved to be wrong in the financial crisis of 2008, rating agencies stressed in their defense that their ratings are nothing but “opinions”. While this was an excuse to avoid legal liability, it also confirms the argument developed here: assessments of the future in highly complex conditions are no more than “pretensions”.
The influence of fictional depictions of future states on investments is not limited to financial markets; it is a much wider phenomenon. It shows itself, for instance, in the bequest of wealth (Beckert 2008), the buying of life insurance (Zelizer 1979, p. 595f.), the purchase of lottery tickets (Beckert and Lutter 2009), or investments in education motivated by imaginaries of intergenerational upward mobility, supported by collective narratives such as the “American dream”.
See also Zbaracki (2004, p. 17) who shows, based on ethnographic work in a large industrial firm, that price-setting practices make use of economic price theory. But rather than determining prices, the theory has influence because it is used to legitimate the position advocated by a group of managers in the negotiations. “Price theory may serve as a rational myth” used by actors to orient themselves in a complex situation.
Psychological theories (Beach and Mitchell 1987) distinguish between several mental “images” through which knowledge is represented: The self-image, consisting of personal beliefs and values; the trajectory-image, depicting a desirable future; the action-image, portraying the sequences of actions needed to achieve the desirable future; and the projected-image, which depicts the anticipated results of the action.
Again, there seems to be a parallel to fictional literature that can also produce “quasi emotions” (Walton 1990, p. 37) in the reader who empathizes with the fate of the characters.
References
Akerlof, G. A., & Shiller, R. (2009). Animal spirits. How human psychology drives the economy, and why it matters for global capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Allais, M. (1953). Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque: critique des postulats et axiomes de l’école Américaine. Econometrica, 21, 503–546.
Anderson, B. (1983). Imagined communities: reflections on the origin and spread of nationalism. London: Verso.
Augier, M., & Kreiner, K. (2000). Rationality, imagination and intelligence: some boundaries in human decision-making. Industrial and Corporate Change, 9, 659–681.
Bacharach, M., & Gambetta, D. (2001). Trust in society. In K. S. Cook (Ed.), Trust in society (pp. 148–184). New York: Russel Sage.
Bandelj, N. (2009). Emotions in economic action and interaction. Theory and Society, 38, 347–366.
Barbalet, J. (1998). Emotion, social theory, and social structure: a macrosociological approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Barbalet, J. (2010). Action theoretic foundations of economic sociology. Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie. Sonderband, 49, 143–157.
Beach, L. R., & Mitchell, T. R. (1987). Image theory: Principles goals, and plans in decision making. In Acta Psychologica 66.
Beckert, J. (1996). What is sociological about economic sociology? Uncertainty and the embeddedness of economic action. Theory and Society, 25, 803–840.
Beckert, J. (2002). Beyond the market. The social foundations of economic efficiency. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Beckert, J. (2003). Economic sociology and embeddedness. How shall we conceptualize economic action? Journal of Economic Issues, 37, 769–787.
Beckert, J. (2005). Trust and the performative construction of markets. Köln: Max-Planck-Institut für Gesellschaftsforschung. MPIfG Discussion Paper 05/8.
Beckert, J. (2006). Was tun? Die emotionale Konstruktion von Zuversicht bei Entscheidungen unter Ungewissheit. In A. Scherzberg (Ed.), Kluges Entscheiden. Disziplinäre Grundlagen und interdisziplinäre Verknüpfungen (pp. 123–141). Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.
Beckert, J. (2008). Inherited wealth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Beckert, J. (2011). The transcending power of goods. In J. Beckert & P. Aspers (Eds.), The worth of goods (pp. 106–128). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Beckert, J. (2013). Capitalism as a system of fictional expectations. Toward a sociological microfoundation of political economy. Politics and Society (forthcoming).
Beckert, J., & Lutter, M. (2009). The inequality of fair play. Lottery gambling and social stratification in Germany. European Sociological Review, 25, 475–488.
Berezin, M. (2005). Emotions and the economy. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), Handbook of economic sociology (pp. 9–127). New York: Russell Sage.
Berger, P. L., & Luckmann, T. (1966). The social construction of reality: A treatise in the sociology of knowledge. Garden City: Anchor Books.
Boulding, K. E. (1956). The image. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.
Bronk, R. (2009). The romantic economist. Imagination in economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Brown, J. S., et al. (2005). Storytelling in organizations. Burlington: Elsevier Butterworth-Heinemann.
Buchanan, J., & Vanberg, V. ([1984] 2008). The market as a creative process. In D. Hausmann (Ed.), The philosophy of economics (pp. 379–398). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bunia, R. (2010). Was ist Fiktion? Kunstforum, 202, 46–53.
Burgdorf, A. (2011). Virtualität und Fiktionalität—Überlegungen zur Finanzwelt als “Vorstellungsraum”. In C. Künzel & D. Hempel (Eds.), Finanzen und Fiktionen (pp. 107–118). Frankfurt/M: Campus Verlag.
Callon, M. (Ed.). (1998). The laws of the markets. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.
Callon, M., & Munesia, F. (2005). Economic markets as calculative collective devices. Organization Studies, 26, 229–1250.
Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., & Rabin, M. (Eds.). (2003). Advances in behavioral economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Camic, C. (1986). The matter of habit. The American Journal of Sociology, 91, 1039–1087.
Castoriadis, C. (1998). The imaginary institution of society. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Coleridge, S. T. (1817). Biographia Literaria. <http://www.gutenberg.org/cache/epub/6081/pg6081.html>.
Costa, V. D., et al. (2010). Emotional imagery: assessing pleasure and arousal in the brain’s reward circuitry. Human Brain Mapping, 31, 1446–1457.
Czarniawska, B. (1997). Narrating the organisation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Dequech, D. (2003). Conventional and unconventional behavior under uncertainty. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 26, 145–168.
Dequech, D. (2006). The new institutional economics and the behaviour under uncertainty. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 59, 109–131.
Dewey, J. (1957). Human nature and conduct. An introduction to social psychology. New York: The Modern Library.
Dewey, J. ([1938] 1998). The pattern of inquiry the essential John Dewey. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 169–179.
Diaz-Bone, R., & Krell, G. (Eds.). (2009). Diskurs und Ökonomie. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.
DiMaggio, P. (2002). Endogenizing “animal spirits”: toward a sociology of collective response to uncertainty and risk. In M. F. Guillén et al. (Eds.), The new economic sociology. Developments in an emerging field (pp. 79–100). New York: Russell Sage.
DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48, 147–160.
Dobbin, F. (2001). How institutional economics is killing microeconomics. Economic Sociology Listserve.
Dobbin, F. (2004). The sociological view of the economy. In F. Dobbin (Ed.), The new economic sociology. A reader (pp. 1–46). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Elster, J. (2009). Excessive ambitions. Capitalism and Society, 4, 1–30.
Esposito, E. (2007). Die Fiktion der wahrscheinlichen Realität. Frankfurt a.M: Suhrkamp.
Favereau, O., & Lazega, E. (2002). Conventions and structures in economic organization. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Fligstein, N. (2001). Social skill and the theory of fields. Sociological Theory, 19, 105–125.
Foucault, M. (1970). The order of things: An archeology of the human sciences. New York: Vintage Books.
Friese, H. (2001). Imagination: History of the concept international encyclopedia of the social and behavioral sciences (pp. 7197–7201). Oxford: Elsevier Publishers.
Garfinkel, H. (1967). Studies in ethnomethodology. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Gold News (2011). <http://goldnews.bullionvault.com/gold_price_111020117>.
Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91, 481–510.
Granovetter, M. (2005). The impact of social structure on economic outcomes. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19, 33–50.
Güth, W., & Kliemt, H. (2010). (Un)Eingeschränkt rational entscheiden in Geschäft und Moral. In Berlin Brandenburgische Akademie der Wissenschaften (Ed.), Preis der Berlin-Brandenburgischen Akademie der Wissenschaften gestiftet von der Commerzbank Stiftung. Preisverleihung am 19. Oktober 2009: Weyma Lübbe. Berlin: BBAW.
Hellwig, M. (1998). Discussion on international contagion: what is it and what can be done against it? Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, 134, 715–739.
Hellwig, M. (1999). Zur “volkswirtschaftlichen Verantwortung” der Banken. In F. Jaeger (Ed.), Die volkswirtschaftliche Verantwortung der Banken. Rüegger: Chur.
Hellwig, M. (2008). Systemic risk in the financial sector: An analysis of the subprime-mortgage financial crisis (Vol. 157). Bonn: Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods. Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods Bonn 2008/43.
Hirschman, A. (1986). Rival views of market society. New York: Viking.
Holmes, D. R. (2009). Economy of words. Cultural Anthropology, 24, 381–419.
Iser, W. (1993). The fictive and the imaginary: Charting literary anthropology. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Joas, H. (1996). The creativity of action. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Karpik, L. (2010). Valuing the unique. The economics of singularities. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Keynes, J. M. ([1936] 1964). The general theory of employment, interest, and money. London: MacMillan.
Keynes, J. M. ([1937] 1973). The general theory of employment. In: The collected writings of J.M. Keynes. London: Macmillan, 109–123.
Knight, F. H. ([1921] 1985). Risk, uncertainty, and profit. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Koselleck, R. (1988). Vergangene Zukunft: Zur Semantik geschichtlicher Zeiten. Frankfurt/M: Suhrkamp Verlag.
Kraemer, K. (2010). Propheten der Finanzmärkte. Zur Rolle charismatischer Ideen im Börsengeschehen. Berliner Journal für Soziologie, 20, 179–201.
Künzel, C., & Hempel, D. (2011). Finanzen und Fiktionen. Frankfurt/M: Campus Verlag.
Lucas, R. (1972). Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory, 4, 103–124.
MacKenzie, D., & Millo, Y. (2003). Constructing a market, performing theory: the historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange. The American Journal of Sociology, 109, 107–145.
Mahony, J. (2000). Path dependence in historical sociology. Theory and Society, 29, 507–548.
March, J. G. (1995). The future, disposable organizations and the rigidities of imagination. Organization, 2, 427–440.
Marx, K. ([1846] 1998). The German ideology. Oxford: Blackwell.
McCloskey, D. (1985). The rhetoric of economics. Madison: The University of Wisconsin Press.
McCloskey, D. (1990a). If you’re so smart. The narrative of economic expertise. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
McCloskey, D. (1990b). Storytelling in economics. In D. Lavoie (Ed.), Economics and hermeneutics. New York: Routledge.
Merton, R. (1957). Social theory and social structure. Glencoe: The Free Press.
Mische, A. (2009). Projects and possibilities: Researching futures in action. Sociological Forum, 24, 694–704.
Miyazaki, H. (2003). The temporalities of the market. American Anthropologist, 105, 255–265.
Möllering, G. (2006). Trust: reason, routine, reflexivity. Oxford: Elsevier.
Morris, P. E., & Hampson, P. (1983). Imagery and consciousness. London: Academic.
Münnich, S. (2011). Interest-seeking as sense-making: ideas and business interests in the new deal. European Journal of Sociology, 52, 277–311.
Muth, J. F. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica, 29, 315–335.
Mützel, S. (2010). Koordinierung von Märkten durch narrativen Wettbewerb. Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie. Sonderband, 49, 87–106.
Nelson, S., & Katzenstein, P. J. (2010). Uncertainty and risk and the crisis of 2008. Ithaca: Cornell University.
Nye, D. E. (2004). Technological prediction. In M. Sturken, D. Thomas, & S. J. Ball-Rokeach (Eds.), Technological visions (pp. 159–185). Philadelphia: Temple University Press.
Orléan, A. (2005) The self-referential hypothesis in finance. Paris.
Orléan, A. (2008). Knowledge in finance: objective value versus convention. Paris.
Orléan, A. (2011). L’Empire de la Valeur. Paris: Editions du Seuil.
Parsons, T. (1951). The social system. London: Routledge.
Pascal, B. ([1672] 1958). Pensées. New York, NY: E. P. Dutton & Co., Inc.
Patalano, R. (2003). Beyond rationality: Images as guide-lines to choice. Torino: University of Torino. Vol. 05/2003.
Piotti, G. (2009). German companies engaging in China. Decision-making processes at home and management practices in Chinese subsidiaries. Köln: Max-Planck-Institut für Gesellschaftsforschung. MPIfG Working Paper 09/14.
Pixley, J. (2004). Emotions in finance: Distrust and uncertainty in global markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Putnam, R. A. (2006). Democracy and value inquiry. In J. R. Shook & J. Margolis (Eds.), A companion to pragmatism (pp. 278–289). Malden: Blackwell Publishing.
Pylyshyn, Z. W. (2003). Seeing and visualizing: It’s not what you think. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Riles, A. (2010). Collateral expertise. Current Anthropology, 51, 1–25.
Roeckelein, J. E. (2004). Imagery in psychology: A reference guide. Westport: Praeger Publishers.
Sabel, C. F., & Zeitlin, J. (1997). Stories, strategies, structures: Rethinking historical alternatives to mass production. In C. F. Sabel & J. Zeitlin (Eds.), World of possibilities. Flexibility and mass production in western industrialization (pp. 1–33). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Salmon, C. (2007). Storytelling. La machine à fabriquer des histoires et à formater les esprits. Paris: La Découverte.
Schumpeter, J. (1912). Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.
Schütz, A. (2003). Das Problem der Personalität in der Sozialwelt. Bruchstücke. In R. Grathoff, H.-G. Soeffner, & I. Srubar (Eds.), Alfred Schütz Werkausgabe: Theorie der Lebenswelt 1. Die pragmatische Schichtung der Lebenswelt (pp. 91–177). Konstanz: UVK Verlagsgesellschaft mbH.
Searle, J. (1975). The logical status of fictional discourse. New Literary History, 6, 319–332.
Shackle, G. L. S. (1961). Decision, order and time in human affairs. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Shackle, G. L. S. (1964). General thought-schemes and the economist. Woolwich: Woolwich Polycentric Press. Woolwich Economic Paper 2.
Shackle, G. L. S. (1979). Imagination and the nature of choice. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.
Shiller, R. J. (2000). Irrational exuberance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Simon, H. (1957). Models of man. New York: Wiley.
Soros, G. (1998). The crisis of global capitalism: Open society endangered. New York: PublicAffairs.
Speer, N., et al. (2009). Reading stories activates neural representations of visual and motor experiences. Psychological Science, 20, 989–999.
Stark, D. (2009). The sense of dissonance: Accounts of worth in economic life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Storper, M., & Salais, R. (1997). Worlds of production. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Sturken, M., & Thomas, D. (2004). Introduction. Technological visions and the rhetoric of the new. In M. Sturken, D. Thomas, & S. J. Ball-Rokeach (Eds.), Technological visions (pp. 3–18). Philadelphia: Temple University Press.
Swedberg, R. (2008). The sociological study of hope and the economy: Introductory remarks. Ithaca: Cornell University.
Tappenbeck, I. (1999). Phantasie und Gesellschaft. Zur soziologischen Relevanz der Einbildungskraft. Würzburg: Königshausen und Neumann.
Vaihinger, H. ([1911] 2007) Die Philosophie des Als Ob. Saarbrücken: VDM Verlag.
van Lente, H., & Rip, A. (1998). Expectations in technological developments: An example of prospective structures to be filled in by agency. In C. Disco & B. van der Meulen (Eds.), Getting new technologies together. Studies in making sociotechnical order (pp. 203–229). Berlin: de Gruyter.
Volkmann, C. (2001). Organization theory and literary theory: Strange encounters. Exeter: School of Business & Economics. Vol. 03/01.
Walton, K. (1990). Mimesis as make believe: On the foundations of the representational arts. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Weber, M. ([1920] 1988). Die Wirtschaftsethik der Weltreligionen. In M. Weber (Ed.), Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie I. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr/Siebeck UTB, 237–573.
Weber, M. ([1922] 1978). Economy and society. Berkeley: University of California Press.
White, H. (1992). Identity and control. A structural theory of social action. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Whitford, J. (2002). Pragmatism and the untenable dualism of means and ends: why rational choice theory does not deserve paradigmatic privilege. Theory and Society, 31, 325–363.
Zbaracki, M. J. (2004). Pricing structure and structuring price. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania.
Zelizer, V. (1979). Morals and markets: The development of life insurance in the United States. New York: Columbia University Press.
Acknowledgments
I would like to thank the two anonymous Theory and Society reviewers for their very helpful comments. For comments on earlier versions of this article I would like to thank David Dequech, Christoph Deutschmann, Arne Dreßler, Martin Hellwig, Sebastian Kohl, Sophie Mützel, and Werner Rammert.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Beckert, J. Imagined futures: fictional expectations in the economy. Theor Soc 42, 219–240 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-013-9191-2
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-013-9191-2
Keywords
- Expectations
- Uncertainty
- Economy
- Promises
- Trust
- Innovation
- Creativity
- Motivation
- Economic sociology
- Future
- Rationality
- Microfoundations