Skip to main content

Experience, information asymmetry, and rational forecast bias

Abstract

This study examines whether it is ever rational for analysts to post biased estimates and how information asymmetry and analyst experience factor into the decision. Using a construct where analysts wish to minimize their forecasting error, we model forecasted earnings when analysts combine private information with consensus estimates to determine the optimal forecast bias, i.e., the deviation from the consensus. We show that the analyst’s rational bias increases with information asymmetry, but is concavely related with experience. Novice analysts post estimates similar to the consensus but as they become more experienced and develop private information channels, their estimates become biased and deviated from the consensus. Highly seasoned analysts, who have superior analytical skills and valuable relationships, need not post biased forecasts.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Notes

  1. Beyer (2008) argues that, even without incentives to appease management, analysts may still post forecasts that exceed median earnings because managers can manipulate earnings upward to prevent falling short of earnings forecasts. Moreover, Conrad et al. (2006) find support for the idea that analysts’ “… recommendation changes are “sticky” in one direction, with analysts reluctant to downgrade.” Evidence also indicates that analysts rarely post sell recommendations for a stock, suggesting that losing a firm’s favor can be viewed as a costly proposition. At the extreme, firms even pursue legal damages for an analyst’s unfavorable recommendations. In a 2001 congressional hearing, president and chief executive officer of the Association for Investment Management and Research told the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Financial Services, Capital Markets Subcommittee, that “…In addition to pressures within their firms, analysts can also be, and have been, pressured by the executives of corporate issuers to issue favorable reports and recommendations. Regulation Fair Disclosure notwithstanding, recent history…has shown that companies retaliate against analysts who issue 'negative' recommendations by denying them direct access to company executives and to company-sponsored events that are important research tools. Companies have also sued analysts personally, and their firms, for negative coverage…” (Association for Investment Management and Research 2001).

  2. See also Han et al. (2001) and Ho and Tsay (2004).

  3. Clement and Tse (2005) are the closest to our analysis, however while they admit that the observed link between inexperience and herding can be a complex issue that might have other roots than just career concerns, they do not provide detailed insight as to what and how this complexity develops.

  4. Here, we focus only on the case of one-period sequential forecasting. However, we believe that the main implications of our model hold true for a multi-period sequential forecasting setting. Since we assume that the probabilistic characteristics of different components are known and analysts can gauge each others’ experience and the amount of information asymmetry perfectly, there would be no incentive to deviate from posting commensurate optimal, rational forecasts. If expert analysts intentionally deviate from their optimal forcasts, no other analyst can compete for their experience or information asymmetry (for more discussion see Trueman 1990).

  5. Horizon value and the number of revisions are highly correlated at 65%. We therefore orthogonalize horizon value in the equation to ensure that multicollinearity is not a problem between these two variables.

  6. http://www.sec.gov/rules/final/33-7881.htm.

  7. See Lin and Yang 2010 for a study of how Reg. FD affects analyst forecasts of restructuring firms.

  8. Brokerage reputation and brokerage size are highly correlated at 67%. We therefore orthogonalize brokerage reputation in the equation to ensure that multicollinearity is not a problem between these two variables.

  9. Following Stangeland and Zheng (2007), we measure accruals as income before extraordinary items (Data #237) minus cash flow from operations, where cash flow from operations is defined as net cash flow from operating activities (Data #308) minus extraordinary items and discontinued operations (Data #124).

  10. Following Hirschey and Richardson (2004), we calculate intangibles as intangible assets to total assets (Data 33/Data #6).

  11. As an alternate proxy for industry fixed effects, Fama–French 12 industry classifications (Fama and French 1997) are used. Results using these proxies are available upon request.

  12. As a robustness test, we use I/B/E/S data. Results may be found in “Appendix B”.

  13. Inasmuch as the experience variable is transformed using the natural logarithm; one unit of experience is approximately equal to two quarters of experience. For tractability, we refer to this as a unit in the empirical results.

  14. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for this point.

References

  • Association for Investment Management and Research (2001) Research objectivity standards will create competitive market pressure for brokerage firms to support analyst objectivity. http://www.cfainstitute.org/pressroom/01releases/01congress.html

  • Baily W, Li H, Mao C, Zhong R (2003) Regulation fair disclosure and earnings information: market, analysts, and corporate response. J Finan 58:2487–2514

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bannister J, Newman H (1996) Accrual usage to manage earnings toward financial analysts’ forecasts. Rev Quant Finan Acc 7:259–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barber B, Lehavy R, Trueman B (2000) Are all brokerage houses created equal? Testing for systematic differences in the performance of brokerage house stock recommendations. University of California at Davis and University of California at Berkeley (unpublished), March

  • Bernhardt D, Campello M, Kutsoati E (2006) Who herds? J Finan Econ 80:657–675

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beyer A (2008) Financial analysts’ forecast revisions and managers’ reporting behavior. J Acc Econ 46:334–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya N (2001) Investors’ trade size and trading responses around earnings announcements: an empirical investigation. Acc Rev 76:221–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boni L, Womack K (2006) Analysts, industries, and price momentum. J Finan Quant Anal 41:85–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown L, Sivakumar K (2003) Comparing the quality of two operating income measures. Rev Acc Stud 4:561–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown S, Hillegeist S, Lo K (2004) Conference calls and information asymmetry. J Acc Econ 37:343–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carey M, Post M, Sharpe S (1998) Does corporate lending by banks and finance companies differ? Evidence on specialization in private debt contracting. J Finan 53:845–878

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter R, Manaster S (1990) Initial public offerings and underwriter reputation. J Finan 45:1045–1068

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter RB, Dark FH, Singh AK (1998) Underwriter reputation, initial returns, and the long-run performance of IPO stocks. J Finan 53:285–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Q, Jiang W (2006) Analysts’ weighting of private and public information. Rev Finan Stud 19:319–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clement M (1999) Analyst forecast accuracy: do ability, resources, and portfolio complexity matter? J Acc Econ 27:285–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clement M, Tse S (2005) Financial analyst characteristics and herding behavior in forecasting. J Finan 60:307–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad J, Cornell B, Landsman W, Roundtree B (2006) How do analyst recommendations respond to major news? J Finan Quant Anal 41:25–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Jong P, Apilado V (2008) The changing relationship between earnings expectations and earnings for value and growth stocks during Reg FD. J Banking Finan 33:435–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechow P, Kothari S, Watts R (1998) The relation between earnings and cash flows. J Acc Econ 25:133–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doyle J, Lundholm R, Soliman M (2003) The predictive value of expenses excluded from pro forma earnings. Rev Acc Stud 8:145–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French K (1997) Industry costs of equity. J Finan Econ 43:153–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Givoly D, Lakonishok J (1979) The information content of financial analysts’ forecasts of earnings. J Acc Econ 2:165–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gu Z, Xue J (2007) Do analysts overreact to extreme good news in earnings? Rev Quant Finan Acc 29:415–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han B, Manry D, Shaw W (2001) Improving the precision of analysts’ earnings forecasts by adjusting for predictable bias. Rev Quant Finan Acc 17:81–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschey M, Richardson V (2004) Are scientific indicators of patent quality useful to investors? J Empir Finan 11:91–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho L, Tsay J (2004) Analysts’ forecasts of Taiwanese firms’ earnings: some empirical evidence. Rev Pac Basin Fin Mar Pol 7:571–597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong H, Kubik J, Solomon A (2000) Security analysts’ career concerns and the herding of earnings forecasts. RAND J Econ 31:f121–f144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsu D, Chiao C-H (2010) Relative accuracy of analysts’ earnings forecasts over time: a Markov chain analysis. Rev Quant Finan Acc (forthcoming)

  • Irani A (2004) The effect of regulation fair disclosure on the relevance of conference calls to financial analysts. Rev Quant Finan Acc 22:15–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishnaswami S, Subramaniam V (1998) Information asymmetry, valuation, and the corporate spin-off decision. J Finan Econ 53:73–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwon S (2002) Financial analysts’ forecast accuracy and dispersion: high-tech versus low-tech stocks. Rev Quant Finan Acc 19:65–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leone A, Wu JS (2002) What does it take to become a superstar? Evidence from institutional investor rankings of financial analysts. Working Paper, University of Rochester

  • Lim T (2001) Rationality and analysts; forecast deviation. J Finan 56:369–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin B, Yang R (2010) Does regulation fair disclosure affect analysts’ forecast performance? The case of restructuring firms. Rev Quant Finan Acc (forthcoming)

  • Loughran T, Ritter J (2004) Why has IPO underpricing changed over time? Finan Manage 33(3):5–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Mest D, Plummer E (2003) Analysts’ rationality and forecast bias: evidence from analysts’ sales forecasts. Rev Quant Finan Acc 21:103–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mikhail M, Walther D, Willis R (1997) Do security analysts improve their performance with experience? J Acc Res 35:131–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nutt S, Easterwood J, Easterwood C (1999) New evidence on serial correlation in analyst forecast errors. Finan Manage 28:106–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen M, Rajan R (1994) The benefits of lending relationships: evidence from small business data. J Finan 49:3–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramnath S (2002) Investor and analyst reactions to earnings announcements of related firms: an empirical Anal. J Acc Res 40:1351–1376

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stangeland D, Zheng S (2007) IPO underpricing, firm quality, and analyst forecasts. Finan Manag 36:1–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Sufi A (2007) Information asymmetry and financing arrangements: evidence from syndicated loans. J Finan 62:629–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas S (2002) Firm diversification and asymmetric information: evidence from analysts’ forecasts and earnings announcements. J Finan Econ 64:373–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trueman B (1990) Theories of earnings-announcement timing. J Acc Econ 13:285–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waymire G (1986) Additional evidence on the accuracy of analyst forecasts before and after voluntary manage earnings forecasts. Acc Rev 61:129–141

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang F (2006) Information uncertainty and stock returns. J Finan 61:105–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou T, Lai R (2009) Herding and information based trading. J Empir Finan 16:388–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zirzewitz E (2002) Regulation fair disclosure and the private information of analysts. working paper, Stanford University

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ali Nejadmalayeri.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proofs

1.1 A. The objective function:

Given that the analyst’s forecast is a weighted average of the analyst’s unconditional estimate and the consensus, F = w E + (1 − w) E c , the objective function can be expressed as:

$$ \mathop {\min }\limits_{w|b} \left[ {w^{2} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{ - 2} + (1 - w)^{2} \tau_{c}^{ - 2} + 2\rho w(1 - w)\left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{ - 1} \tau_{c}^{ - 1} } \right] $$
(6)

The first order condition then is:

$$ 2w\left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{ - 2} - 2(1 - w)\tau_{c}^{ - 2} + 2\rho (1 - w)\left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{ - 1} \tau_{c}^{ - 1} - 2\rho w\left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{ - 1} \tau_{c}^{ - 1} \equiv 0 $$

by collecting terms, we then have:

$$ w\left\{ {\left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{ - 2} + \tau_{c}^{ - 2} - 2\rho \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{ - 1} \tau_{c}^{ - 1} } \right\} = \tau_{c}^{ - 2} - \rho \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{ - 1} \tau_{c}^{ - 1} $$

this means that the optimal weight is:

$$ w = \frac{{\left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{2} - \rho \tau_{c} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)}}{{\left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{2} + \tau_{c}^{2} - 2\rho \tau_{c} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)}} $$
(7)

1.2 B. Proof of proposition 1:

By taking the derivative of Eq. 7 with respect to τ 0, we have:

$$ \frac{\partial w}{{\partial \tau_{0} }} = \frac{{2\tau_{c}^{2} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right) - 2\rho \tau_{c} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{2} - \rho \tau_{c}^{3} }}{{\left[ {\left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{2} + \tau_{c}^{2} - 2\rho \tau_{c} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)} \right]^{2} }} $$
(8)

Clearly, since the denominator of ∂w/τ 0 is positive, then the sign is only a function of the numerator. This implies that the sign changes when the numerator, \( 2\tau_{c}^{{}} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right) - 2\rho \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{2} - \rho \tau_{c}^{2} , \) is at maximum. To find the maximum, we solve for τ 0 that satisfies the first order conditions of the numerator. The first order condition yields\( \tau_{c} - 2\rho \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right) \equiv 0 \). Thus, at optimal weight \( \tau_{0} + \tau (b) = 0.5\rho^{ - 1} \tau_{c} . \)

1.3 C. Proof of proposition 2:

By taking the derivative of Eq. 7 with respect to bias, we have:

$$ \frac{\partial w}{\partial b} = \frac{{\left[ {2\tau_{c}^{2} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right) - 2\rho \tau_{c} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{2} - \rho \tau_{c}^{3} } \right]\frac{\partial \tau }{\partial b}}}{{\left[ {\left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)^{2} + \tau_{c}^{2} - 2\rho \tau_{c} \left( {\tau_{0} + \tau (b)} \right)} \right]^{2} }} $$
(9)

Clearly, since the denominator of ∂w/b is positive, then the sign is only a function of the numerator. This implies (1) that since ∂τ/b is positive, then the optimal weight would be monotonically increasing with ∂τ/b or information asymmetry, and (2) that the optimal weight is nonlinearly, concavely related to private information precision. Since the first term in the numerator is a quadratic function of analyst’s own precision, the maximum in the function is the point at which the numerator changes sign. This point, however, is exactly the same point at which ∂w/τ 0 maximizes. For biases at which \( \tau_{0} + \tau (b) \) falls below \( 0.5\rho^{ - 1} \tau_{c} . \), then so long as bias increases so does the optimal weight.

Appendix B

See Table 6.

Table 6 Alternate samples

Appendix C

See Table 7.

Table 7 Alternate proxies for information asymmetry for Table 5

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Knill, A., Minnick, K. & Nejadmalayeri, A. Experience, information asymmetry, and rational forecast bias. Rev Quant Finan Acc 39, 241–272 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-011-0252-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-011-0252-1

Keywords

JEL Classification