Skip to main content
Log in

Voting, Regulation, and the Railroad Industry: An Analysis of Private and Public Interest Voting Patterns

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine the role of public and private interests in the passage of major legislative bills that have governed the rail industry since 1887. Our model of voting patterns in the House and Senate introduces novel measures of industry concentration, competition, and network characteristics. We find that both the level and concentration of rail infrastructure in a state, the presence of water competition, and the level of agricultural production each have a major influence over voting patterns not only for the inception of regulation but also in the major bills that deregulated the industry in the 1970s and in 1980.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Much of this literature is amply discussed in Carleton and Perloff (2005), Kahn (1988), Stigler (1971), Schmalensee (1979), Posner (1969), Posner (1974), Needham (1983), and Viscusi et al. (2005). There is a related set of papers on regulatory capture; see, for example, Laffont and Tirole (1991), and Dal Bó (2006). There are also a number of studies that examine public and private interest theories in terms of voting patterns on legislation. These include Kau et al. (1982), Chappell (1982), Gilligan et al. (1989), Glazer and Robbins (1985), Glazer et al. (1987), Poole (1988), Poole and Rosenthal (1993) and Stratmann (1995).

  2. Pegrum (1968), Locklin (1972), Wilcox (1955), and Hillman (1968) that provide superb summaries of the development of the industry, the Granger movement, and the call for regulation as well as descriptions of sections of the Act.

  3. Zerbe (1980) used the same basic data as Spann and Erickson (1970) but used different calculations.

  4. As Hilton (1966) documents, this was not due to a lack of expansion of rail infrastructure, as there was a 60 % increase in track built between 1880 and 1885. However, this track was located strategically, and often there was no economic motivation to serve certain locations and/or to offer multiple alternatives to locations.

  5. Gilligan et al. (1989) explains how short-haul and long-haul movements can actually be thought of as separate markets served by rail.

  6. Binder (1988), Ulen (1980a, b), Ellison (1994),and many others outline many of these arrangements.

  7. In the Wabash case, the Wabash railroad charged more for a short-haul than for a long-haul for similar shipments in the same direction. Shippers from Gilman, Illinois, paid more for shipments to New York than did shippers that were located in Peoria, Illinois. Gilman was closer to New York than Peoria, but Wabash had no competition in Gilman and faced considerable competition in Peoria.

  8. Anecdotal evidence of this conflict of interest can be provided by Joseph Emerson Brown, the senator from Georgia. Senator Brown was one of only 15 U.S. Senators to vote against the Interstate Commerce Act, and the only representative from Georgia to vote against this act. He also served as president of the Western and Atlantic Railroad prior to taking office. Whether this history of working in the railroad industry influenced his vote on the Interstate Commerce Act or not is unknown, but this does illustrate the potential conflict of interest for elected officials leaving office.

  9. As mentioned previously, railroads had formed associations, through which pooling was used to squelch “destructive” competition among railroads in the association.

  10. Although we also have run the model for the Hepburn Act of 1906, the Mann–Elkins Act of 1910, the Transportation Act of 1920, and the Sunset Act of 1995. The former three Acts refine the ICAct, the latter retained rail reregulation, but created the Surface Transportation Board housed within the Department of Transportation and ended the 108 year reign of the Interstate Commerce Commission with a vote of 417 for and only 8 against in the House, and a voice vote in the Senate.

  11. Some members did not vote and were excluded from the analysis.

  12. Note that each of these variables are common to the Congressional voting literature (e.g. McArthur and Marks 1988; Rothenberg and Sanders 2000; Goodman and Nokken 2004; Lawrence 2007; Jenkins and Nokken 2008).

  13. Note that the 1880 Census provides state level data on “cereal production” which includes wheat, oats, corn, etc. and is used for our grain production variable.

  14. We also estimated specifications with a Granger State dummy variable, but never found this to be a statistically significant determining factor in voting behavior when included with the more informative right-hand side variables, including grain production and railroad concentration.

  15. Note that Gilligan et al. (1989) also have a “center” variable for large shipping regions, but details of the construction of this variable are not provided, preventing us from reconstructing this variable. However, as mentioned previously, our waterway competition, grain production, and coastal waterway shipments variables should adequately capture the impacts of their center dummy variable.

  16. Note that our track per square mile variable could be misleading if railroads are monopolizing sections of the state, something which we lack data to estimate. However, the insignificance of this results when accounting for the other competitive factors could be caused by this dynamic.

  17. In the 1960s and 1970s, the railroad industry was struggling due to the advent of new forms of competition, innovations of products that displaced products that were dominated by rail that were more likely to travel by truck, and a lack of innovation and ability to respond due to regulatory control. Major bankruptcies led to the 3R Act, which established Conrail; the 4R Act, which refined the establishment of Conrail but also initiated a new regulatory environment; and the Staggers Rail Act, which substantially reduced regulation of the rail industry (lessened control of rates, eased merger guidelines, etc.).

  18. Note that the timing of the votes for these acts prevented there from being any lame duck members of congress.

References

  • Aitchison, C. B. (1937). The evolution of the Interstate Commerce Act: 1887–1937. The George Washington Law Review, 5(3), 289–403.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binder, J. J. (1985). Measuring the effects of regulation with stock price data. The RAND Journal of Economics, 16(2), 167–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder, J. J. (1988). The Sherman Antitrust Act and the railroad cartels. Journal of Law and Economics, 31(2), 443–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyer, K., Jessup, E., Prater, M. E., Blanton, B., Bahizi, P., Nibarger, D., et al. (2011). Rail rate and revenue changes since the Staggers Act. Journal of the Transportation Research Forum, 50(1), 55–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carleton, D. W., & Perloff, J. M. (2005). Modern industrial organization. Boston, MA, USA: Pearson Addison Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chappell, H. W. (1982). Campaign contributions and congressional voting: A simultaneous probit-tobit model. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 64(1), 77–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dal Bó, E. (2006). Regulatory capture: A review. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(2), 203–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellison, G. (1994). Theories of cartel stability and the joint executive committee. The Rand Journal of Economics, 25(1), 37–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, T. W., Marshall, W. J., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Regulation and the theory of legislative choice: The Interstate Commerce Act of 1887. Journal of Law and Economics, 32(1), 35–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, T. W., Marshall, W. J., & Weingast, B. R. (1990). The economic incidence of the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887: A theoretical and empirical analysis of the short-haul pricing constraint. The Rand Journal of Economics, 21(2), 189–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, A., Grofman, B., & Robbins, M. (1987). Partisan and incumbency effects of 1970s congressional redistricting. American Journal of Political Science, 31(3), 680–707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, A., & Robbins, M. (1985). Congressional responsiveness to constituency change. American Journal of Political Science, 29(2), 259–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, C., & Nokken, T. P. (2004). Lame-Duck legislators and consideration of the ship subsidy bill of 1922. American Politics Research, 32(4), 465–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadley, A. T. (1889). Railroad business under the Interstate Commerce Act. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 3(2), 170–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, J. J. (1968). Competition and railroad price discrimination; legal precedent and economic policy. Evanston, IL, USA: Transportation Center at Northwestern University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilton, G. W. (1966). The consistency of the Interstate Commerce Act. Journal of Law and Economics, 9, 87–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins, J. A., & Nokken, T. P. (2008). Partisanship, the electoral connection, and lame-duck sessions of Congress, 1877–2006. Journal of Politics, 70(2), 450–465.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, A. E. (1988). The economics of regulation: Principles and institutions. Cambridge, MA, USA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J. B., Keenan, D., & Rubin, P. H. (1982). A general equilibrium model of congressional voting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 97(2), 271–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolko, G. (1965). Railroads and regulation, 1877–1916. Princeton, NJ, USA: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J. J., & Tirole, J. (1991). The politics of government decision-making: A theory of regulatory capture. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1089–1127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, C. N. (2007). Of shirking, outliers, and statistical artifacts lame-duck legislators and support for impeachment. Political Research Quarterly, 60(1), 159–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Locklin, D. P. (1972). Economics of transportation. Homewood, IL, USA: R.D. Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacAvoy, P. W. (1965). The economic effects of regulation: The trunk-line railroad cartels and the Interstate Commerce Commission before 1900. Cambridge, MA, USA: M.I.T. Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McArthur, J., & Marks, S. V. (1988). Constituent interest vs. legislator ideology: The role of political opportunity cost. Economic Inquiry, 26(3), 461–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Needham, D. (1983). The economics and politics of regulation: A behavioral approach. Boston, MA, USA: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pegrum, D. F. (1968). Transportation; economics and public policy. Homewood, IL, USA: R.D. Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1984). Constituent interest and congressional voting. Journal of Law and Economics, 27(1), 181–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. (1988). Recent developments in analytical models of voting in the US Congress. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 13(1), 117–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1993). The enduring nineteenth-century battle for economic regulation: The Interstate Commerce Act Revisited. Journal of Law and Economics, 36(2), 837–860.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, R. H. (1983). A study of cartel stability: The Joint Executive Committee, 1880–1886. The Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2), 301–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1969). Natural monopoly and its regulation. Stanford Law Review, 21(3), 548–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of Economic Regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2), 335–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prager, R. A. (1989). Using stock price data to measure the effects of regulation: The Interstate Commerce Act and the railroad industry. The RAND Journal of Economics, 20(2), 280–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothenberg, L. S., & Sanders, M. S. (2000). Lame-duck politics: Impending departure and the votes on impeachment. Political Research Quarterly, 53(3), 523–536.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee, R. (1979). The control of natural monopolies. Lexington, MA, USA: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spann, R. M., & Erickson, E. W. (1970). The economics of railroading: The beginning of cartelization and regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 1(2), 227–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T. (1995). Campaign contributions and congressional voting: Does the timing of contributions matter? The Review of Economics and Statistics, 77(1), 127–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ulen, T. S. (1980a). Cartels and regulation: Late nineteenth-century railroad collusion and the creation of the Interstate Commerce Commission. Journal of Economic History, 40(1), 179–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ulen, T. S. (1980b). The market for regulation: The ICC from 1887 to 1920. The American Economic Review, 70(2), 306–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K., Vernon, J. M., & Harrington, J. E. (2005). Economics of regulation and antitrust. Cambridge, MA, USA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilcox, C. (1955). Public policies toward business. Chicago, IL, USA: Richard D. Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zerbe, R. O, Jr. (1980). The costs and benefits of early regulation of the railroads. The Bell Journal of Economics, 11(1), 343–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kevin E. Henrickson.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Henrickson, K.E., Wilson, W.W. Voting, Regulation, and the Railroad Industry: An Analysis of Private and Public Interest Voting Patterns. Rev Ind Organ 43, 21–39 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-013-9402-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-013-9402-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation