Review of Economics of the Household

, Volume 14, Issue 1, pp 1–26 | Cite as

Do spouses cooperate? An experimental investigation

  • François Cochard
  • Hélène Couprie
  • Astrid Hopfensitz
Article

Abstract

This study makes a significant contribution to investigations of household behavior by testing for a willingness to cooperate and share income by men and women who are either in couple with each other or complete strangers. We present results from an economic experiment conducted with 100 co-habiting heterosexual couples. We compare defection behavior in the prisoner’s dilemma within real couples to pairs of strangers. One out of four participants chose not to cooperate with their spouse. To understand why spouses might prefer defection, we use a novel allocation task to elicit the individual’s trade-off between efficiency and equality within a couple. We further investigate the impact of socio-demographic and psychological characteristics of the couples. We find in particular that lack of preferences for joint income maximization, having children and being married lead to higher defection rates in the social dilemma.

Keywords

Prisoner dilemma Experiment Household Cooperation Efficiency versus equality 

JEL Classification

C72 C91 D13 

Supplementary material

11150_2014_9276_MOESM1_ESM.pdf (471 kb)
Supplementary material 1 (PDF 471 kb)

References

  1. Allen, D. W. (1992). Marriage and Divorce: Comment. American Economic Review, 82(3), 679–685.Google Scholar
  2. Andreoni, J., & Vesterlund, L. (2001). Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 293–312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Apps, P., & Rees, R. (1988). Taxation and the household. Journal of Public Economics, 35(3), 355–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Ashraf, N. (2009). Spousal control and intra-household decision making: An experimental study in the Philippines. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1245–1277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Basu, K. (2001). Gender and say: A model of household behavior with endegenously determined balance of power. Economic Journal, 116(511), 558–580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Bateman, I., & Munro, A. (2005). An experiment on risky choice amongst households. Economic Journal, 115(502), 176–189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Beblo, M., Beninger, D., Cochard, F., Couprie, H., & Hopfensitz, A. (forthcoming). Efficiency-equality trade-off within French and german couples—A comparative experimental study, Annals of Economics and Statistics.Google Scholar
  8. Becker, G. (1981). A treatise on the family. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  9. Becker, G. S., Landes, E., & Michael, R. (1977). An economic analysis of marital instability. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 1141–1188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Bernhard, H., Fischbacher, U., & Fehr, E. (2006). Parochial altruism in humans. Nature, 442, 912–915.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., & Normann, H. T. (2010). A within-subject analysis of other-regarding preferences. Games and Economic Behavior, 72, 321–338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Bochet, O., Page, T., & Putterman, L. (2006). Communication and punishment in voluntary contribution experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60, 11–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Bohnet, I., & Frey, B. (1999). The sound of silence in Prisoner’s dilemma and dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 38, 43–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Browning, M., & Chiappori, P.-A. (1998). Efficient intra-household allocations: A general characterization and empirical tests. Econometrica, 66(6), 1241–1278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Browning, M., Chiappori, P.-A., & Lechene, V. (2006). Collective and unitary models: A clarification. Review of Economics of the Household, 4(1), 5–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Carlsson, F., He, H., Martinsson, P., Qin, P., & Sutter, M. (2012). Household decision making in rural China. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 84(2), 525–536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817–869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Chiappori, P.-A. (1988). Rational household labor supply. Econometrica, 56(1), 63–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Chiappori, P.-A., & Ekeland, I. (2006). The microeconomics of group behavior: General characterization. Journal of Economic Theory, 130, 1–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Chiappori, P.-A., Fortin, B., & Lacroix, G. (2002). Marriage market, divorce legislation and household labor supply. Journal of Political Economy, 110(1), 37–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Cigno, Alessandro. (1991). Economics of the family. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  22. Cigno, Alessandro. (2012). Marriage as a commitment device. Review of Economics of the Household, 10(2), 193–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Cooper, R., DeJong, D., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. (1996). Cooperation without reputation: Experimental evidence from prisoner dilemma games. Games and Economic Behavior, 12(2), 187–218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Croson, R., & Gneezy, U. (2008). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(2), 1–27.Google Scholar
  25. de Palma, A., Picard, N., & Ziegelmeyer, A. (2011). Individual and couple decision behavior under risk: Evidence on the dynamics of power balance. Theory and Decision, 70(1), 45–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Del Boca, D., & Flinn, C. (2012). Endogenous household interaction. Journal of Econometrics, 166(1), 49–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Del Boca, D., & Flinn, C. (2014). Household behavior and the marriage market. Journal of Economic Theory, 150, 515–550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Donni, O., & Moreau, N. (2007). Collective labor supply: A single-equation model and some evidence from French data. Journal of Human Resources, 42(1), 214–246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Glenn, N. D., & McLanahan, S. (1982). Children and marital happiness: A further specification of the relationship. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 44(1), 63–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Goerges, L. (2014). The power of love: Subtle driving-force for unegalitarian labour division?. Onlinefirst: Review of Economics of the Household.Google Scholar
  32. Grossbard, S. (2015). A price theory of marriage. Berlin: Springer (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  33. Grossbard-Shechtman, A. (1984). A theory of allocation of time in markets for labour and marriage. Economic Journal, 94(376), 863–882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Iversen, V., Jackson, C., Kebede, B., Munro, A., & Verschoor, A. (2006). What’s love got to do with it? An experimental test of household models in East Uganda. CSAE WPS/2006-01.Google Scholar
  35. Iyavarakul, T., McElroy, M. B., & Staub, K. (2009), The dimensions of divorce laws: Waiting times, no-fault, and unilateral divorce laws. 4th annual conference on empirical legal studies.Google Scholar
  36. Kebede, B., Tarazona, M., Munro, A., & Verschoor, A. (2011). Intra-household efficiency: An experimental study from Ethiopia, working paper CSAE WPS/2011.Google Scholar
  37. List, J. A. (2004). Young, selfish and male: Field evidence of social preferences. The Economic Journal, 114(492), 121–149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Lundberg, S., & Pollak, R. A. (1993). Separate spheres bargaining and the marriage market. Journal of Political Economy, 101(6), 988–1010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Lundberg, S., & Pollak, R. A. (2007). The American family and family economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives., 21(2), 3–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Mani A. (2010). Mine, yours or ours: The efficiency of household investment decisions—An experimental approach, working paper, University of Warwick.Google Scholar
  41. Manser, M., & Brown, M. (1980). Marriage and household decision making: A bargaining analysis. International Economic Review, 21, 31–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Mazzocco, M. (2007). Household intertemporal behavior: A collective characterization and a test of commitment. Review of Economic Studies, 74(3), 857–895.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. McElroy, B., & Horney, M. J. (1981). Nash-bargained household decisions: Toward a generalization of the theory of demand. International Economic Review, 22, 333–350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Munro, A., Bateman, I., & McNally, T. (2008b). The family under the microscope: An experiment testing economic models of household choice. MPRA working paper, nr. 8974.Google Scholar
  45. Munro, A., McNally, T., & Popov, D. (2008a). Taking it in turn: An experimental test of theories of the household, MPRA working paper, nr. 8976.Google Scholar
  46. Nomaguchi, K. M., & Milkie, M. A. (2003). Costs and rewards of children: The effects of becoming a parent on adults’ lives. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 65(2), 356–374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Oosterbeek, H., Sonnemans, J., & van Velzen, S. (2003). The need for marriage contracts: An experimental study. Journal of Population Economics, 16(3), 431–453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Parkman, A. M. (1992). No-fault divorce; what went wrong?. San Francisco: Westview press.Google Scholar
  49. Pavoni, N. (2000). Inefficiencies in dynamic family decisions: An incomplete contracts approach to labor supply. CHILD working papers no. 6/2000.Google Scholar
  50. Peters, E. H. (1986). Marriage and divorce: Informational constraints and private contracting. American Economic Review, 76(3), 437–454.Google Scholar
  51. Peters, E. H. (1992). Marriage and divorce: Reply. American Economic Review, 82(3), 687–693.Google Scholar
  52. Peters, E. H., Ünür, A. N., Clark, J., & Schulze, W. D. (2004). Free-riding and the provision of public goods in the family: A laboratory experiment. International Economic Review, 45(1), 283–299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Rasul, I. (2006). Marriage markets and divorce laws. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 22(1), 30–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Reuben, E., & van Winden, F. (2008). Social ties and coordination on negative reciprocity: The role of affect. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 34–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Robinson, J. (2008). Limited insurance within the household: Evidence from a field experiment in Kenya, MPRA working paper, nr. 8314.Google Scholar
  56. Roth, A. (1995). Introduction to experimental economics. In J. Kagel & A. Roth (Eds.), The handbook of experimental economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Samelson, P. A. (1956). Social indifference curves. Quaterly Journal of Economics, 70, 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. South, J., & Spitze, G. (1994). Housework in marital and nonmarital households. American Sociological Review, 59(3), 327–347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Spanier, G. B. (1976). Measuring dyadic adjustment: New scales for assessing the quality of marriage and similar dyads. Journal of Marriage and Family, 38, 15–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Stafford, R., Backman, B., & Dibona, P. (1977). Division of labor among cohabiting and married couples. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 39, 43–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2009). The paradox of declining female happiness. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1(2), 190–225.Google Scholar
  62. Tajfel, H., Billig, M., Bundy, R. P., & Flament, C. (1971). Social categorization and intergroup behavior. European Journal of Social Psychology, 1(2), 149–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Udry, C. (1996). Gender, agricultural production, and the theory of the household. Journal of Political Economy, 104(5), 1010–1046.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. van Laningham, J., Johnson, D. R., & Amato, P. R. (2001). Marital happiness, marital duration, and the U-shaped curve: Evidence from a five-wave panel study. Social Forces, 79(4), 1313–1341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Warr, P. (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Economics Letters, 13, 207–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Woolley, F. (2003). Marriage and Control over Money. In S. Grossbard-Shechtman (Ed.), Marriage and the economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  67. Zelder, M. (1993). Inefficient dissolutions as a consequence of public goods: The case of no-fault divorce. The Journal of Legal Studies, 22(2), 503–520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2014

Authors and Affiliations

  • François Cochard
    • 1
  • Hélène Couprie
    • 2
  • Astrid Hopfensitz
    • 3
  1. 1.Université de Franche-Comté (CRESE)BesançonFrance
  2. 2.Université de Cergy-Pontoise (THEMA)Cergy-Pontoise CedexFrance
  3. 3.Toulouse School of EconomicsToulouseFrance

Personalised recommendations