Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Time preferences and consumer behavior

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We investigate the predictive power of survey-elicited time preferences. The discount factor elicited from choice experiments using real payments predicts various health, energy, and financial outcomes, including overall self-reported health, smoking, installing energy-efficient lighting, and credit card balance. Allowing for time-inconsistent preferences, both the long-run and present-bias discount factors (δ and β) are also significantly associated in the expected direction with several outcomes. We consider several hypotheses regarding the strength of the association between discount factors and outcomes, such as salience of the outcome or liquidity constraints.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Explore related subjects

Discover the latest articles, news and stories from top researchers in related subjects.

Notes

  1. Von Gaudecker et al. (2011) perform a similar analysis but looking at risk, not time, preferences.

  2. A related prediction is found in the model of willpower in Bénabou and Tirole (2004).

  3. The time periods were the same as those used in Meier and Sprenger (2010). We adjusted the dollar values of the payments downward to reflect our budget (and rounded each to the nearest dollar integer).

  4. The probabilities and dollar values are taken from Andersen et al. (2008).

  5. Ferecatu and Önçüler (2016) provide an alternative methodology for estimating time and risk preferences, based on a hierarchical Bayesian methodology.

  6. An alternative and somewhat simpler way to calculate discount factors is employed by Meier and Sprenger (2010). They calculate a monthly discount factor for each of the three payout time pairs; call these δ0,1, δ0,6, and δ6,7. (That is, δ0,1 is the discount factor calculated using the respondent’s answer to the MPL questions about payoffs now vs. one month from now.) The arithmetic mean of all three of these discount factors is δ avg ; this assumes time-consistent discounting. They allow for time-inconsistent discounting by noting that a respondent can have a different value for δ0,1 and δ6,7. If δ0,1<δ6,7, then consumers are present-biased. The present bias discount factor is β qh =δ0,1/δ6,7 and the long-run discount factor δ qh =δ6,7. A caveat of using this method is that it drops observations for respondents failing to respond to one or more questions, as well as those with inconsistency in their responses, whereas our MLE method retains some of these individuals. Also, the present bias discount factors δ qh and β qh are calculated using just the red and blue blocks. Another methodology for calculating discount factors is to assume that a respondent was indifferent at any observed switching point; however, this method requires strong assumptions about whether to use the first or last switching point if a respondent leaves a question blank or exhibits multiple switches. Our results are robust to using these alternate calculation methods. An alternative strategy is to require that respondents only have at most one switching point by imposing that requirement in the survey, rather than asking about each pair separately; this is the method taken in, e.g., Tanaka et al. (2010).

  7. The payout questions include the time preference questions described here and the lottery questions asked to elicit risk preferences, described above.

  8. For some subjects who exhibited multiple switching points (violating preference monotonicity), our MLE method returned implausibly large or small discounting parameters. We exclude subjects with fitted values of δ qh  < 0.45, β qh  < 0.25, or β qh  > 2.5, which drops 8% of respondents.

  9. For examples, see Ioannou and Sadeh (2016), Meier and Sprenger (2010), and Frederick et al. (2002). The discount factors are low (discount rates are high) relative to studies that use alternative elicitation methods, such as convex time budgets (Andreoni and Sprenger 2012a) or Bayesian methods (Ferecatu and Önçüler 2016).

  10. That survey is available at: http://www.cdc.gov/brfss/.

  11. We considered separate models for smoking status and cigarettes per day among smokers, but the sample size in the regression containing only smokers was too small to obtain meaningful precision. We therefore are unable to disentangle whether effects of time preference on smoking occur along the extensive or intensive margins.

  12. That survey is available at: http://www.eia.gov/consumption/residential/. Additional questions were taken from the survey designed for Attari et al. (2010).

  13. Other health, energy, and financial variables were asked of respondents, although regression results are not reported here. The entire survey, including the questions not used in this study, is in Appendix B.

  14. Chapman and Elstein (1995) find that individuals discount monetary and medical outcomes at different rates, whereas Ioannou and Sadeh (2016) find no difference in discount rates for money versus an environmental outcome: the number of bee-friendly flowers planted.

  15. The questions are: “How patient are you in general?”, “How strong is your willpower/ability to control your impulses?”, “How difficult is it for you to avoid eating a snack food you enjoy (e.g. chocolate chip cookies, ice cream, potato chips) if it is easily available, even if you are not hungry?”

  16. We calculated this health-related discount factor by assuming that a consumer was indifferent at the mid-point between the first observed switching row. For respondents that never switched, but for example always chose drug B, we assumed the respondent was indifferent at the most extreme delayed row. Eighty-two percent of subjects exhibited zero or one switch for these migraine questions. Note that this methodology implicitly assumes a linear utility function for health-related outcomes.

  17. CRT scores are also positively correlated with several standardized test scores, including the SAT and the ACT (Frederick 2005 Table 4).

  18. In question 2, the intuitive answer is 100 min, but the correct answer is 5 min. In question 3, the intuitive answer is 24 days, but the correct answer is 47 days.

  19. Age and income are the only control variables with a non-trivial number of missing values (3.3% and 5% of the sample, respectively). The results are robust (with occasionally slightly less significance) to simply dropping observations with any missing demographic variables or creating missing value dummy variables and including these observations. For the continuous variables that are modeled as a series of dummies (e.g. age and income), we impute by first running linear regressions for the continuous measure and then discretizing the predicted value by rounding to the nearest applicable unit (e.g. year of age, dollar of income).

  20. We do not include CRT score as a control in the main specification because it likely depends at least partly on time preference. Adding it might therefore “control away” part of the causal effect of time preference. We acknowledge, though, that similar arguments could be made for some of the covariates we do include—namely education and income. It is therefore reassuring that including CRT score is of little consequence for the results.

  21. The results are generally similar using linear regressions, though the average marginal effects are often more precisely estimated by the non-linear models.

  22. Results are similar for regressions where the dependent variable is BMI or severe obesity (BMI ≥ 35).

  23. There are 66 respondents for whom the information required to calculate BMI is unavailable. Of those, all of them fail to report their weight, compared to just 25 who fail to report height.

  24. The results are robust to many other measures of smoking, including an indicator for being a regular smoker or for having smoked at least 100 cigarettes in one’s life. Results are similar but less significant for some other drinking measures, including number of drinks per week. We focus on binge drinking because moderate alcohol consumption is not necessarily unhealthy.

  25. The negative (though insignificant) association between δ and sunscreen use might occur because more patient people are less likely to be out in the sun at all, and therefore less often use sunscreen. The positive coefficient for the seat belt regressions is consistent with our expectations and it is mirrored by a slightly larger coefficient on β qh . An alternate hypothesis is that more patient people are less likely to wear a seat belt since they may drive more slowly or safely and not feel the need to wear one. The correlation we find could also be explained by aversion to being caught and fined, since this is a relatively easily detected violation.

  26. These findings are consistent with Allcott and Taubinsky (2015)—see their Table A2–1.

  27. By contrast, Newell and Siikamäki (2015) find that elicited discount factors (not allowing for quasi-hyperbolic discounting) are significantly correlated with energy-efficiency investment decisions. Their study differs from ours in a number of ways that may influence the results. First, their elicited time preferences are calculated from a series of hypothetical money trade-off questions, rather than our MPL questions that can accommodate quasi-hyperbolic preferences and in which actual (non-hypothetical) payouts are made to a random subset of respondents. Second, their energy-efficiency outcome variable is based on responses to a hypothetical choice experiment over water heater purchases, rather than actual energy-efficiency purchases. Their robust, significant results combined with our less strong results may suggest that present bias can sever the link between planned energy-efficiency investments (as measured in their hypothetical water heater purchases) and actual investments.

  28. However, Meier and Sprenger (2010) find a correlation between credit card balance and an indicator for present bias at either the 5% or 1% level depending on the specification. Their sample consists of primarily low- to moderate-income individuals whereas ours is representative of the overall population, which may explain the difference.

  29. In the main specifications in Tables 4 through 7, there are 41 statistically significant (at least the 10% level) coefficients, and in Appendix Tables A5 through A8 that number drops to 34, while the sample size for most of the regressions drops from about 800 to about 600 observations. Of the 41 coefficients that were statistically significant in our main results, the magnitudes actually increase for 25 of them after imposing the sample restriction, suggesting that the reduced statistical significance is merely the result of the smaller sample size.

  30. For instance, a Bonferroni correction would mean multiplying the p-value for our most highly significant result by 30, which strikes us as excessively cautious for a relatively small-scale survey. The procedure from Holm (1979) is also very conservative.

References

  • Ainslie, G. (1991). Derivation of “rational” economic behavior from hyperbolic discount curves. The American Economic Review, 81(2), 334–340.

  • Allcott, H., & Taubinsky, D. (2015). Evaluating behaviorally motivated policy: Experimental evidence from the lightbulb market. American Economic Review, 105(8), 2501–2538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allcott, H., & Wozny, N. (2014). Gasoline prices, fuel economy, and the energy paradox. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(10), 779–795.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, S., Harrison, G., Lau, M., & Rutstrom, E. E. (2008). Eliciting risk and time preferences. Econometrica, 76(3), 583–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J., & Sprenger, C. (2012a). Estimating time preferences from convex budgets. American Economic Review, 102(7), 3333–3356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J., & Sprenger, C. (2012b). Risk preferences are not time preferences. American Economic Review, 102(7), 3357–3376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ariely, D., & Wertenbroch, K. (2002). Procrastination, deadlines, and performance: Self-control by precommitment. Psychological Science, 13(3), 219–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arya, S., Eckel, C., & Wichman, C. (2013). Anatomy of the credit score. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 95, 175–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attari, S., DeKay, M., Davidson, C., & Bruine de Bruin, W. (2010). Public perceptions of energy consumption and savings. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 107(7), 16054–16059.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Augenblick, N., Niederle, M., & Sprenger, C. (2015). Working over time: Dynamic inconsistency in real effort tasks. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(3), 1067–1115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axon, R. N., Bradford, W. D., & Egan, B. M. (2009). The role of individual time preferences in health behaviors among hypertensive adults. Journal of the American Society of Hypertension, 3(1), 35–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2004). Willpower and personal rules. Journal of Political Economy, 112(4), 848–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradford, W. D. (2010). The association between individual time preferences and health maintenance habits. Medical Decision Making, 30, 99–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradford, W. D., Zoller, J., & Silvestri, G. (2010). Estimating the effect of individual time preferences on the use of disease screening. Southern Economic Journal, 76, 1005–1031.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burks, S., Carpenter, J., Gotte, L., & Rustichini, A. (2012). Which measures of time preference best predict outcomes? Evidence from a large-scale field experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 84(1), 308–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, G. D., Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B. C., & Metrick, A. (2009). Optimal defaults and active decisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 1639–1674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chabris, C., Laibson, D., Morris, C., Schuldt, J., & Taubinsky, D. (2008). Individual laboratory-measured discount rates predict field behavior. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 37(2/3), 237–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chapman, G. B., & Elstein, A. S. (1995). Valuing the future: Temporal discounting of health and money. Medical Decision Making, 15, 373–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courtemanche, C., Heutel, G., & McAlvanah, P. (2015). Impatience, incentives and obesity. Economic Journal, 125, 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, S., & Malmendier, U. (2006). Paying not to go to the gym. American Economic Review, 96(3), 694–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, H., & Silverman, D. (2009). Time-inconsistency and welfare program participation: Evidence from the NLSY. International Economic Review, 50(4), 1043–1077.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferecatu, A., & Önçüler, A. (2016). Heterogeneous risk and time preferences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 53(1), 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S. (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ganiats, T. G., Carson, R. T., Hamm, R. M., Cantor, S. B., Sumner, W., Spann, S. J., Hagen, M. D., & Miller, C. (2000). Population-based time preferences for future health outcomes. Medical Decision Making, 20(3), 263–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillingham, K., & Palmer, K. (2014). Bridging the energy efficiency gap: Policy insights from economic theory and empirical evidence. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 8(1), 18–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holm, S. (1979). A simple sequentially rejective multiple test procedure. Scandinavian Journal of Statistics, 6(2), 65–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ioannou, C. A., & Sadeh, J. (2016). Time preferences and risk aversion: Tests on domain differences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 53(1), 29–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 443–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lubotsky, D., & Wittenberg, M. (2006). Interpretation of regressions with multiple proxies. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(3), 549–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meier, S., & Sprenger, C. (2010). Present-biased preferences and credit card borrowing. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2(1), 193–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newell, R. G., & Siikamäki, J. (2015). Individual time preferences and energy efficiency. American Economic Review, 105(5), 196–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruhm, C. J. (2012). Understanding overeating and obesity. Journal of Health Economics, 31(6), 781–796.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1937). A note on measurement of utility. Journal of Economic Studies, 4(2), 155–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strotz, R. H. (1955). Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization. The Review of Economic Studies, 23(3), 165–180.

  • Scharff, R. L., & Viscusi, W. K. (2011). Heterogeneous rates of time preference and the decision to smoke. Economic Inquiry, 49(4), 959–972.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stanovich, K., & Wests, R. (2000). Individual differences in reasoning: Implications for the rationality debate? Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 22(5), 645–726.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutter, M., Kocher, M., Rutzler, D., & Trautmann, S. (2013). Impatience and uncertainty: Experimental decisions predict adolescents’ field behavior. American Economic Review, 103(1), 510–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka, T., Camerer, C. F., & Nguyen, Q. (2010). Risk and time preferences: Linking experimental and household survey data from Vietnam. American Economic Review, 100(1), 557–571.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. (1981). Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Economics Letters, 8(3), 201–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toubia, O., Johnson, E., Evgeniou, T., & Delquié, P. (2013). Dynamic experiments for estimating preferences: An adaptive method of eliciting time and risk parameters. Management Science, 59(3), 613–640.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Der Pol, M. (2011). Health, education, and time preference. Health Economics, 20(8), 917–929.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Gaudecker, H.-M., Van Soest, A., & Wengström, E. (2011). Heterogeneity in risky choice behavior in a broad population. American Economic Review, 101(2), 664–694.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weller, R., Cook, E., Avsar, K., & Cox, J. (2008). Obese women show greater delay discounting than healthy-weight women. Appetite, 51, 563–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Will Mautz and Camden Sweed for valuable research assistance, Georgia State University, the University of North Carolina at Greensboro, and the Harvard Center for Risk Analysis for funding, Darren Lubotsky for providing his code to implement the multiple proxies procedure, and Allen Bellas and conference and seminar participants at UNCG, GSU, Georgia Tech, the Federal Trade Commission, the Midwest Economics Association meetings, and the Harvard Center For Risk Analysis’s March 2014 “Risk, Perception, and Response” conference for helpful comments. Ruhm thanks the University of Virginia Bankard Fund for partial financial support. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Trade Commission.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Garth Heutel.

Electronic supplementary material

ESM 1

(PDF 1248 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bradford, D., Courtemanche, C., Heutel, G. et al. Time preferences and consumer behavior. J Risk Uncertain 55, 119–145 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-018-9272-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-018-9272-8

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation