Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Consumer benefits of reforming a state-dominated industry

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The presence of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) in an industry where private firms operate poses a concern over fair competition. This paper estimates the improvement in consumer welfare from eliminating the SOE’s privileges awarded by state-ownership and regulation. The empirical framework is based on a random coefficient discrete choice model and yields an economically interpretable welfare measure in a differentiated product market. Utilizing data on the Korean cigarette manufacturing industry that recently underwent privatization and deregulation, the estimated model shows a significant increase in consumer surplus. This improvement is ascribed to firms’ better alignment of product lines with consumer preferences, to expanded consumer choice, and to a limited rise in prices. The results, however, raise a distributional concern as the gains mostly fall on consumers of mid- and high-price brands.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to the recently collected OECD data (Kowalski et al. 2013), 204 of the world 2,000 largest companies have been identified as state-owned enterprises in years 2010 and 2011, with the combined sales amounting to 6 % of world GDP.

  2. Recent studies argue that even rational smokers may act against the long-term self-interest. See Gruber and Koszegi (2001), for example.

  3. Almost all tobacco products are consumed in cigarettes and the other forms of tobacco products are negligible.

  4. Tobacco Business Act (Act No. 6078, Dec. 31, 1999), Chapter III, Article 11.

  5. Tobacco Business Act (Act No. 6460, Apr. 7, 2001), Chapter III, Article 11-(2).

  6. See Min (2011) for a model that includes non-smoking in the choice set.

  7. The 2003 annual report of KT&G states, “We will continue to introduce differentiated brands that offer high profit margins and meet consumer demand for high quality products. Moreover, the restructuring of our product portfolio to focus on strategic brands will include the gradual phasing out of non-profitable brands. (...) Furthermore, we will be responsive to market demands, and continue to develop brands that meet consumers’ increasing preference for low-tar and slim-type cigarettes.”

  8. Enforcement Decree of the National Health Promotion Act (Decree No. 15732, Feb. 28, 1998), Article 14-(1).

  9. I also run a specification where other firms’ profits are included in the objective and get similar results.

  10. I do not use \(\sum _{l\in F_{f},l\ne j} nb_l\) and \(\sum _{l\not \in F_{f}} nb_l\) as instruments because of multi-collinearity. \(q\), another cost driver, is not used as an instrument because it is an endogenous variable.

  11. A standard pack holds 20 cigarettes.

  12. The manufacturers consistently associate low-tar and slimmer products with “premium” brands (KT&G 2003). Also, low-tar and slim products are on average more expensive.

  13. Cigarette prices in Korea are sticky even these days when this paper is written. Foreign makers only recently begin to experiment on repricing products for reasons other than the change in tax rates. They raised the prices of core products in 2011 but reversed the change next year for the ensuing sharp decrease in demand.

  14. The calculation of confidence intervals follow parametric bootstrapping as in Nevo (2001), where I take a draw from the estimated distribution of the model parameters and calculate the surplus function, and repeat the process 1,000 times to take the 5th percentile and the 95th percentile.

  15. Recent developments in the literature suggests further options to a researcher. Ackerberg and Rysman (2005) present a model where the space of unobserved characteristics becomes crowded as more products are added. Berry and Pakes (2007) give a discrete choice model without the logit error and an estimation algorithm. However, with a limited number of markets, it is hard to apply more sophisticated models.

References

  • Ackerberg, D. A., & Rysman, M. (2005). Unobserved product differentiation in discrete-choice models: Estimating price elasticities and welfare effects. RAND Journal of Economics, 36(4), 771–788.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, S. P., de Palma, A., & Thisse, J.-F. (1997). Privatization and efficiency in a differentiated industry. European Economic Review, 41(9), 1635–1654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., & Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica, 63(4), 841–890.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, S., & Pakes, A. (2007). The pure characteristics demand model. International Economic Review, 48(4), 1193–1225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonnet, C., Dubois, P., Martimort, D., & Straub, S. (2009). Empirical evidence on satisfaction with privatization in Latin America: Welfare effects and beliefs. IDEI Working Papers 566, Institut d’conomie Industrielle (IDEI), Toulouse.

  • Capobianco, A., & Christiansen, H. (2011). Competitive neutrality and state-owned enterprises: Challenges and policy options. OECD Corporate Governance Working Papers No. 1.

  • Checchi, D., Florio, M.,&Carrera, J. (2005). Privatization discontent and its determinants: Evidence from Latin America. IZA Discussion Papers 1587, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).

  • De Fraja, G., & Delbono, F. (1989). Alternative strategies of a public enterprise in oligopoly. Oxford Economic Papers, 41(2), 302–311.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fumagalli, E., Garrone, P., & Grilli, L. (2007). Service quality in the electricity industry: The role of privatization and managerial behavior. Energy Policy, 35(12), 6212–6224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galiani, S., Gertler, P. J., & Schargrodsky, E. (2005). Water for life: The impact of the privatization of water services on child mortality. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 83–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J., & Koszegi, B. (2001). Is addiction rational? theory and evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(4), 1261–1303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, R. G., & Wiens, E. G. (1980). Government enterprise: An instrument for the internal regulation of industry. Canadian Journal of Economics, 13(1), 125–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iyengar, S. S., & Lepper, R. M. (2000). When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too much of a good thing? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 79(6), 995–1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korea Tobacco & Ginseng Co. (KT&G) (2003). Annual Report.

  • Kowalski, P., Bge, M., Sztajerowska, M., & Egeland, M. (2013). State-owned enterprises: Trade effects and policy implications. OECD Trade Policy Paper No. 147.

  • Loewenstein, G. (1999). Is more choice always better? Social Security Brief, No. 7. National Academy of Social Insurance, Washington, D.C.

  • Megginson, W. L., & Netter, J. M. (2001). From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(2), 321–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Min, H. (2011). Reform in a differentiated-product industry: The case of Korean cigarette manufacturing. Korean Economic Review, 27(1), 57–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nevo, A. (2000). A practitioner’s guide to estimation of random-coefficients logit models of demand. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 9(4), 513–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nevo, A. (2001). Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry. Econometrica, 69(2), 307–342.

  • Park, S. (2009). Preference evolution in the south korean cigarette market. Job Market Paper: Johnson Graduate School of Management, Cornell University, New York.

  • Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Johnson, E. J. (1993). The adaptive decision maker. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rivers, D., & Vuong, Q. (2002). Model selection tests for nonlinear dynamic models. Econometrics Journal, 5(1), 1–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sappington, D., & Sidak, J. (2003). Incentives for anticompetitive behavior by public enterprises. Review of Industrial Organization, 22(3), 183–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shafey, O., Eriksen, M., Ross, H., & Mackay, J. (2009). The tobacco atlas. Brighton: American Cancer Society.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (1985). Regret, recrimination and rationality. Theory and Decision, 19, 77–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Train, K. (2009). Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vickers, J., & Yarrow, G. (1991). Economic perspectives on privatization. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(2), 111–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This research was supported by Hankuk University of Foreign Studies Research Fund. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 2013 Summer Conference of the Korea Academic Society of Industrial Organization under the title “Quantifying consumer benets in a privatized industry.” I thank the editor and two anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Heechul Min.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Min, H. Consumer benefits of reforming a state-dominated industry. J Regul Econ 47, 58–77 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-014-9262-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-014-9262-y

Keywords

JEL Classification Codes

Navigation