Skip to main content
Log in

The “Italian Football Federation Auction” for Co-ownership Resolution

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper is inspired by the Italian Football Federation (FIGC) Auction. The auction was used by the FIGC from the 1950s until 2015 to resolve a 50% co-ownership between two teams in the same league with respect to the performance rights of a football player. Though FIGC banned such joint ownership in 2015, the resolution process is nevertheless interesting with respect to the received literature. In the FIGC Auction each co-owner submits a price offer for the whole asset. The highest bid wins the auction and obtains the asset, while the loser receives as payment the bid that is offered by the winner. Therefore, whether a bidder is a buyer, or a seller, can be established only after the auction has taken place—rather than before the auction. The main contribution of this paper is to investigate the set of pure strategy Nash Equilibria for two extensions of the FIGC Auction, with complete information. The first extension is the Extended Italian Football Federation Auction (EA), where asset shares can differ from 50%. The other extension is the Second Price Extended Italian Football Federation Auction (SEA), which is based on second price rather than first price. As compared to more standard auctions, though in the EA equilibria no bidder may have negative profits, in some circumstances we find that losing the auction may be more profitable than winning the auction. Finally, in the SEA we show that truthful bidding is not a weakly dominant strategy and that—somewhat surprisingly—the set of Nash Equilibria coincides with that of EA.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Cai, H. (2003). A theory of joint ownership. Rand Journal of Economics, 34, 63–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cramton, P., Gibbons, R., & Klemperer, P. (1987). Dissolving a partnership efficiently. Econometrica, 55, 615–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Frutos, M., & Kittsteiner, T. (2008). Efficient partnership dissolution under buy-sell clauses. Rand Journal of Economics, 39, 184–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ensthaler, L., Giebe, T., & Li, J. (2014). Speculative partnership dissolution with auctions. Review of Economics Design, 18, 127–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galavotti, S., Muto, N., & Oyama, D. (2011). On efficient partnership dissolution under ex-post individual rationality. Economic Theory, 48, 87–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jehiel, P., & Pauzner, A. (2006). Partnership dissolution with interdependent values. Rand Journal of Economics, 1, 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khoroshilov, Y. (2016). Information precision and common value partnership dissolution: An experimental study. Managerial and Decision Economics, 38, 822–831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khoroshilov, Y. (2018). Partnership dissolution: Information and efficiency. Decision Analysis, 15, 133–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kittsteiner, T., Ockenfels, A., & Trhal, N. (2012). Partnership dissolution mechanisms in the laboratory. Economics Letters, 117, 394–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klemperer, P. (2004). Auctions: Theory and practice. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Krishna, V. (2009). Auction theory. Cambridge: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krishna, V., & Morgan, J. (1997). An analysis of the war of attrition and the all-pay auction. Journal of Economic Theory, 72, 343–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, J., & Wolfstetter, E. (2010). Partnership dissolution, complementarity and investment incentives. Oxford Economic Papers, 62, 529–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, J., Xue, Y., & Wu, W. (2012). Partnership dissolution and proprietary information. Social Choice and Welfare, 40, 495–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAfee, R. (1992). Amicable divorce: Dissolving a partnership with simple mechanisms. Journal of Economic Theory, 56, 266–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menezes, F., & Monteiro, P. (2005). An introduction to auction theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. (2004). Putting auctions theory to work. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Moldovanu, B. (2002). How to dissolve a partnership. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 158, 66–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, J. (2004). Dissolving a partnership (un) fairly. Economic Theory, 23, 909–923.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank the Editor and the referees for very constructive comments which much improved the paper, Wim Naudè for discussions on a previous version of the work and Carlotta Capezzuoli for having brought to my attention the Italian Football Federation Auction. Moreover, I would like to thank the Maastricht School of Management for having funded, and hosted in its Working Paper series, an earlier version of the article.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nicola Dimitri.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

Suppose \( v_{1} \ge \rho v_{2} \). From the agents’ payoff functions it follows that agent \( 1's \) best reply is given by

$$ b_{1} \left( {b_{2} } \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} {b_{1} = \rho b_{2} } \hfill & {\quad if\;\;v_{1} > \rho b_{2} } \hfill \\ {b_{1} \in \left[ {0,\rho b_{2} } \right] } \hfill & {\quad if\;\;v_{1} = \rho b_{2} } \hfill \\ {b_{1} \in \left[ {0,\rho b_{2} } \right)} \hfill & {\quad if\;\;v_{1} < \rho b_{2} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.; $$

while for agent \( 2 \).

$$ b_{2} \left( {b_{1} } \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} {b_{2} = \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho } + \varepsilon } \hfill & {\quad if\;\;v_{2} > \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \hfill \\ {b_{2} \in \left[ {0,\frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \right] } \hfill & {\quad if\;\;v_{2} = \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \hfill \\ {b_{2} \in \left[ {0,\frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \right] } \hfill & {\quad if\;\;v_{2} < \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right., $$

with \( \varepsilon > 0 \) very small and such that \( \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho } + \varepsilon < v_{2} \). Then it follows immediately that \( \left( {b_{1} = \rho b;b_{2} = b} \right) \) with \( v_{2} \le b \le \frac{{v_{1} }}{\rho } \) are the price pairs where the two best replies meet: hence the set of pure strategy Nash Equilibria.□

Analogous reasoning holds for \( v_{1} < \rho v_{2} \): where the two best replies meet at the following price pairs—\( \left( {b_{1} = \rho b - \varepsilon ;\;b_{2} = b} \right) \) with \( \frac{{v_{1} }}{\rho } < b \le v_{2} \)—which then define the set of pure strategy Nash Equilibria, and the result is proved.

Proof of Proposition 2

Start by considering agent 2 and suppose \( F_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) \) and \( f_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) \) are agent 1’s mixed Nash Equilibrium distribution and probability density functions over the support \( \left[ {\underline{v} ,\bar{v}} \right] \), with \( \bar{v} > \underline{v} \). We assume \( F_{1}^{'} \left( {b_{1} } \right) = f_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) > 0 \) everywhere on \( \left[ {\underline{v} ,\bar{v}} \right] \). Moreover, define

$$ E_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) = \mathop \smallint \limits_{{\underline{v} }}^{{\bar{v}}} b_{1} dF_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right). $$

Then agent 2’s expected payoff is given by

$$ E\varPi_{2} \left( {b_{2} } \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {E_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) - v_{2} } \hfill & {\quad if\;\;b_{2} \le \underline{v} } \hfill \\ { \mathop \smallint \limits_{{\underline{v} }}^{{b_{2} }} \left( {v_{2} - b_{2} } \right)dF_{1} \left( x \right) + \mathop \smallint \limits_{{b_{2} }}^{{\bar{v}}} \left( {x - v_{2} } \right)dF_{1} \left( x \right)} \hfill & {\quad if\;\;\underline{v} < b_{2} \le \bar{v}} \hfill \\ {v_{2} - b_{2} } \hfill & {\quad if\;\;b_{2} > \bar{v} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.. $$
  1. (i)

    Suppose first \( \underline{v} \ge v_{2} \). Hence for \( b_{2} \le \underline{v} \) agent \( 2 \) would lose the auction and obtain a constant, positive payoff \( E_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) - v_{2} > 0 \). If \( \underline{v} < b_{2} \le \bar{v} \), then differentiating \( E\varPi_{2} \left( {b_{2} } \right) \) over the interval \( \underline{v} < b_{2} \le \bar{v} \) yields

    $$ \frac{{dE\varPi_{2} \left( {b_{2} } \right)}}{{db_{2} }} = - [F_{1} \left( {b_{2} } \right) - F_{1} \left( {\underline{v} } \right)] + 2\left( {v_{2} - b_{2} } \right)f_{1} \left( {b_{2} } \right), $$

    which, because \( f_{1} \left( {b_{2} } \right) > 0 \) over the interval \( \left[ {\underline{v} ,\bar{v}} \right] \), is always negative for \( b_{2} > v_{2} \). But since \( \mathop {\lim }\limits_{{b_{2} \to \underline{v} }} (\int_{{\underline{v} }}^{{b_{2} }} {\left( {v_{2} - b_{2} } \right)dF_{1} \left( x \right)} + \int_{{b_{2} }}^{{\bar{v}}} {\left( {x - v_{2} } \right)dF_{1} \left( x \right))} = E_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) - v_{2} \), losing the auction would be preferable. Finally, if \( b_{2} > \bar{v} \), agent \( 2 \) wins the auction but obtains a negative payoff; therefore, his best choice would be to reply with any action in the interval \( 0 \le b_{2} \le \underline{v} \). However, against this agent \( 1 \) would increase his profit by choosing \( b_{1} \le \underline{v} \), which proves that in this case there cannot be a MSNE where agent \( 1 \) randomizes over the interval \( \left[ {\underline{v} ,\bar{v}} \right] \) with \( \underline{v} \ge v_{2} \).

  2. (ii)

    Suppose \( \underline{v} < v_{2} \le \bar{v} \). If \( b_{2} \le \underline{v} \), then, again, agent \( 2 \) loses the auction, and his payoff \( E_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) - v_{2} \) is constant. If \( \underline{v} < b_{2} \le \bar{v} \), the payoff \( E\varPi_{2} \left( {b_{2} } \right) \) is non-negative at \( b_{2} = v_{2} \) and decreasing for \( v_{2} \le b_{2} \le \bar{v} \), which implies that \( E\varPi_{2} \left( {b_{2} } \right) > E\varPi_{2} \left( {v_{2} } \right) \ge 0 \) for at least one \( b_{2} < v_{2} \). If \( \bar{v} < b_{2} \), he would win the auction, but obtains negative profits. Therefore, for agent \( 2 \) it is optimal to bid below \( v_{2} \), which would imply that for agent \( 1 \) too it is better to bid below \( v_{2} \). Hence, also in this case, there cannot be a MSNE where agent \( 1 \) randomizes over the interval \( \left[ {\underline{v} ,\bar{v}} \right]. \)

  3. (iii)

    Finally, suppose \( v_{2} > \bar{v} \). If \( b_{2} \le \underline{v} \), agent \( 2 \) loses the auction, with his expected payoff \( E_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) - v_{2} \) being constant and negative. If \( b_{2} > \bar{v} \), he wins the auction with expected profit \( v_{2} - b_{2} , \) which is decreasing in \( b_{2} \) and is close to \( v_{2} - \bar{v} > 0 \) for values near to \( \bar{v} \). Hence, he would never choose \( b_{2} \le \underline{v} \); and, moreover, in a MSNE agent \( 2 \) has to obtain at least \( v_{2} - \bar{v} \). Therefore, in a MSNE agent \( 2 \) would randomize over a closed and convex interval \( \left[ {\underline{w} ,\bar{w}} \right] \), against agent \( 1 \) randomizing on \( \left[ {\underline{v} ,\bar{v}} \right] \), only if \( \left[ {\underline{w} ,\bar{w}} \right] \subseteq \left[ {\underline{v} ,\bar{v}} \right] \). However, first notice that if \( \bar{w} < \bar{v} \), then agent \( 1 \) would not find it worthwhile to include \( \bar{v} \) in his randomization interval, since in this case \( E\varPi_{1} \left( {b_{1} = \bar{v}} \right) = v_{1} - \bar{v} < v_{1} - \bar{w} = E\varPi_{1} \left( {b_{1} = \bar{w}} \right) \), which contradicts the initial assumption that \( b_{1} = \bar{v} \) is optimal. It follows that also \( \bar{v} = \bar{w} \) is a necessary condition for agent \( 2 \) to best-reply by randomizing over \( \left[ {\underline{w} ,\bar{w}} \right] \). Then observe that \( E\varPi_{2} \left( {b_{2} = \underline{v} } \right) = E_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) - v_{2} < 0 \), while \( E\varPi_{2} \left( {b_{2} = \bar{v}} \right) = v_{2} - \bar{v} > 0 \). Hence, for agent \( 2 \) to best-reply by randomizing over \( \left[ {\underline{w} ,\bar{w}} \right] \) an additional necessary condition must be that \( \underline{v} < \underline{w} \). But in this case for agent \( 1 \) it will be \( E\varPi_{1} \left( {\underline{v} \le b_{1} < \underline{w} } \right) = E_{2} \left( {b_{2} } \right) - v_{1} < 0 \), with \( E_{2} \left( {b_{2} } \right) = \int_{w}^{{\bar{w}}} {b_{2} dF_{2} \left( {b_{2} } \right),} \) while \( E\varPi_{1} \left( {b_{1} = \bar{v}} \right) = v_{1} - \bar{v} > 0 \), which implies that agent \( 1 \) would not find it optimal to include offers \( b_{1} \)—such that \( \underline{v} \le b_{1} < \underline{w} \)—in his randomization interval, which proves the result.

