Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Consumption-based capital asset pricing models: issues and controversies

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper discusses the issues and controversies surrounding consumption-based capital asset pricing models (CCAPMs). While CCAPMs provide a chance to explain the phenomena observed in stock markets, their viability is jeopardized owing to the weak predictability of the equity premium and risk-free rate puzzles. Even given market frictions and market incompleteness, CCAPMs must test their validity constantly in the face of the formidable challenges of rival models. Measurement error with respect to time aggregation is also regarded as a major threat, causing the low volatility of consumption and eventually resulting in chaining itself to weak return predictability. In addition, the dual choice problem of portfolio and consumption rooted in CCAPMs guides us into how investors accumulate wealth through the financial market to reach the zenith of expected utility. This paper offers insights as well as understanding into the behavior of an agent and market phenomena in the context of a consumption-based economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also Rubinstein (1976) and Grossman and Shiller (1982).

  2. Heaton (1993) shows that measurement error leads to wrong inferences.

  3. See “Appendix” for information about the data source.

  4. See Eq. (8.3.7) in Chapter 8 of Campbell, Lo, and Mackinlay (1997) (CLM hereafter).

  5. Hung (1994) employs a bivariate Markov switching process, characterizing consumption and dividends as asymmetric market fundamentals.

  6. Although Bansal and Yaron (2004) exploit EZ’s utility, their results are fundamentally dependent on the processes underlying returns, consumption growth, and a persistent predictable component that determines the conditional expectation of consumption growth.

  7. Some argue that expected returns should not be as large as historical returns. For instance, the expected aggregate equity premium based on analysts’ earnings forecast was a little above 3.1% in 1985–1998 (Claus and Thomas 2001), while the one-year forecast of the conditional equity premium was 3.5% in 2001 (Welch 2001). These numbers are low compared with the historical equity premium.

  8. In an intertemporal context, the risk-free rate is considered to be an annuity that provides a constant real return over a long period.

  9. Campbell (2001) provides evidence that IES is even smaller.

  10. Equation (8.3.6) in Chapter 8 of CLM.

  11. Siegel (2002) shows a risk premium similar to that of the U.S. stock market for Germany and Japan since 1926.

  12. Equation (8.4.11) in Chapter 8 of CLM.

  13. See Siegel (1998).

  14. Equation (8.4.19) in Chapter 8 of CLM.

  15. Bansal and Yaron (2004) also report a similar risk aversion coefficient.

  16. Durable goods serve as collateral for credit purchases. Therefore, they can be financed, and durable equity loans are available to consumers. Therefore, the market for durable goods, which is constrained by collateral in reality, distorts the consumption allocation across goods and over time. These features supposedly induce different responses of consumption to stock market movement.

  17. By contrast, Dun and Singleton (1986), Eichenbaum and Hansen (1990), and Heaton (1993, 1995) show that durable goods do not help explain the equity premium.

  18. In addition, basic and luxury goods are used by Watcher and Yogo (2004) and food by Mankiw and Zeldes (1991).

  19. Since 1989, the Survey of Consumer Finance has interviewed a fresh sample of households every three years. Hence, household investment has not been tracked.

  20. Brown and Gibbons (1985) assert that temporal aggregation bias is avoided if we access instantaneous consumption sampled at discrete intervals. See footnote 2 in their paper.

  21. Generally, CCAPMs are not obtained if liquidity-constrained income alters the covariance of aggregate consumption growth with asset returns. Instead, an ICAPM is obtained (Brown 1988).

  22. As an economic constraint, Chapman (1998) imposes the restriction on utility to preclude the negative marginal utility in some dates and states of the world.

References

  • Abel A (1990) Asset prices under habit formation and catching up with the Joneses. Am Econ Rev 80:38–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Abel A (1999) Risk premia and term premia in general equilibrium. J Monet Econ 43:3–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ait-Sahalia Y, Jonathan P, Yogo M (2004) Luxuary goods and the equity premium. J Finance 59:2959–3004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aiyagari R, Gertler M (1991) Asset returns with transaction costs and uninsured individual risk. J Monet Econ 27:311–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakshi G, Chen Z (1996) The spirit of capitalism and stock-market prices. Am Econ Rev 86:133–157

    Google Scholar 

  • Bansal R, Yaron A (2004) Risks for the long run: a potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles. J Finance 49:1481–1509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (2006) Rare disasters and asset markets in the twentieth century. Q J Econ 121:823–826

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (2009) Rare disasters, asset prices, and welfare cost. Am Econ Rev 99:243–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brav A, Constantinides G, Geczy C (2002) Asset pricing with heterogeneous consumers and limited participation: empirical evidence. J Polit Econ 110:793–824

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breeden D (1979) An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumption and investment opportunities. J Finance Econ 7:265–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breeden D, Gibbons M, Lintzenberger R (1989) Empirical tests of the consumption-oriented CAPM. J Finance 44:231–262

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown S, Goetzmann W, Ross S (1995) Survival. J Finance 50:853–873

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burnside C (1994) Hansen and Jagannathan bounds as classical tests of asset pricing models. J Bus Econ Stat 12:57–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell J (2006) Household finance. J Finance 61:1553–1604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell J, Cochrane J (2000) Explaining the poor performance of consumption-based asset pricing models. J Finance 55:2863–2878

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell J, Lo A, Mackinlay C (1997) The econometric of financial market. Princeton University Press, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Ceccetti S, Lam P, Mark N (1994) Testing utility restrictions on intertemporal marginal rates of substitution implied by Euler equation and asset returns. J Finance 49:123–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chabi-Yo F (2008) Conditional information and variance bonds on pricing kernels with higher-order moments: theory and evidence. Rev Finance Stud 21:181–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cocco J (2004) Portfolio choice in the presence of housing. Rev Finance Stud 18:536–567

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane J (1996) A cross-sectional test of an investment-based asset pricing model. J Polit Econ 104:572–621

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane J (1997) Where is the market going? uncertain and novel theories. Econ Perspect 21:3–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane J (2001) Asset pricing. Princeton University Press, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Constantinides G (1990) Habit formation: a resolution of the equity premium puzzle. J Polit Econ 98:519–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dimson E, Marsh P, Staunton M (2002) Triumph of the optimists: 101 years of global investment returns. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dimson E, Marsh P, Staunton M (2004) Irrational optimism. Finance Anal J60:15–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dimson E, Marsh P, Staunton M (2008) The worldwide equity premium: a smaller puzzle In: Mehra R (ed) Handbook of the equity risk premium. Chap 11, Elsevier

  • Duffie G (2005) Time variation in the covariance between stock returns and consumption growth. J Finance 60:1673–1712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dun K, Singleton K (1986) Modeling the term structure of interest rates under non-separable utility and durability of goods. J Finance Econ 12:27–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichenbaum M, Hansen LP (1990) Estimating models with intertemporal substitution using aggregate time series data. J Bus Econ Stat 8:53–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein L, Zin S (1989) Substitution, risk premium, and the temporal behavior of consumption growth and asset returns: atheoretical framework. Econometrica 57:937–968

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein L, Zin S (1991) Substitution, risk premium, and the temporal behavior of consumption growth and asset returns: an empirical analysis. J Polit Econ 99:263–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama E, Kenneth F (2002) The equity premium. J Finance 57:637–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferson W, Constantinides G (1991) Habit persistence and durability in aggregate consumption: empirical test. J Finance Econ 29:199–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix X (2008) Variable rare disasters: a tractable theory of ten puzzles in macro-finance. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 98:64–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman S, Laroque G (1990) Asset pricing and optimal portfolio choice in the presence of illiquid durable consumption goods. Econometrica 58:25–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall R (1988) Intertemporal substitution in consumption. J Polit Econ 96:221–273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen LP, Jagannathan R (1991) Testing volatility restrictions on intertemporal marginal rate of substitution implied by Euler equations and asset returns. J Polit Econ 49:225–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen LP, Singleton K (1982) Generalized instrumental variables estimation of nonlinear rational expectations models. Econometrica 50:1269–1286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen LP, Singleton K (1983) Stochastic consumption, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of asset returns. J Polit Econ 91:249–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen LP, Heaton J, Li N (2008) Consumption strikes back: long-run risk. J Polit Econ 116:260–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He H, Modest D (1995) Market frictions and consumption-based asset pricing. J Polit Econ 95:94–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heaton J (1993) The interaction between time-nonseparable preferences and time aggregation. Econometrica 61:353–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heaton J (1995) An empirical investigation of asset pricing with time nonseparable preferences. Econometrica 63:681–717

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heaton J, Lucas D (1999) Stock prices and fundamentals. In: Bernanke B, Rotemberg J (eds) Macroeconomics annual 1999. National Bureau of Economic Research, MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Heaton J, Lucas D (2000) Portfolio choice and asset prices: the importance of entrepreneurial risk. J Finance 55:1163–1198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hindy A, Huang C, Zhu S (1997) Optimal consumption and portfolio rules with durability and habit formation. J Econ Dyn Control 21:325–550

    Google Scholar 

  • Hung M (1994) The interaction between nonexpected utility and asymmetric market fundamentals. J Finance 49:325–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jagannathan R, Wang Z (1996) Conditional CAPM and cross-section of expected returns. J Finance 51:3–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jagannathan R, McGrattan E, Scherbina A (2000) The declining U.S. equity premium. Fed Reserv Bank Minneap Q Rev 24:3–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorion P, Goetzmann W (1999) Global stock markets in twentieth century. J Finance 54:953–980

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • José M, Prado L (2006) Durables, nondurables, down payments and consumption excesses. J Monet Econ 53:1509–1539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kan R, Zhou G (1999) A critique of stochastic discount factor methodology. J Finance 54:1221–1248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kocherlakota N (1996) The equity premium puzzle: it’s still a puzzle. J Econ Lit 34:42–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Koo H (1998) Consumption and portfolio section with labor income: a continuous-time approach. Math Finance 8:49–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koo H (1999) Consumption and portfolio section with labor income: a discrete-time approach. Math Methods Oper Res 50:219–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korniotis G (2008) Habit formation, incomplete markets, and the significance of regional risk for expected returns. Rev Finance Stud 21:2139–2172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lettau M, Ludvigson S (2009) Euler equation errors. Rev Econ Dyn 12:255–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luttmer GJ (1996) Asset pricing in economies with frictions. Econometrica 34:1439–1467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malloy C, Moskowitz T, Vission-Jorgensen A (2009) Long-run stockholder consumption risk and asset return. J Finance 94:2427–2479

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw G, Zeldes S (1991) The consumption of stockholders and nonstockholders. J Finance Econ 29:97–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall D, Parekh N (1999) Can costs of consumption adjustment explain asset pricing puzzles? J Finance 54:623–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehra R, Prescott E (1985) The equity premium: a puzzle. J Monet Econ 15:146–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehra R, Prescott E (2003) The equity premium in retrospect. In: Constantinides GM, Harris M, Stulz R (eds) Handbook of the economics of finance, vol 14. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Munk C (2008) Portfolio and consumption choice with stochastic investment opportunities and habit formation in preference. J Econ Dyn Control 32:3560–3589

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Otrok C, Ravikumar B, Whiteman C (2002) Habit formation: a resolution of the equity premium puzzle? J Monet Econ 49:1261–1288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker J (2003) Consumption risk and expected stock returns. Am Econ Rev 93:376–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker J, Julliard C (2005) Consumption risk and the cross section of expected return. J Polit Econ 113:185–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piazzesi M, Schneider M, Tuzel S (2007) Housing, consumption and asset pricing. J Finance Econ 83:531–569

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rietz T (1988) The equity risk premium: a solution? J Monet Econ 21:117–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santos T, Veronesi P (2006) Labor income and asset returns. Rev Finance Stud 19:1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seminov A (2016) Background risk in consumption and the equity risk premium. Rev Quant Finance Account 48:407–439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel J (1992) The real rate of interest from 1800–1990: a study of the U.S. and the U.K. J Monet Econ 29:227–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel J (1999) The shrinking equity premium. J Portf Manag 26:10–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snow K (1991) Diagnosing asset pricing models using the distribution of asset returns. J Finance 46:955–983

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tallarini T, Zhang H (2005) External habit and the cyclicality of expected stock returns. J Bus 78:1023–1048

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsai H, Wu Y (2015) Optimal portfolio with asset return predictability and nontradable labor income. Rev. Quant Finance Account 45:215–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viceira L (2001) Optimal portfolio choice for long-horizon investors with nontradable labor income. J Finance 56:433–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wachter J, Yogo M (2010) Why do household portfolio shares rise in wealth? Rev Finance Stud 23:3929–3965

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weil P (1989) The equity premium puzzle and the riskfree rate puzzle. J Monet Econ 24:401–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Welch I (2001) The equity premium consensus forecast revisited, Yale University ICF, Lowles Foundation Discussion paper No.1325

  • Wilcox D (1992) The construction of U.S. consumption data: some facts and their implication for empirical work. Am Econ Rev 82:922–941

    Google Scholar 

  • Yao R, Zhang H (2005) Optimal consumption and portfolio choices with risky housing and borrowing constraints. Rev Finance Stud 18:198–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yogo M (2006) A consumption-based explanation of expected stock returns. J Finance 61:539–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wonnho Choi.

Additional information

This paper is the updated and extended version of one part of my Ph.D. thesis, “A Review of Consumption-based Capital Asset Pricing Model”

Appendix: Data source

Appendix: Data source

Personal income and population data come from lines 1 and 39 from NIPA Table 2.1. personal income and its disposition in Sect. 2 personal income and outlays. Durables, nondurables and services data come from lines 3, 25 and 47 from NIPA Table 2.4.5. Personal consumption expenditures by type of product in Sect. 2 personal income and outlays. Both obtain from Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis for the period 1929–2009. Inflation in the rate of change in consumer price index for all urban consumers, not seasonally adjusted (CPI-U NSA) from the US Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics for the same period. The current standard reference base period is 1982–1984 = 100. That is, all price changes are measured from a base (100) that represents the average index level of the 36-month period encompassing 1982, 1983, and 1984. Value-weighted (including NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ) index returns excluding dividends and the three month Treasury Bill rate come from CRSP data files and CRSP’s Fama Risk Free Rates File for the period 1929–2009, respectively. NBER recessions comes from the website of NBER, http://www.nber.org/cycles/recessions.html.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Choi, W. Consumption-based capital asset pricing models: issues and controversies. Rev Quant Finan Acc 50, 181–205 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-017-0627-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-017-0627-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation