Allais, M. (1953). “Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque, critique des postulats et axiomes de l’ecole americaine,” Econometrica 21, 503–546.
Google Scholar
Allais, M. (1979). “The Foundations of a Positive Theory of Choice Involving Risk and a Criticism of the Postulates and Axioms of the American School.” In M. Allais and O. Hagen (eds.), Expected Utility Hypotheses and the Allais Paradox, pp.~27–145. Holland, Dordrecht: D. Reidel.
Google Scholar
Arrow, K.J. (1971). Essays in the Theory of Risk Bearing. Chicago, IL: Markham.
Google Scholar
Bell, D.E. (1985). “Disappointment in Decision Making Under Uncertainty,” Operations Research 33, 1–27.
Google Scholar
Bell, D.E. (1995). “Risk, Return, and Utility,” Management Science 41, 23–30.
Google Scholar
Camerer, C. (1995). “Individual Decision Making.” In J.H. Kagel and A.E. Roth (eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics, pp. 587–683. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Google Scholar
Coombs, C.H. (1975). “Portfolio Theory and the Measurement of Risk.” In M.F. Kaplan and S. Schwartz (eds.), Human Judgment and Decision Processes, pp. 63–85. New York: Academic Press, Inc.
Google Scholar
Coombs, C.H. and P.E. Lehner. (1981). “An Evaluation of Two Alternative Models for a Theory of Risk: Part 1.” Journal of Experimental Psychology, Human Perception and Performance 7, 1110–1123.
Google Scholar
Coombs, C.H. and P.E. Lehner. (1984). “Conjoint Design and Analysis of the Bilinear Model: An Application to Judgments of Risk,” Journal of Mathematical Psychology 28, 1–42.
Google Scholar
Edwards, W. (1954). “The Reliability of Probability-Preferences,” American Journal of Psychology 68, 68–95.
Google Scholar
Fishburn, P.C. and R.L. Keeney. (1975). “Generalized Utility Independence and Some Implications,” Operations Research 23, 928–940.
Google Scholar
Harless, D.W. and C.F. Camerer. (1994). “The Predictive Utility of Generalized Expected Utility Theories,” Econometrica 62, 1251–1289.
Google Scholar
Holt, C.A. and S.K. Laury. (2002). “Risk Aversion and Incentive Effects,” American Economic Review 92, 1644–1655.
Google Scholar
Jia, J. (1995). “Measures of Risk and Risk-Value Theory.” Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Texas at Austin, TX unpublished.
Jia, J. and J.S. Dyer. (1996). “A Standard Measure of Risk and Risk-Value Models,” Management Science 42, 1961–1705.
Google Scholar
Jia, J. and J.S. Dyer. (2001). “Risk-Value Theory.” Working Paper, Graduate School of Business, University of Texas at Austin, TX.
Google Scholar
Jia, J., J.S. Dyer, and J.C. Butler. (1999). “Measures of Perceived Risk,” Management Science 45, 519–532.
Google Scholar
Jia, J., J.S. Dyer, and J.C. Butler. (2001). “Generalized Disappointment Models,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 22, 59–78.
Google Scholar
Kahneman, D.H. and A. Tversky. (1979). “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk,” Econometrica 47, 263–290.
Google Scholar
Keeney, R.L. and H. Raiffa. (1976). Decisions with Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value Tradeoffs. New York: Wiley.
Google Scholar
Keller, L.R., R.K. Sarin, and M. Weber. (1986). “Empirical Investigation of Some Properties of the Perceived Riskiness of Gambles,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 38, 114–130.
Google Scholar
Levy, H. and M. Levy (2002a). “Experimental Tests of the Prospect Theory Value Function: A Stochastic Dominance Approach,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 89, 1058–1081.
Google Scholar
Levy, H. and M. Levy (2002b). “Prospect Theory: Much Ado About Nothing?” Management Science 48, 1338–1349.
Google Scholar
Loomes, G. and R. Sugden. (1986). “Disappointment and Dynamic Consistency in Choice Under Uncertainty,” Review of Economic Studies LIII, 271–282.
Google Scholar
Lopes, L.L. (1984). “Risk and Distributional Inequality,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 10, 465–485.
Google Scholar
Luce, R.D. and E.U. Weber. (1986). “An Axiomatic Theory of Conjoint, Expected Risk,” Journal of Mathematical Psychology 30, 188–205.
Google Scholar
Markowitz, H. (1959), Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. New York: John Wiley {&} Sons.
Google Scholar
Payne, J.W., D.J. Laughhunn, and R. Crum. (1980). “Translation of Gambles and Aspiration Level Effects in Risky Choice Behavior,” Management Science 26, 1039–1060.
Google Scholar
Payne, J.W., D.J. Laughhunn, and R. Crum. (1981). “Further Tests of Aspiration Level Effects in Risky Choice Behavior,” Management Science 27, 953–958.
Google Scholar
Pollatsek, A. and A. Tversky. (1970). “A Theory of Risk,” Journal of Mathematical Psychology 7, 540–553.
Google Scholar
Pratt, J.W. (1964). “Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large,” Econometrica 32, 122–136.
Google Scholar
Rotar, I.V. and A.G. Sholomitsky. (1994). “On the Pollatsek-Tversky Theorem on Risk,” Journal of Mathematical Psychology 38, 322–334.
Google Scholar
Sarin, R.K. and M. Weber. (1993). Risk-Value Models,” European Journal of Operational Research 70, 135–149.
Google Scholar
von Neumann, J. and O. Morgenstern. (1947). “Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Google Scholar
Wakker, P.P. (2003). The data of Levy and Levy (2002) “Prospect Theory: Much Ado About Nothing?” Actually Support Prospect Theory,” Management Science 49, 979–981.
Google Scholar
Weber, E.U. and W.P. Bottom. (1989). “Axiomatic Measures of Perceived Risk: Some Tests and Extensions,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 2, 113–131.
Google Scholar
Weber, E.U. and W.P. Bottom. (1990). “An Empirical Evaluation of the Transitivity, Monotonicity, Accounting, and Conjoint Axioms for Perceived Risk,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Process 45, 253–275.
Google Scholar
Weber, E.U. and C. Hsee. (1998). “Cross Cultural Differences in Risk Perception, but Cross Cultural Similarities in Attitudes Toward Perceived Risk,” Management Science 44, 1205–1217.
Google Scholar
Weber, E.U. and R.A. Milliman. (1997). “Perceived Risk Attitudes: Relating Risk Perception to Risky Choice,” Management Science 43, 123–144.
Google Scholar