Skip to main content
Log in

Life Cycles and Gender in Residential Mobility Decisions

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using household survey data from the recent economically depressed period, we attempt to identify typical household characteristics by residential type and study whether households change their residence at different stages of life. We find that the general trend in residential choice is influenced by socioeconomic background. The results of a multinomial probit estimation highlight that the probability of homeownership is higher in rural areas and increases with age of household heads, financial wealth, and family size. In contrast, the probability of renting a house is higher in urban areas and among female households. Moreover, it is observed that people adjust residential size despite market imperfections. The dwelling size increases with age of household heads and declines once they reach retirement age; however, the residential mobility is low at older ages. Furthermore, there are gender differences in terms of attitudes toward downsizing residences; female households are more willing to accept downsizing than are male households.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In 2015, people more than 60 years old accounted for 33.1 percent of Japan’s population, and this figure was the highest in the world, followed by Italy (28.6 percent) and Germany (27.6 percent).

  2. This is due to lack of price data by residential type.

  3. Yaari (1965) proposed a mathematical framework that considered consumers’ lifetime allocation with the uncertainty of survival.

  4. Owing to the regulation set by the data provider (the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications), the confidential data used in this study cannot be passed on to the third party, but are available for purchase from the provider.

  5. The consumption tax (VAT) was increased from 3 to 5 percent in 1997.

  6. Architectural areas are synonymous with floor space and dwelling size, which are also commonly used previously. Due to unavailability of detailed information in our dataset, renovations are considered as changing residences here only if dwelling size changes.

  7. However, the IIA is found to be particularly not restrictive in many applications ((Dow and Endersby 2004).

  8. Also see Appendix A for further explanations.

  9. Seko and Sumita (2007b) used dummies to identify gender, occupation, and college graduation to estimate permanent income and use this income to explain household behavior.

  10. Takats (2012) reports a significant relationship between demography and house prices in a panel of advanced countries.

  11. The average age of males and females at the time of first marriage is 29 and 27 years, respectively.

  12. In case of condominiums, the common area among residents is excluded from the calculation of architectural areas.

  13. We assume a parallel trend in the control and treatment groups before an intervention event like retirement. This assumption is reasonable because all households live in the same (relatively homogeneous) country and period.

  14. It has been known as Urban Renaissance Agency (Toshi Saisei Kikou) since 2004.

  15. According to 2010 statistics from the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications.

References

  • Angelini, V., & Laferrere, A. (2012). Residential mobility of the European elderly. CESifo Economic Studies, 58(3), 544–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Artle, R., & Varaiya, P. (1978). Life cycle consumption and homeownership. Journal of Economic Theory, 18(1), 38–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakan, D. (1966). The Duality of Human Existence: An Essay on Psychology and Religion. Rand McNally.

  • Banks, J., Blundell, R., Oldfield, Z., Smith, J.P. (2012). Housing mobility and downsizing at older ages in Britain and the USA. Economica, 79(313), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baquedano, M. L. S. d. A., Lizarraga, M. T. S. d. A., Cardelle-Elawar, M. (2007). Factors that affect decision making: Gender and age differences. International Journal of Psychology and Psychological Therapy, 7, 381–391.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borsch-Supan, A., Heiss, F., Seko, M. (2001). Housing demand in Germany and Japan. Journal of Housing Economics, 10(3), 229–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card, D., & Krueger, A.B. (1994). Minimum wages and employment: A case study of the fast-food industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania. American Economic Review, 84(4), 772–793.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, H.L. (1976). Decision making within the household. Journal of Consumer Research, 2(4), 241–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deutsch, E., Tiwari, P., Moriizumi, Y. (2006). The slowdown in the timing of housing purchases in Japan in the 1990s. Journal of Housing Economics, 15(3), 230–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dow, J.K., & Endersby, J.W. (2004). Multinomial probit and multinomial logit: a comparison of choice models for voting research. Electoral studies, 23(1), 107–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1957). A Theory of the Consumption Function, Chapter III, The Permanent Income Hypothesis, pp. 20–37. Princeton University Press.

  • Gabriel, R. (2018). Gender and the resiential mobility and neighborhood attainment of Black -White couples. Demography, 55(2), 459–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geissler, F., Leopold, T., Pink, S. (2013). Gender differences in residential mobility: The case of leaving home in East Germany. Schmollers Jahrbuch : Journal of Applied Social Science Studies / Zeitschrift fur Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften, 133(2), 239–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, R.T., & Cunningham, I.C.M. (1980). Family purchasing roles in two countries. Journal of International Business Studies, 11(1), 92–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harano, K., Nakagawa, M., Shimizu, C., Karato, H. (2012). The effects of asymmetric information on prices in the second house market. Nihon Keizai Kenkyu, 66, 51–71.

  • Hayashi, F., Ito, T., Slemrod, J. (1988). Housing finance imperfections, taxation, and private saving: a comparative simulation analysis of the United States and Japan. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 2(3), 215–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, J., & Ioannides, Y.M. (1989). Dynamic aspects of consumer decisions in housing markets. Journal of Urban Economics, 26(2), 212–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, J.V., & Ioannides, Y.M. (1983). A model of housing tenure choice. American Economic Review, 73(1), 98–113.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henthorne, T.L., LaTour, M.S., Hudson, T.W. (1997). Japanese couples’ marital roles in stages of product purchase decision making. International Marketing Review, 14(1), 39–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horioka, C.Y. (1988). Tenure choice and housing demand in Japan. Journal of Urban Economics, 24(3), 289–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ishikawa, N., & Fukushige, M. (2015). Dissatisfaction with dwelling environments in an aging society: An empirical analysis of the Kanto area in Japan. Review of Urban & Regional Development Studies, 27(3), 149–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorda, O., Schularick, M., Taylor, A.M. (2016). The great mortgaging: housing finance, crises and business cycles. Economic Policy, 31(85), 107–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kobayashi, K., & Yukutake, N. (2008). The relocation of residece in tokyo area after the 1990s. Jutaku Tochi Keizai (Quarterly Journal o f Housing and Economics), 68, 27–35. In Japanese.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kose, S. (1997). Housing elderly people in Japan. Ageing International, 23(3), 148–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, M.-J. (2016). Matching, Regression Discontinuity, Difference in Differences, and Beyond. Oxford University Press.

  • Leung, C. (2004). Macroeconomics and housing: a review of the literature. Journal of Housing Economics, 13(4), 249–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsuo, M. (2016). Gender differences in mobility of Hispanic immigrants. Transport Policy, 52, 209–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moriizumi, Y. (1993). Tenure choice and the demand for rental housing in Japan. Economic Studies Quarterly, 44(1), 29–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moriizumi, Y., & Naoi, M. (2011). Unemployment risk and the timing of homeownership in Japan. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 41(3), 227–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagayasu, J. (2016). Inflation and bubbles in the Japanese condominium market. MPRA Paper 71192.

  • Sanchez, A.C., & Andrews, D. (2011). Residential mobility and public policy in OECD countries. OECD Journal: Economic Studies, 2011(1), 1–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seko, M. (2000). Elderly houshouse’s housing tenure choice in Japan. Keio Journal of Economics, 93(2), 353–368. In Japanese.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seko, M., & Sumita, K. (2007a). Effects of government policies on residential mobility in Japan: Income tax deduction system and the Rental Act. Journal of Housing Economics, 16(2), 167–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seko, M., & Sumita, K. (2007b). Japanese housing tenure choice and welfare implications after the revision of the tenant protection law. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(3), 357–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seko, M., Sumita, K., Naoi, M. (2012). Residential mobility decisions in Japan: Effects of housing equity constraints and income shocks under the recourse loan system. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 45(1), 63–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snow, J. (1855). On the mode of Communication of Cholera, 2nd edn. London: John Churchill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strodtbeck, F.L. (1951). Husband-wife interaction over revealed differences. American Sociological Review, 16(4), 468–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takats, E. (2012). Aging and house prices. Journal of Housing Economics, 21 (2), 131–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Train, K.E. (2009). Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation. Cambridge University Press.

  • Yaari, M.E. (1965). Uncertain lifetime, life insurance, and the theory of the consumer. Review of Economic Studies, 32(2), 137–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jun Nagayasu.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interests

The author declares that he has no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The earlier version of this paper was presented at the biannual meeting of the Japanese Economic Association and the Japan Society of Monetary Economics (2018). I would like to thank the editor, anonymous referees, Charles Y. Horioka, Masafumi Kozuka, Arito Ono, Yoko Shirasu, and Hisaski Yamaga and other participants for constructive comments, and Gabriel Cordoba and Zheqin Chen for research assistance. All remaining errors are mine. The author declares that he has no conflict of interest. This work was supported by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (JSPS, KAKENHI Grant Number 17K03796). Any opinion, findings and conclusions expressed in this paper are those of the auhor and do not necessarily reflect the views of the author’s organization or the JSPS.

Appendices

Appendix: A

Using the notations used in the main text, the probability of i choosing j can be expressed in the MNP framework as

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} Prob(v_{i1}\leq 0, \dots, v_{i J-1}\leq 0) &=& \frac{1}{(2\pi)^{\frac{(J-1)}{2}} \arrowvert {\Sigma} \arrowvert^{\frac{1}{2}} } {\int}_{-\infty}^{-\lambda_{i1}} \dots {\int}_{-\infty}^{-\lambda_{iJ-1}}\\ &&\times \exp \left( - \frac{1}{2} z^{\prime} {\Sigma}^{-1}z\right) dz \end{array} $$

We have used STATA to compute the MNP statistics, which use the Gaussian quadrature approximation for the integral in the above equation.

Appendix: B

Closely following Lee (2016, p. 167) and maintaining the same notations used in the main text, we can state an identification condition for the DIDID by rewriting Eq. (8). In order to distinguish between treated and untreated responses of households, we define y1 as a potential response of treated households and y0 as that of untreated households. Then, the aggregate response can be expressed as y = (1 − k)y0 + ky1, where k = 1 for the treated group and 0 otherwise. Assuming that the treatment occurs in the second period, it follows that y = y0 for the first period (Time = 0) and y = (1 − k)y0 + ky1 for the second period (Time = 1). This is because only when all dummy indicators (Time, Gender and AGs) are equal to 1, the composite term (Time ×Gender ×AGs) becomes unity, and k = 0 when one (or two or all) of the dummies is 0. Therefore, y = y0 is always established for the first period.

Then, by ignoring covariate x in Eq. (8) for simplicity and by subtracting and adding E(y0|AGs = 1,Gender = 1,Time = 1) after the first of Eq. (8), we can obtain the net effect that is equal to:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&E(y^{1}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1,\text{Gender} = 1,\text{Time} = 1) - E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1, \text{Gender} = 1,\text{Time} = 1 )\\ &&+E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1,\text{Gender} = 1, \text{Time} = 1) - E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1, \text{Gender} = 1, \text{Time} = 0)\\ &&-[E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 0, \text{Gender} = 1,\text{Time} = 1) - E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 0, \text{Gender} = 1, \text{Time} = 0)]\\ &&-\{[E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1, \text{Gender} = 0, \text{Time} = 1) - E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1, \text{Gender} = 0), \text{Time} = 0]\\ &&-[E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 0, \text{Gender} = 0, \text{Time} = 1) - E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 0, \text{Gender} = 0, \text{Time} = 0)]\} \end{array} $$

Note that E(y0|AGs = 1,Gender = 1,Time = 1) is counterfactual due to y0 despite AGs = 1,Gender = 1 during the second period. Households in this group are expected to change residence. The last eight items are involved in the identification condition; that is,

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1,\text{Gender} = 1, \text{Time} = 1) - E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1, \text{Gender} = 1, \text{Time} = 0)\\ &&-[E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 0, \text{Gender} = 1,\text{Time} = 1) - E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 0, \text{Gender} = 1, \text{Time} = 0)]\\ &=& E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1, \text{Gender} = 0, \text{Time} = 1) - E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 1, \text{Gender} = 0), \text{Time} = 0\\ &&-[E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 0, \text{Gender} = 0, \text{Time} = 1) - E(y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}} = 0, \text{Gender} = 0, \text{Time} = 0)] \end{array} $$

This abovementioned equation implies that an identification condition for the DIDID for repeated cross-sectional data requires differences between untreated response changes for the (AGs= 1,Gender= 1) group and the (AGs= 0, Gender= 1) group being equal to those between untreated response changes for the (AGs= 1,Gender= 0) group and the (AGs= 0, Gender= 0) group. For example, untreated responses of the (AGs= 1, Gender= 1) group correspond to responses of elderly females who did not move residence. As Lee (2016, pp. 168-175) stated, the identification condition for repeated cross-sectional data is difficult to understand since eight terms are involved; this condition for panel data is much simpler.

When this identification condition holds, we can obtain an expression for the net effect that identifies the effect on the treated (AGs = 1,Gender = 1) in the second period:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &E(y^{1}-y^{0}| \mathrm{AG_{\textit{s}}}=1,\text{Gender}=1,\text{Time}=1) \end{array} $$

Thus, the net effect is equal to the expected value of differences between identified and counterfactual effects, and this is equivalent to ID8D in Lee (2016).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Nagayasu, J. Life Cycles and Gender in Residential Mobility Decisions. J Real Estate Finan Econ 62, 370–401 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-019-09743-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-019-09743-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation