Skip to main content
Log in

Equity premium puzzle or faulty economic modelling?

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we revisit the equity premium puzzle reported in 1985 by Mehra and Prescott. We show that the large equity premium that they report can be explained by choosing a more appropriate distribution for the return data. We demonstrate that the high-risk aversion value observed by Mehra and Prescott may be attributable to the problem of fitting a proper distribution to the historical returns and partly caused by poorly fitting the tail of the return distribution. We describe a new distribution that better fits the return distribution and when used to describe historical returns can explain the large equity risk premium and thereby explains the puzzle.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Two empirical studies more than 35 years apart—Friend and Blume (1975) and Chiappori and Paiella (2011)—find support for the constancy of CRRA over time. In contrast, using a GARCH-M model, Das and Sarkar (2010) find strong empirical evidence that CRRA varies over time. Following are estimates for the CRRA that have been reported by researchers: (1) Friend and Blume (1975), greater than 2, (2) French et al. (1987), 2.41, (3) Pindyck (1988), range from 1.57 to 5.32, (4) Azar (2006), 4.5, and (5) Todter (2008), 1.4 to 7.2.

  2. X is log-normally distributed, denote \(X \sim logN\left( \mu ,\sigma ^2\right) \), if logX is normally distributed, \( logX \sim N \left( \mu ,\sigma ^2 \right) \), with mean \(\mu \) and variance \(\sigma ^2\).

  3. The values were estimated using the R-Package GeneralizedHyperbolic. See Scott (2015).

  4. For a further discussion of the use of NCIG distribution and double subordinator models, see Shirvani et al. (2019).

  5. A Lévy subordinator is a Lévy process with increasing sample path (see Sato 2002).

  6. The proof is provided in “Appendix”.

  7. Many papers rely upon the generalized method of moment to estimate risk aversion (Horvath et al. 2020; Kocherlakota and Pistaferri 2009). However, Toda and Walsh (2015, 2017) demonstrated that this procedure is not valid for disaggregated data.

  8. See Yu (2003).

  9. See Chapter 6 of Sato (2002).

References

  • Azar S (2006) Measuring relative risk aversion. Appl Financ Econ Lett 2:341–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barberis N, Huang M (2006) The loss aversion/narrow framing approach to the equity premium puzzle. Technical report. National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Barillas F, Hansen LP, Sargent TJ (2009) Doubts or variability? J Econ Theory 144(6):2388–2418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barndorff-Nielsen O (1977) Normal inverse Gaussian distributions and stochastic volatility modeling. Scand J Stat 24:1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benartzi S, Thaler R (1995) The equity premium: a puzzle. Q J Econ 110:73–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell JY, Cochrane JH (1999) By force of habit: a consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior. J Polit Econ 107(2):205–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Z, Epstein L (2002) Ambiguity, risk, and asset returns in continuous time. Econometrica 70(4):1403–1443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chhikara R, Folks L (2003) The inverse Gaussian distribution: theory. methodology and applications. Marcel Dekker, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA, Paiella M (2011) Relative risk aversion is constant: evidence from panel data. J Eur Econ Assoc 9:1021–1052

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Constantinides GM (1990) Habit formation: a resolution of the equity premium puzzle. J Polit Econ 98(3):519–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cover JP, Zhuang B (2016) Life with habit and expectation: a new explanation of the equity premium puzzle. Available at SSRN 2765089

  • Das S, Sarkar N (2010) Is the relative risk aversion parameter constant over time? A multi-country study. Empir Econ 38:605–617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diebold F, Gunther T, Tay A (1998) Evaluating density forecasts, with applications to financial risk management. Int Econ Rev 39:863–883

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • French KR, Schwert GW, Stambaugh RF (1987) Expected stock returns and volatility. J Financ Econ 19:3–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friend I, Blume ME (1975) The demand for risky assets. Am Econ Rev 65:900–922

    Google Scholar 

  • Giannikos C, Koimisis G (2020) Habits, wealth and equity risk premium. Finance Res Lett. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horvath R, Kaszab L, Marsal A (2020) Equity premium and monetary policy in a model with limited asset market participation. Econ Model. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2020.03.010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ju N, Miao J (2012) Ambiguity, learning, and asset returns. Econometrica 80(2):559–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kocherlakota N (1996) The equity premium: it is still a puzzle. J Econ Lit 40:42–711

    Google Scholar 

  • Kocherlakota N, Pistaferri L (2009) Asset pricing implications of Pareto optimality with private information. J Polit Econ 117(3):555–590

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundtofte F, Wilhelmsson A (2013) Risk premia: exact solutions vs. log-linear approximations. J Bank Finance 37:4256–4264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehra R, Prescott E (1985) The equity premium: a puzzle. J Monet Econ 15:145–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehra R, Prescott E (2003) The equity premium in retrospect. In: Constantinides GM, Harris M, Stulz RM (eds) Handbook of the economics of finance, chapter 14. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Nada S (2013) Equity premium puzzle: not solved yet. In: Proceedings of the 2013 international conference on economics and business administration, pp 48–61

  • Otrok C, Ravikumar B, Whiteman CH (2002) Habit formation: a resolution of the equity premium puzzle? J Monet Econ 49(6):1261–1288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck RS (1988) Risk aversion and determinants of stock market behavior. Rev Econ Stat 70:183–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rietz T (1998) The equity risk premium: a solution. J Monet Econ 22:117–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruan X, Zhang JE (2020) Ambiguity on uncertainty and the equity premium. Finance Res Lett. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sato K (2002) Levy processes and infinitely divisible distributions. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott D (2015) Package ‘GeneralizedHyperbolic’. R Package Documentation

  • Shirvani A, Rachev S, Fabozzi F (2019) Multiple subordinated modeling of asset returns. arXiv:1907.12600

  • Toda AA, Walsh K (2015) The double power law in consumption and implications for testing Euler equations. J Polit Econ 123(5):1177–1200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toda AA, Walsh KJ (2017) Fat tails and spurious estimation of consumption-based asset pricing models. J Appl Econom 32(6):1156–1177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Todter KH (2008) Estimating the uncertainty of relative risk aversion. Appl Financ Econ Lett 4:25–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Y, Mu C (2019) Can ambiguity about rare disasters explain equity premium puzzle? Econ Lett 183:108555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu J (2003) Empirical characteristic function estimation and its applications. Econom Rev 23:93–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Frank J. Fabozzi.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

In this appendix, we derive the Lévy exponent and MGF of a doubly subordinated IG process.

Corollary: Let T(t) be an IG subordinator with Lévy exponent

$$\begin{aligned} \psi _{T(1)}(u)=-\ln E\left[ \exp \left( iu\,T(1) \right) \right] =\,-\frac{\lambda _T}{\mu _{T}}\left( 1-\sqrt{1-\frac{2\mu _{T}^2 \,iu}{\lambda _T}} \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(21)

and U(t), independent of T(t), be an IG process with Laplace exponent given

$$\begin{aligned} \phi _{U(1)}(s)=-\ln E\left[ \exp \left( -s\,U(1) \right) \right] =\,-\frac{\lambda _U}{\mu _{U}}\left( 1-\sqrt{1+\frac{2\mu _{U}^2 \,s}{\lambda _U}} \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(22)

then \(V(1)=T\left( U(1) \right) \) is a subordinator with Lévy exponent given

$$\begin{aligned} \psi _{V(1)}(u)=\phi _{U(1)}\left( \psi _{T}(u) \right) =-\frac{\lambda _U}{\mu _{U}} \left( 1-\sqrt{1-2\,\frac{\mu _{U}^2\,\lambda _T}{\lambda _U\,\mu _{T}} \left( 1-\sqrt{1-\frac{2\mu _{T}^2}{\lambda _T}iu}\right) }\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(23)

and the MGF given

$$\begin{aligned} M_{V(1)}(v)=\,\exp \left( \frac{\lambda _U}{\mu _{U}} \left( 1-\sqrt{1-2\,\frac{\mu _{U}^2\,\lambda _T}{\lambda _U\,\mu _{T}} \left( 1-\sqrt{1-\frac{2\mu _{T}^2}{\lambda _T}v}\right) }\right) \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(24)

where \(v\in \,\left( 0,\frac{\lambda _T}{2\mu _{T}^2}\left[ 1-\left( \frac{\lambda _T\,\mu _{T}}{2\mu _{U}^2\,\lambda _U}\right) ^2 \right] \right) \).

Proof

If T(t) is a Lévy subordinator with Lévy exponent, \(\psi _{T}(u)\,=\,-\ln \,E\left[ \exp \left( iu\,T(1) \right) \right] \) \(u\in {\mathbb {R}}\), and U(t), independent of T(t), is a Lévy subordinator with Laplace exponent \(\phi _{U}(s)\,=\,-\ln E\left[ \exp \left( -s\,U(1)\right) \right] \), \(s>0\), then the subordinator process \(Y(t)=T\left( U(t) \right) \) is again a Lévy subordinator with Lévy exponent and probability transition givenFootnote 9

$$\begin{aligned} \psi _{Y}(u)= & \, \phi _{T}\left( \psi _{U}(u)\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned} P_{Y}(t,A)= & \, \int _{0}^{\infty } P_{T}(t,A)\,P_{U}(u,dt), \end{aligned}$$
(26)

respectively. Using (25), and substituting (21) in (22), the Lévy exponent and consequently the MGF are obtained.\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Shirvani, A., Stoyanov, S.V., Fabozzi, F.J. et al. Equity premium puzzle or faulty economic modelling?. Rev Quant Finan Acc 56, 1329–1342 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-020-00928-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-020-00928-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation