Introduction

U.S. colleges and universities face a range of financial challenges. In recent decades, organizational cost pressures steadily rose while the share of state funding devoted to higher education fell (Archibald & Feldman, 2011, 2017; Kane et al., 2003). Higher education institutions responded to these trends by increasing net tuition revenue, but will find it difficult to produce further increases due to stagnating family income and concerns about student debt and access (Archibald & Feldman, 2017). The coronavirus pandemic has made the situation even more challenging in the short run by threatening key existing revenue streams and increasing spending pressures in a number of areas (Smith, 2020). These revenue streams will face further challenges in the late 2020s when the “birth dearth” that followed the Great Recession leads to a reduction in high school graduates (Grawe, 2018).

Researchers and practitioners have provided advice to colleges and universities on how to navigate this difficult financial terrain (Christensen & Eyring, 2011; Smith, 2020; Zemsky et al., 2005). A standard recommendation is for institutions to identify new programs in areas associated with rising demand by students and limited supply by other institutions. Online programs often receive a lot of attention due to growing student interest, especially from adult students. In a survey of chief academic officers, Allen et al. (2016, p. 21) found that 63% of these leaders believe that online education is critical to their institutions’ long-term strategy.

The views of administrators may be shaped by the financial success of online programs at some early entrants into the online market.Footnote 1 These institutions generated positive net revenue from their online programs and used it to cross-subsidize other programs and activities (Ortagus & Derreth, 2020). The positive net revenues associated with online programs relate to the presence of economies of scale and scope (Cheslock et al., 2016). The economies of scope limit the expenditure increase caused by the addition of an online program, while the economies of scale cause these new expenditures to be outpaced by new revenues once enrollments reach a certain threshold.

The experiences of some schools have limited applicability to all schools due to the “collective rationality” problem (Hannan & Freeman, 1977, p. 932). The number of students wanting an online education is not infinite, so the number of schools that can achieve a substantially-sized online program is limited. The number will be much smaller if online education is primarily concentrated, with a small number of higher education institutions enrolling most students, rather than fragmented, with large numbers of institutions enrolling meaningful numbers of online students. Researchers have not examined this topic despite the growing importance of online enrollment patterns. The number of students taking all of their coursework online increased by around 22% between Fall 2012 and Fall 2018, while the number of students taking in-person classes fell by around 9%. If online enrollments continue to grow as expected, they will increasingly shape the U.S. higher education system. To shed light into this increasingly important topic, this paper examines concentration levels in online education and how these levels change over time when the size of the online market expands.

We start by applying the lessons from Sutton’s endogenous fixed cost model to online education (Shaked & Sutton, 1987; Sutton, 1991, 1998). Although higher education researchers have highlighted the fixed costs that an institution must absorb in order to enter the online market with educational offerings that meet a basic level of quality (Jones, 2004; Meyer, 2006; Rumble, 1997), they have not similarly emphasized the role of fixed costs that are endogenous in that they rise with the level of quality. As our upcoming review of theory will attest, the presence of endogenous fixed costs can have significant implications for concentration levels in the market for online education if enrollments continue to expand as expected. Although basic scale economies become a weaker barrier to entry as market size grows, endogenous fixed costs, which increase with market size, can continue to prevent higher education institutions from creating successful new online programs even after market size becomes large. We apply these insights from Sutton’s model to predict online enrollment patterns.

We then employ the available data on online enrollments contained within the Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System (IPEDS), which spans the Fall 2012 to Fall 2018 period, to provide the first detailed description of market concentration in online education. Our work has four important features. First, we account for different dynamics at the local and national level by separately estimating k-organization concentration ratios for nonresident students and for 50 state-specific sets of resident students. Second, we explore how concentration ratios change as the definition of exclusively online enrollment narrows. Third, we compare enrollment patterns for online education to patterns for in-person education to provide a point of reference for online enrollments. Fourth, we examine how the role of the for-profit sector differs between in-person and online education, which indicates how opportunities for profit generation might vary between these two types of education.

We conclude the paper with a discussion that shifts attention away from higher education institutions and towards students. As institutions seek to sustain themselves financially, students are affected by their actions. We outline how concentration patterns could relate to institutional expenditure and tuition price patterns, and describe opportunities for further research into these areas. We also discuss how the ideas and findings in this paper relate to policy debates and research opportunities regarding practices such as expensive marketing campaigns (Cellini & Chaudhary, 2020) and the use of online program managers (Carey, 2019; Hall & Dudley, 2019).

Related Literature

The existing literature on enrollment patterns across institutions within the U.S. higher education system focuses primarily on in-person education. Past work described two broad historical transformations for in-person education. The first change relates to expansion in both the number of higher education institutions and the enrollment size of institutions as the demand for higher education grew over decades and centuries (Geiger, 2015; Goldin & Katz, 1999; Kwoka & Snyder, 2004). The second change relates to the distribution of students across institutions as the higher education industry moved from a collection of geographically isolated autarkies to a national market in which geographically disparate universities compete for the same students (Hoxby, 1997, 2009). Although the majority of students continued to attend nearby institutions after this shift, students with the strongest academic credentials increasingly enrolled in the most prestigious colleges, which led to greater between-institution inequality and smaller within-institution inequality in student test scores (Hoxby, 1997, 2009). These enrollment shifts did not lead to extremely large enrollment at any one institution, because national institutions restricted enrollment due to their focus on selectivity while local institutions were constrained by the size of nearby populations (Winston, 1999).

Researchers have not similarly examined enrollment patterns for online education, but they have investigated topics that shape enrollment patterns.Footnote 2 Ortagus and Yang (2018) found a negative relationship between changes in state appropriation funding and changes in online enrollment at public 4-year institutions, suggesting that financial challenges may spur institutions to launch and grow online programs. Skinner (2019) found that online enrollments were smaller at open admission public institutions when nearby broadband speeds were at the lower end of the spectrum.

While studying the economics of online education production, higher education researchers have noted that organizational scale could play an important role within online education (Jones, 2004; Meyer, 2006; Rumble, 1997). These authors described potential economies of scale in online education driven by substantial initial set-up costs and low marginal costs associated with expanded enrollments. Because schools would be hesitant to absorb set-up costs when the number of online students is not large, these costs can serve as a barrier to entering the online market and lead to a small number of schools capturing the available pool of online students. Empirical research documenting economies of scale in online education is sparse due to data limitations,Footnote 3 but authors have carefully specified the activities associated with the development, delivery, and administration of online education and described how each activity is likely to impact costs (Jones, 2004; Meyer, 2006; Rumble, 1997).

Industrial organization economists have long examined general questions pertaining to concentration. Ellickson (2015) provided a helpful overview of the approaches utilized in this literature, including the bounds approach associated with Sutton’s endogenous fixed cost model. Researchers have applied Sutton’s model to a range of industries, including book retailers (Latcovich & Smith, 2001), supermarkets (Ellickson, 2007), restaurants, and newspapers (Berry & Waldfogel, 2010). Although the model has not been applied to the case of higher education at length, Cowen and Tabarrok (2014) noted that Sutton’s model has great relevance to online education.

Sutton’s Endogenous Fixed Cost Model

Introduction to the Model

Berry and Waldfogel (2010) provided a concise and effective overview of Sutton’s model, and we utilize the structure and equations from their overview here. They employed three equations to capture key considerations relating to consumers (e.g., students) and organizations (e.g., universities). The first equation contains a utility function for a consumer i considering a product j:

$${\text{U}}_{{{\text{ij}}}} = \, \theta_{{\text{i}}} \delta_{{\text{j}}} - {\text{ p}}_{{\text{j}}} {-} \, \gamma \left( {{\text{v}}_{{\text{i}}} - {\text{x}}_{{\text{j}}} } \right)^{{2}}$$

In this model, δj represents vertical dimensions of quality. If δj were to increase, all consumers would value product j more highly. For example, all consumers prefer faster processing speeds for computers and smart phones. In contrast, the term xj represents horizontal dimensions of quality, whose valuation differs across consumers. For example, consumers differ in the preference for sweetness in iced tea. The valuation of product j would depend upon the distance between desired product attributes of the individual consumer (vi) and the actual attributes of the product (xj). The remaining parameters play the following roles: γ represents the importance of horizontal dimensions of quality in shaping the utility of consumers, θi represents the importance of vertical dimensions of quality, and pj is the price of product j.

The key organizational considerations relate to the cost structure of producing the product, and the below equations describe the factors shaping variable and fixed costs of the organization.

$${\text{VC}}\left( {{\text{q}}_{{\text{j}}} ,\delta_{{\text{j}}} } \right) \, = {\text{ q}}_{{\text{j}}} {\text{mc}}\left( {\delta_{{\text{j}}} } \right)$$
$${\text{FC }} = {\text{ FC}}\left( {\delta_{{\text{j}}} } \right)$$

VC(qjj) represents the variable costs of producing product j at a quantity level of qj and a (vertical) quality level of δj. For simplicity, the equation for variable costs assumes that marginal cost, mc, is constant in quantity (qj) and is increasing in quality (δj). FC(δj) represents the fixed costs, which depends on δj but by definition does not depend on qj.

The model has three implications that are important for the purposes of this paper. First, when increases in quality (δj) lead to large increases in variable costs, VC(qjj), but not fixed costs, FC(δj), concentration levels will likely fall when market size expands.Footnote 4 The rationale for this claim is that organizations offering high-quality products must charge substantially higher prices than organizations offering low-quality products in order to cover the high marginal costs associated with quality. As market size increases, organizations will have a greater incentive to enter the market with a product containing specific combinations of price and quality that match the tastes of specific bands of customers. In turn, this entrance reduces concentration.

Second, a market may remain concentrated as it grows if increases in δj lead to large increases in fixed costs, FC(δj), but not variable costs, VC(qjj). In this case, fixed costs associated with items such as advertising and R&D play a significant role in shaping quality (i.e., customers’ valuation of the product). These costs are endogenous as they relate to a choice variable for the organization pertaining to quality rather than basic set-up costs. As markets expand, the equilibrium level of endogenous fixed costs grows, so the barrier to entry associated with these fixed costs may not diminish in importance as it does with scale economies. Furthermore, organizations offering low-quality products will have difficulty competing, because high-quality products can be priced at similar levels as low-quality products when markets are large and fixed costs can be spread across a large number of consumers. For these reasons, the presence of endogenous fixed costs can cause a market to remain concentrated as its size expands.

Third, although Sutton’s results hold when horizontal dimensions of quality are present, the market will be relatively less concentrated when these dimensions are important, because more organizations will enter the market and specialize to meet the tastes of specific bands of consumers (Sutton, 1991). A key horizontal dimension of quality relates to the distance between consumers and organizations. When consumers prefer nearby organizations, more organizations will enter the market to serve nearby populations.

Before we apply this model to higher education, we need to address one potential source of confusion regarding the term quality. This term is used very differently within the industrial organization literature in economics than within higher education journals. Within economics, the term essentially relates to the valuation of enrollment opportunities by prospective students. A student is more likely to enroll in an online program if she assigns a high valuation to the program and is less likely to enroll if she assigns a low valuation. Colleges and universities can shape a student’s valuation by increasing its advertising or increasing its investment in activities such as instruction and student services. In regard to concentration levels, the degree to which different types of expenditures shape valuation is irrelevant within Sutton’s model. The key issue is that an institution will have difficulty attracting students if it does not spend sufficient funds on the types of expenditures that shape valuation. As we will discuss later in this paper, the impact of spending on student learning and societal well-being will vary across alternative types of expenditures.

Application of the Model to Higher Education

Sutton’s model, and industrial organization theory in general, assumes that the sole objective of organizations is to maximize profits. This assumption aligns with the behavior of for-profit colleges and universities, which seek to distribute profits to their owners. In contrast, nonprofit institutions, especially publicly-controlled ones, are motivated by a more complex set of objectives that includes non-financial objectives such as the provision of access to district or state residents. Due to these differences by sector, we should expect Sutton’s model to better predict enrollment patterns in the for-profit sector than in the nonprofit sector. Similar to the organizations in the model, we expect for-profit institutions to not enter the online market in the presence of fixed costs unless they can attain scale so that these costs are spread across a large number of students. Contrastingly, in order to meet non-financial objectives, nonprofit institutions may sometimes choose to enter the online market even if they cannot obtain the scale required for positive net revenue. When scale can be achieved, nonprofits may be less driven to obtain the exact level of scale that would maximize net revenue because financial objectives are less central to these organizations. If fewer for-profit institutions enter the online market and those that do disproportionately operate at scale, then online enrollments will be more concentrated in the for-profit sector than in the nonprofit sector.

Although financial considerations are less central to nonprofit institutions, they still shape decision-making pertaining to online education. Slaughter and Leslie (1997) and Slaughter and Rhoades (2004) describe how nonprofit colleges and universities increasingly engage in academic capitalism by emphasizing financial considerations within their decision-making. This practice may be especially prevalent in online education, because Sjogren and Fay (2002) note that administrators often expect online courses and programs to more than pay for themselves.

When nonprofits, especially public institutions, do consider non-financial objectives pertaining to online education, they are most likely to do so for online programs targeted at state residents (rather than online programs oriented towards the national market). A public institution may create a locally-oriented online program in an area of need for the state even if the program does not generate positive net revenue. In contrast, a for-profit institution will be very unlikely to create an online program for non-financial reasons.

These distinctions by organizational sector and student residency can sharpen predictions regarding a central question: How will concentration levels in online education change as the size of the online market expands? If we relied upon Sutton’s model to answer this question, the salient concern would then become whether or not a student’s valuation of an online program (i.e., quality) is primarily determined by factors relating to the institution’s spending on fixed costs. Journalistic accounts of large online providers suggest that these schools spend considerable amounts of money on fixed costs relating to recruitment, student services, and course development, which can all shape potential students’ valuation of their educational offerings (Blumenstyk, 2018; McKenzie, 2019). These investments fund items like national marketing campaigns and improvements to student-information systems. If the activities associated with fixed costs are central for attracting and retaining students, then institutions that do not spend heavily on them will have difficulty building their enrollments. Sutton’s model implies that the needed level of spending will grow as the size of the online market expands. Only a small set of schools will find it in their financial interest to spend at these levels, and as a result, this small set of schools will be able to capture a substantial share of enrollments.

Because Sutton’s model better aligns with decisions pertaining to nationally-oriented programs than locally-oriented programs, we should expect nonresident enrollment patterns and resident enrollment patterns to react differently to increases in the online market. For nonresident enrollment, we would adopt the prediction emanating from the model: Nonresident online enrollment will be concentrated and remain concentrated even after the online market expands.Footnote 5 Relatively few institutions will expend the resources that are required for successful competition in regional or national online markets.

We might expect a different pattern for resident enrollments for two reasons. First, nonfinancial objectives not present in Sutton’s model (i.e., a commitment to providing access to state residents) will encourage public institutions to respond to growing student interest by launching online programs for resident students.Footnote 6 Second, financial considerations may not deter market entry, because locally-oriented programs may not require large spending on marketing or other areas if some prospective online students prefer nearby institutions (i.e., if horizontal dimensions of quality are important). Although online students value proximity less than in-person students do, they likely still possess at least a weak preference for local institutions.Footnote 7 If an expanding market allows an institution to attract a meaningful number of nearby students due to a preference for local schools, the institution’s entrance into the online market may not produce substantial financial losses and might even produce gains.Footnote 8 For the two reasons noted in this paragraph, we would expect concentration levels for resident online enrollment within a specific state to be more likely to fall as the size of the online market expands.

Although our focus is on online education, our empirical analysis will also include an examination of in-person enrollment patterns in order to provide a point of reference. Industrial organization theory provides three considerations that suggest online enrollments will be more concentrated than in-person enrollments. First, as noted earlier, horizontal dimensions of quality relating to geographical proximity are less important in online education, because online students do not need to relocate in order to enroll at non-local institutions. Second, economies of scale are stronger in online education than in-person education due to the lower marginal costs associated with enrollment increases (Cowen & Tabarrok, 2014; Jones, 2004; Meyer, 2006).Footnote 9 Third, the size of the market for online education is currently small relative to the size of the market for in-person education.

Data and Methods

Our primary data source is IPEDS. We extracted institution-level data from the IPEDS Fall Enrollment survey component—specifically the Fall Enrollment by Distance Education Status sub-component and the Residence and Migration sub-component—and the IPEDS Institutional Characteristics survey component.Footnote 10 The analysis period is Fall 2012 through Fall 2018, which represent all years for which distance education enrollment data are available.

The analysis sample is the universe of Title IV institutions. A Title IV institution is an organization that provides postsecondary education and is eligible to enroll students who receive Title IV federal financial aid (Congressional Research Service, 2007).Footnote 11 Title IV institutions must obtain institution-level accreditation by an accrediting agency recognized by the U.S. Department of Education and satisfy requirements stipulated in the Program Participation Agreement (PPA) contract with the U.S. Department of Education, including annual completion of all components of the IPEDS survey. A Title IV institution may be a single-campus institution or a multi-campus institution with a main campus and one or more branch campuses.Footnote 12 Because multiple campuses from the same Title IV institution sometimes report enrollment data separately, we aggregate data reported at the campus-level to the Title IV institution-level using digits 2–5 of the Office of Postsecondary Education Identification (OPEID) code as recommended by Jaquette and Parra (2016).

The IPEDS Fall Enrollment component represents an annual fall snapshot of the number of students enrolled in courses for credit, including both degree-seeking students and non-degree-seeking students. The Fall Enrollment by Distance Education Status sub-component identifies three types of students with respect to mode of education (U.S. Department of Education, 2017): First, “enrolled exclusively in distance education courses,” defined as students who are enrolled only in courses that are considered distance education courses; second, “enrolled in some but not all distance education courses,” defined as students who are enrolled in at least one course that is considered a distance education course, but are not enrolled exclusively in distance education courses; and, third, students “not enrolled in any distance education courses.”Footnote 13 For the analysis reported in this paper, we combine the latter two categories because students who enroll in some in-person coursework will face similar geographical constraints during the college choice search as students who enroll entirely in in-person coursework. For brevity, we refer to enrollment for this combined group as “in-person enrollment.” Our results do not differ qualitatively when we instead solely use the last category to measure in-person enrollment.

To examine how the market structures for online and in-person education relate to geography, we separately examine resident and nonresident enrollments. We obtained resident and nonresident online enrollments from the Distance Education Status sub-component, which collects enrollment data separately for online students who are located in the same state as their institution and for online students who are located in a different state or country as their institution. To create measures of resident and nonresident enrollment for in-person students, we used the Residence and Migration sub-component. This sub-component contains limitations as it only collects data for first-time undergraduate students and does not report figures separately for online and in-person students. We are able to make adjustments to account for some of these limitations, because the Distance Education Status sub-component also includes figures reported separately for undergraduate and graduate students.Footnote 14

We also examine how concentration levels change when we adjust our definition of online students. IPEDS reports enrollment patterns based solely upon the fall semester in question rather than the student’s degree program. A student who reports enrolling exclusively in online courses during the Fall 2018 semester, for example, may take in-person courses during other semesters. Students who take both in-person and online coursework in their degree program should have less concentrated enrollment patterns than students who take their entire degree program online, because the former students are more likely to attend higher education institutions that are geographically proximate. IPEDS data will consequently provide a limited portrait of the enrollment choices of students desiring an exclusively online education and the enrollment outcomes of institutions that offer exclusively online degree programs.

The 2012 National Postsecondary Student Aid Study (NPSAS) contains information that, when used in conjunction with IPEDS, can produce rough enrollment estimates for the number of students whose entire degree program is online. Unlike other editions of NPSAS, NPSAS:12 asked students both whether all of their coursework for the academic year was entirely online and whether their entire degree program was entirely online. We used this information to calculate estimates of “online degree program” enrollments for each school via three steps. First, we estimated logit regressions where the probability that an “online” student is in an “online degree program” depends upon several key variables that relate to market concentration.Footnote 15 Second, we multiplied the coefficients from this logit regression by the relevant values for each institution in our sample to produce adjustment parameters for each school. Third, we multiplied these adjustment parameters by the original IPEDS measures of “online” enrollment to produce estimates of “online degree program” enrollment.Footnote 16 As we will discuss in more detail in the results section, our findings do not generally change when we use these adjusted enrollments rather than the originally reported IPEDS enrollments. The primary difference is that our estimates of online enrollment concentration increase in magnitude when adjusted enrollments are used.

To assess concentration levels, we report k-organization concentration ratios, which measure the combined share of total enrollment of the largest k universities. Although we examined a wide range of concertation ratios and other measures (e.g., Herfindahl index), we report concentration ratios for 1, 2, 5, 10, and 20 institutions because we found that these five concentration ratios describe the observed concentration patterns well. We also report basic descriptive statistics and the number of institutions within certain enrollment bands in order to more fully describe the distribution of enrollments across higher education institutions. Because enrollment patterns differ meaningfully across sectors, we report results separately for public, private nonprofit, and private for-profit institutions after reporting results for all institutions.

Results

Market Concentration in Online Education

While applying Sutton’s model to the U.S. higher education system, we predicted that online nonresident enrollment would be concentrated and would remain concentrated as the size of the online market grows over time. We also predicted that resident enrollment concentration would be more likely to fall as market size expands for reasons both related and unrelated to the model. Table 1 reports concentration ratios estimated separately for nonresident (panel B) and resident (panel C) students. Consistent with our expectations, the concentration ratios computed solely using data for nonresident students reveal highly concentrated enrollments. In 2018, the two institutions with largest online nonresident enrollments accounted for a bit less than 1 out of every 6 online nonresident students (15.5%). The largest five institutions enrolled a bit less than 1 out of every 3 students (30.5%). The share moved close to one-half (45.1%) for the 10 largest institutions and well over one-half (59.6%) for the 20 largest institutions.

Table 1 Online concentration ratios for nonresident and resident students by institutional control, Fall 2012 & Fall 2018

The overall changes in concentration levels did not align with our expectations when all institutions were examined but did align when only nonprofit institutions were examined. Concentration ratios fell between 2012 and 2018 in the former case and rose in the latter case. These varying results relate to a dramatic drop in online enrollments within the for-profit sector, which initially contained the largest providers of online education. After rapid enrollment growth during the 2000s, large for-profit institutions struggled to attract online students in the 2010s amid poor outcomes for online students at for-profits, new federal regulations, and intensive media coverage of troubling organizational behavior (Cellini & Turner, 2019; Fabina, 2019; Fountain, 2019; Kinser & Zipf, 2019). Nonresident online enrollment declined by almost 300,000 students for the for-profit sector. In contrast, nonresident online enrollment increased by slightly over 400,000 students at nonprofit institutions. These new enrollments at nonprofits were heavily captured by the largest providers, which caused nonprofit concentration ratios to increase.

As the for-profit share of nonresident enrollments steadily fell from 65 to 37% between 2012 and 2018, the enrollment reductions in the for-profit sector had a declining influence on overall concentration levels. Figure 1 reports nonresident concentration ratios for each year, with separate results by institutional type. Overall concentration levels plateaued near the end of the period and even slightly increased between 2017 and 2018. The trends for the nonprofit sector increasingly shape overall trends, and concentration ratios are not falling for this sector. If these trends persist, a relatively small number of higher education institutions will continue to enroll most nonresident online students. Although overall nonresident concentration levels have fallen since 2012, a meaningful amount of concentration remains. For both the nonprofit and overall market in Fall 2018, the majority of nonresident online enrollments are captured by fewer than 15 higher education institutions.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Nonresident online enrollment concentration ratios

Panel C of Table 1 reports figures that describe concentration levels for resident students. For each individual state, concentration ratios were computed using resident enrollment solely for that state (e.g., Michigan residents enrolled online at Michigan postsecondary institutions). Weighted means were then computed from these 50 state-specific ratios, with each state’s level of online resident enrollment serving as the weight.

As expected, the results reveal very different patterns for nonresident students. State-specific resident concentration ratios were similar to national nonresident concentration ratios, especially for the nonprofit sector, even though individual states only contain a small fraction of the total number of higher education institutions. The five largest online institutions in a state typically captured around one-third of all online resident enrollments while the five largest online institutions in the nation acquired a similar share of all online nonresident enrollments.

The results reveal that resident student concentration levels fell during our period, on average.Footnote 17 The trends are very similar for the overall market and for the nonprofit sector, because for-profit institutions primarily enroll nonresident students. The reductions in concentration are meaningfully sized, as concentration ratios generally dropped by 4–6 percentage points. These declines occurred steadily throughout the period as each concentration ratio fell for each year-to-year change.

In summary, Table 1 highlights three different trends in the market for online education: falling nonresident concentration due to declines in enrollment at large for-profit institutions, slightly increasing nonresident concentration within the nonprofit sector, and falling resident concentration within most states. The trend for the entire online market will reflect these three trends as well as trends in the share of students who are resident students.Footnote 18 Although we do not report the findings here, we also examined concentration ratios for total online enrollment for each year during the 2012–2018 period. The trends for these concentration ratios are very similar to those reported for nonresident students in Table 1 and Fig. 1. Ratios fell for all institutions but rose slightly for nonprofit institutions. The negative trend for all institutions plateaued near the end of the period and slightly increased between 2017 and 2018.

Table 2 reports concentration ratios for total online enrollment in 2018. Because the national distribution of resident enrollments is relatively fragmented, these concentration ratios for total enrollments are lower than their nonresident-specific and resident-specific counterparts from Table 1. That said, a meaningful amount of concentration remains. For example, the largest 10 institutions in regards to online enrollment capture 20.8% of the online market. The sector-specific ratios reveal much lower concentration in the public sector than in the private nonprofit and for-profit sectors, which is a byproduct of relatively large online resident enrollments in the public sector and relatively large online nonresident enrollments in the other two sectors.

Table 2 Adjusted and unadjusted online concentration ratios by institutional control, Fall 2018

Table 2 also reports concentration ratios for our estimates of enrollments in exclusively online degree programs. Our IPEDS measure of online enrollments includes students who are enrolled online for the fall semester in question but not for all of their coursework in their degree program. Data from NPSAS:12 indicate that around 83% of students who are enrolled exclusively online during the 2011–2012 academic year were enrolled in a degree program that was entirely online. The results from a logit regression, reported in Appendix Table 6, reveal that this share varies across several key variables that relate to market concentration.Footnote 19

Using the procedures outlined in our data and methods section, we used these regression results to produce institution-level estimates of enrollments in exclusively online degree programs. We then used these enrollment estimates to produce concentration ratios for this narrower definition of online enrollment, which are reported in Table 2. The results indicate that concentration ratios are 20–25% higher than the ratios produced by unadjusted IPEDS online enrollments.Footnote 20 The ratios are higher for the narrower definition, because resident students at public institutions are most likely to enroll entirely in online classes for one term even though they are not in an exclusively online degree program. When a substantial portion of public resident enrollments is removed, the share of total online enrollments that are captured by large national providers becomes greater.

Comparing Online Education with In-Person Education

Table 3 contains 2018 figures for in-person education that are similar to those presented in Table 2 for online education. The results reveal that enrollment patterns for in-person education are much more fragmented. The 10 largest providers of in-person enrollment only capture 3.8% of total enrollment while the corresponding figure for online enrollments from Table 2 is 20.8%. The differences are especially striking in the private sectors. In the private nonprofit sector, the largest 10 institutions capture around a tenth (9.8%) of the in-person students, while the same ratio for online enrollments is almost one-half (47.3%) of students. For the private for-profit sector, the corresponding figures are 16.6% and 75.0%.