Proof of Proposition 3

The proof is immediate. Consider agent \( 1^{\prime}s \) profit

$$ \varPi_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} {\left( {v_{1} - \rho b_{2} } \right)} & {\quad if\;\;b_{1} \ge \rho b_{2} } \\ {\left( {\frac{{b_{1} - v_{1} }}{\rho }} \right)} & {\quad if\;\;b_{1} < \rho b_{2} } \\ \end{array} } \right., $$

and suppose that \( v_{1} < \rho b_{2} \). Then if \( b_{1} \ge \) \( \rho b_{2} \), the payoff \( \left( {v_{1} - \rho b_{2} } \right) \) is negative; while if \( b_{1} < \rho b_{2} \), the payoff \( \left( {\frac{{b_{1} - v_{1} }}{\rho }} \right) \) is positive, for \( v_{1} < b_{1} < \rho b_{2} \) and for \( b_{1} = v_{1} \) the payoff is equal to zero. Analogous considerations hold for agent \( 2 \), and the result is proved.□

Proof of Proposition 4

(i) \( v_{1} \ge \rho v_{2} \)

Consider agent \( 1's \) payoff:

$$ \varPi_{1} \left( {b_{1} } \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} {\left( {v_{1} - \rho b_{2} } \right)} & {\quad if\;\;b_{1} \ge \rho b_{2} } \\ {\left( {\frac{{b_{1} - v_{1} }}{\rho }} \right)} & {\quad if\;\;b_{1} < \rho b_{2} } \\ \end{array} } \right., $$

from which it follows immediately that his best reply is given by

$$ b_{1} \left( {b_{2} } \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} {b_{1} \ge \rho b_{2} } & {\quad if\;\;v_{1} \ge \rho b_{2} } \\ {b_{1} = \rho b_{2} - \varepsilon } & {\quad if\;\;v_{1} < \rho b_{2} } \\ \end{array} } \right., $$

where \( \varepsilon > 0 \) is arbitrarily small.

For agent \( 2 \) the payoff is

$$ \varPi_{2} \left( {b_{2} } \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {v_{2} - \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \right)} & {\quad if\;\;b_{2} > \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \\ {\rho (b_{2} - v_{2} )} & {\quad if\;\;b_{2} \le \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \\ \end{array} } \right., $$

and his best reply given by

$$ b_{2} \left( {b_{1} } \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} {b_{2} > \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \hfill & {\quad if\;\;v_{2} > \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \hfill \\ {b_{2} \ge \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \hfill & {\quad if\;\;v_{2} = \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \hfill \\ {b_{2} = \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \hfill & {\quad if\;\;v_{2} < \frac{{b_{1} }}{\rho }} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.. $$

It is then easy to check that the two best replies meet at price pairs \( \left( {b_{1} = b\rho ;\;b_{2} = b} \right) \), with \( v_{2} \le b \le \frac{{v_{1} }}{\rho } \), which represent the set of pure strategy Nash Equilibria. Analogous considerations hold for \( v_{1} < \rho v_{2} \), and the result is proved.□

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Dimitri, N. The “Italian Football Federation Auction” for Co-ownership Resolution. Rev Ind Organ 58, 275–285 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-020-09746-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-020-09746-2

Keywords

Navigation