Table 3 In-Person concentration ratios by institutional control, Fall 2018

Concentration ratios are drastically higher for online education than for in-person education, because online education ratios have much smaller denominators (total enrollment) but have similarly-sized, and sometimes larger, numerators (enrollment of largest providers). Total enrollment for online education (3,206,915) is one-fifth of total enrollment for in-person education (16,653,084). Yet, the three largest providers of online education (Western Governors University, Southern New Hampshire University, and University of Phoenix) all had enrollments above 96,000, while the largest provider of in-person education (Pennsylvania State University) had an enrollment of 76,933.

Not only is the level of scale different for online than for in-person education, but the recipe for scale also differs. Large online providers achieve scale by primarily enrolling nonresident students while large in-person providers achieve scale by primarily enrolling resident students. Table 4 documents this point by reporting the average nonresident enrollment shares for specific enrollment bands for both online and in-person. Nonresident share and enrollment size are positively related for online education but not for in-person education.

Table 4 Average nonresident undergraduate enrollment share by enrollment size, Fall 2018

The differences between in-person and online education described in this section align with the expectations stated earlier in this paper. Institutions can more easily scale their online programs than their in-person programs because expanding online enrollment slots at scale is less expensive (due to lower marginal costs) and filling online enrollment slots at scale is less challenging (due to the ease by which online students can attend distant institutions). The peculiar economics associated with in-person education also plays a role, because it leads top ranked institutions to respond to strong student demand by becoming more selective rather than scaling enrollments (Hoxby, 2009; Winston, 1999). Selectivity increases the academic credentials of incoming students and the subsidy level per student, two factors that determine student demand (Winston, 1999). The in-person students who are most willing to relocate for college typically enroll at well-resourced selective institutions (Hoxby, 2009). Thus, the institutions that seek to scale in-person education typically focus on local populations and are consequently constrained by the size of those populations.

Further Examination of the For-Profit Sector

Comparing online and in-person enrollment patterns across sectors can reveal further insights. Tables 1 and 2 revealed that the for-profit sector was more concentrated than the nonprofit sector, and our earlier theoretical discussion predicted that would be the case because for-profit institutions are more likely to act in accordance with Sutton’s model. Specifically, they will be less likely to enter the market and more likely to operate at scale when they do enter the market.

Table 5 reports a number of statistics that allow for examination by sector of both market entry and enrollment scale for institutions that enter. We do find that for-profit institutions are relatively unlikely to enter the online market, while public institutions, who are driven by access considerations alongside financial considerations, disproportionately choose to enter. The share of for-profit institutions with non-zero online enrollment is 9.2%, while the corresponding share for public institutions is 80.9%.Footnote 21 The difference narrows when we solely examine 4-year institutions, because less-than-4-year for-profit institutions are especially unlikely to enter the online market.Footnote 22

Table 5 Market entry and enrollment size by institutional control, Fall 2018

We also find that for-profit institutions are more likely to operate at scale. Among those institutions that entered the online market, 18.1% of 4-year for-profits enroll at least 5000 online students while the corresponding figures for 4-year public and private nonprofit institutions are 4.7% and 2.4%. The mean enrollment at 4-year for-profits is three times as large as the mean enrollment for publics and six times as large as the mean enrollment for private nonprofits. The median online enrollment at for-profits, however, is well below the median at public institutions, so when not operating at large scales, for-profit institutions are more likely to operate small, rather than moderately sized, online programs.Footnote 23

The in-person enrollment patterns reported in Table 5 paint a very different portrait of differences across sectors. Large numbers of institutions from each sector have entered the in-person market, and for-profit institutions disproportionately operate at small scales. Because for-profit institutions are more likely to select those activities that best produce profits, these differences by sector suggest that a large number of local small-scale profitable opportunities exist for in-person education, while a small number of large-scale nationally-oriented profitable opportunities are present for online education.

Spending on Endogenous Fixed Costs

Sutton’s model has implications for expenditure patterns as well as enrollment patterns, because the model implies that expenditures on endogenous fixed costs by leading online institutions will increase as the size of the online market grows over time. Up to this point, we have solely focused our attention on enrollment patterns because the available expenditure data for higher education institutions contain numerous limitations. The IPEDS Finance component does not distinguish between expenditures for online programs and expenditures for in-person programs and does not classify expenditures in a way that allows spending on endogenous fixed costs to be measured. The data submitted by higher education institutions to the Internal Revenue Service and the general public via Form 990 also does not distinguish between online and in-person programs and is only provided by private nonprofit institutions.

Form 990, however, does classify expenditures in a helpful manner, because it requires schools to report their level of advertising and promotion expenditures. Advertising is one of the primary examples, along with R&D, used by Sutton (1991) in discussions of endogenous fixed costs. Consequently, Form 990 data can provide insight, albeit limited, into whether or not leading national universities increase their spending on endogenous fixed costs as market size expands. Increased spending by existing large providers can dissuade other institutions from entering the national market and lead the market for nonresident students to remain concentrated.

Figure 2 reports advertising and promotion expenditures for the four private nonprofit institutions with the largest nonresident online enrollments in the Fall of 2012. Unlike most other online providers in the private nonprofit sector, these schools solely enroll online students (Western Governors University and Excelsior) or primarily enroll online students (Liberty University and Southern New Hampshire). As a group, they captured 50% of the nonresident online enrollments in the private nonprofit sector in Fall 2012. The expenditure trends in Fig. 2 support Sutton’s model in that two of the four institutions invested heavily in advertising and retained, and even grew, their market share. Between the 2012 and 2018 fiscal years, real advertising and promotion expenditures increased by around 180% at Western Governors University and 1,120% at Southern New Hampshire University. At the same time, these institutions increased their nonresident online enrollments by 197% and 1055%.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Nonresident online enrollment and advertising and promotion expenditures for the four largest private nonprofit online providers

Discussion

Sutton’s model of endogenous fixed costs suggests that the impact of expanding market size on concentration will depend upon whether a student’s valuation of an online program (i.e., quality) is produced primarily through spending on fixed costs or spending on variable costs. If endogenous fixed costs, such as advertising and R&D, are important determinants of quality, then we should find that concentration levels remain substantial even as market size grows large. The magnitude of these concentration levels may be tempered if horizontal dimensions of quality (e.g., the distance between seller and buyer) are important. If some customers have a preference for nearby organizations, then more organizations will enter the market as small local providers. When applied to online education, this model suggests that the online market will be concentrated and contain a small number of large providers capturing an enduring share of nonresident students and large number of small providers primarily enrolling resident students.

In our empirical analyses, we find that relative to in-person education, national online enrollment patterns are heavily concentrated. The largest ten online providers captured around 20–25% of online enrollment during the Fall of 2018. The scale of these large providers is driven by the enrollment of nonresident students. Over 40% of online students enroll outside of their home state, and almost half of these nonresident students congregate at 10 large providers. A substantial number of small local providers exist alongside these large national providers.

Overall concentration levels fell between Fall 2012 and Fall 2018 as the enrollments of large for-profit institutions plummeted. Yet substantial levels of concentration remained present in the online market, because concentration levels in the nonprofit sector actually increased over this period. The rise of large nonprofit “mega-universities” (Blumentyk, 2018; Gardner, 2019) meant that overall concentration levels started to plateau, and even slightly rise, by the end of our study period. Data on marketing expenditures by rapidly expanding “mega-universities” match expectations flowing from Sutton’s model. In combination, the trends we observe suggest that the national online market may remain fairly concentrated in the decades to come.

Sutton’s model enhances our understanding of these patterns and their consequences by highlighting the role of endogenous fixed costs, a type of costs that have received very little attention by higher education researchers. Analysts that ignore these costs will underestimate the organizational costs associated with online education and the level of concentration in online enrollment patterns. Greater attention should be paid to endogenous fixed costs, especially in regard to questions pertaining to magnitude, type, and outsourcing.

The magnitude of endogenous fixed costs that an institution must incur in order to compete in the national market will shape both enrollment patterns and organizational costs. A highly concentrated market with large spending requirements will mean that relatively few higher education institutions will be able to leverage economies of scale and scope to generate substantial positive net tuition revenue. A majority of chief academic officers believe that online education is critical to their institutions’ long-term strategy (Allen et al., 2016), so concentrated benefits will heighten the financial sustainability challenges facing many institutions.

The magnitude of spending also carries implications for online students, because it can shape the quality and price of online education. Within the industrial organizational literature from economics, the term quality refers to the valuation of enrollment opportunities by prospective students. These valuations determine the enrollment decisions of these students. We don’t yet have a clear sense of how specific types of expenditures (e.g., advertising and recruitment, student services, instruction) shape the valuations of online students. The most influential expenditures will naturally grow in prominence if institutions compete for students by spending on those items that most affect their enrollment decisions.

Higher education researchers are more likely to use the term quality in relation to student learning, development, and outcomes. They will consequently be very interested in whether spending competitions are centered on instruction and student services rather than on advertising and recruitment. We should expect student learning and outcomes to expand more rapidly if institutions compete by focusing further on the development of richly interactive, high-quality online course materials rather than by increasing the level of advertising.Footnote 24 If online enrollments continue to grow as expected, the nation’s stock of human capital will be increasingly shaped by the nature of online education.

The magnitude and type of spending will influence the decisions of students who are choosing between their local broad access institutions, non-profit mega-universities, and for-profit institutions. Questions about the quality of these educational options relate to important equity concerns about the U.S. higher education system, and Sutton’s model highlights specific questions pertaining to educational spending. Investments into the academic quality of online programs at local broad access institutions will be shaped by the number of students enrolling in these programs. Greater attention should be paid to the enrollment preferences of online students (i.e., their preference for local institutions) and the spending on online programs at local broad access institutions. For non-profit mega-universities and for-profit institutions, the most important questions pertain to type of spending rather than magnitude. If these institutions were able to leverage their scale so that they could invest heavily in the quality of their instruction and services, then the enrollment options of geographically constrained students would be greatly enhanced. Limited evidence currently exists on spending patterns. One recent study was conducted by Cellini and Chaudhary (2020) who found higher spending on advertising at for-profit institutions and institutions with greater than 50% of students taking classes exclusively online.

Endogenous fixed costs create a financing challenge for institutions seeking to create a new online program. An institution must spend heavily during the development and launching of the program, but it does not generate any tuition revenue from the program during these initial periods. To fund this start-up period internally, an institution must either have discretionary resources on hand or take on new debt. A second challenge is that some new online programs are unsuccessful and attract few students, which means the institution will never recoup its initial investment. In response to these and other challenges, nonprofit institutions have been increasingly partnering with for-profit online program managers (OPMs) via tuition share agreements. These agreements provide up-front capital and reduce risk by having the OPM firm cover the initial costs associated with launching an online program and certain ongoing services in return for a share of future tuition revenues. From the perspective of Sutton’s model, OPM tuition share-based partnerships transform initial fixed costs into future variable costs and make it easier for an institution to enter the market. Consequently, OPM agreements could potentially decrease the level of concentration in the online market.

The future role of OPMs is uncertain, however. OPM-university partnerships based on tuition share agreements raise policy concerns that might lead to future regulation (Carey, 2019; Hall & Dudley, 2019). Research into the financing challenge associated with online programs could inform these policy discussions and our understanding of the forces shaping market structure in online education. Such work could also contribute to the literature on academic capitalism (Slaughter & Leslie, 1997; Slaughter & Rhoades, 2004), because the use of OPM firms is an advanced form of outsourcing that relates to core activities such as instruction and advising. The embedding of for-profit firms within nonprofit higher education institutions blurs the distinction between nonprofit and for-profit institutions.

Conclusion

Our discussion section noted a number of areas for further research relating specifically to endogenous fixed costs, and in this conclusion section, we discuss future research opportunities more broadly. Any discussion of the future must incorporate considerations pertaining to the COVID-19 pandemic, because the widespread use of remote education during the pandemic will likely influence student demand for online education as well as the capacity and desire of higher education institutions to produce online education.

The limited information that exists suggests that student interest in online education grew during the COVID-19 pandemic. Blumenstyk (2021) reported data from the National Student Clearinghouse Research Center indicating that national undergraduate enrollment fell by 4.4% from fall 2019 to fall 2020 while undergraduate enrollments at predominately online institutions increased by 5%. Similar differences occur when the comparisons are made for graduate students (+ 3% versus + 10%) and for transfer student (− 8% versus + 4%). Blumenstyk (2021) also noted that enrollments grew rapidly at mega-universities, such as Arizona State (+ 20%), Southern New Hampshire (+ 18%), and Western Governors University (+ 7%). This short-term growth in online enrollments likely reflects the low appeal of in-person programs that contain limited and distanced in-person interactions. The long-term post-pandemic impact on student demand will be harder to gauge, because student experiences with remote education could increase or decrease their future interest in online education.Footnote 25 Increased exposure to internet-based learning may make online education more attractive to students, but negative experiences with hastily developed remote learning experiences may produce the opposite effect.

On the supply side, the widespread adoption of remote instruction and student services likely increased the capacity of many institutions to offer fully online programs. The expansion of this capacity could shape the future market structure of online education. If the infrastructure that many institutions developed while providing remote education can be used to increase the number and quality of their online programs in the future, then the pandemic may lead to a narrowing gap between leading national online providers and other institutions. The degree to which institutions can leverage their remote education infrastructure is uncertain, however, because much of that infrastructure was oriented around synchronous instruction and traditionally aged students rather than asynchronous instruction and adult students.

The pandemic may increase higher education institutions’ interest in online education, because the pandemic’s financial challenges may heighten the need to identify new sources of revenue. Recent evidence suggests that interest in online programs continued to grow during the pandemic. HolonIQ (2021) reported that institutions formed 180 new partnerships with OPM firms in 2020, which is an increase over the previous high of 154 new partnerships in 2019. The rising use of OPM firms may reflect another aspect of the pandemic’s financial impact: institutions may find it increasingly difficult to cover start-up costs using internal funds.

As further data emerges, researchers can examine how the COVID-19 pandemic impacted market structure in online education. When examining market structure, future work can extend beyond this study to further explore how online enrollment levels relates to the mission, approach, reputation, and other characteristics of higher education institutions. To keep the scope of this study manageable, we only differentiated institutions by institutional control and level. Further differentiation would likely produce additional insight.

Research into differences in online market entry by institutional reputation might be especially important for understanding the future market structure of online education. Institutions with strong existing brands from in-person education have historically shunned online education, but they have shown an increased interest in online education in recent years (McKenzie, 2018). Such schools could potentially leverage their reputations and other resources to gain meaningful levels of market share but may be hesitant to enter the market in a substantive way, as the business model that produced their strong reputation was often based on a scarcity of enrollment slots (Hoxby, 2014). They may choose to enter the market only in targeted fields, a possibility that researchers could study because the IPEDS Completion survey component identifies whether each degree, as measured by the 6-digit Classification of Instructional Programs (CIP) code and award level, is offered as a distance education program. If elite institutions enter the online market in a meaningful way and establish new streams of net revenue, it will further increase the extreme financial inequality that exists across U.S. colleges and universities (Cheslock & Shamekhi, 2020; Clotfelter, 2017; Taylor & Cantwell, 2019).

The pricing decisions of online programs is another topic worthy of further study. The largest online nonprofit providers of online education have leveraged economies of scale in order to keep their tuition prices low. Southern New Hampshire University (SNHU) has frozen its online tuition since 2012, and Western Governors University charges a low flat rate for six-month terms that does not vary by the number of courses taken.

The limited research that has been conducted on online pricing suggests that these mega-universities are atypical and that nonprofit institutions generally charge similar or higher prices for online than for in-person education once fees are included (Poulin & Strout, 2017). For institutions with small online enrollments, this pricing may simply reflect the substantial per-student costs associated with producing online education at a small scale. For institutions with moderate online enrollments, the pricing could be driven by expenditure pressures relating to Sutton’s model, because these schools may have spent heavily to attract and retain the students they were able to enroll. Alternatively, the pricing could reflect a desire by institutions to generate large levels of net revenue from online programs. In this latter scenario, online prices (and the institutional net revenue associated with higher prices) might fall over time if competition for online students intensifies. Longitudinal research that examines how online prices relates to competition, scale, organizational characteristics, and other factors could provide helpful insights into the financial impact of online programs on higher education institutions and the nature of the online enrollment choices available to students. If online enrollments continue to grow as expected, the importance of work in this and other areas pertaining to online education will only increase in importance.