Skip to main content
Log in

Computation of Hedging Coefficients for Mortgage Default and Prepayment Options: Malliavin Calculus Approach

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study explores the hedging coefficients of the financial options to default and to prepay embedded into mortgage contracts based on the change in spot rate, underlying house price and its volatility. In the computations, the finite-dimensional Malliavin calculus is applied since the distribution of both options is unknown and their payoffs are non-differentiable. Naturally, the hedging coefficients are obtained as a product of option’s payoff and an independent weight, which permits the user to derive estimations for the hedging coefficients by running a crude Monte Carlo (MC) algorithm. The simulations reveal that the financial options to default and to prepay are both more sensitive to a change in spot rate than a change in underlying house price and its volatility. There are two potential usages of the hedging coefficients: first, they allow the user to determine the effects of spot rate and underlying house price change and its volatility on the default and prepayment options, and second, borrowers and lenders can replicate and hedge their main portfolio by using the balance between these coefficients and the default and prepayment options.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Ambrose, B.W., & Buttimer, R.J. (2000). Embedded options in the mortgage contract. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 21(2), 95–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ambrose, B.W., Buttimer, R.J., Capone, C.A. (1997). Pricing mortgage default and foreclosure delay. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29(3), 314–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azevedo-Pereira, J.A., Newton, D.P., Paxson, D. (2000). Numerical solutions of a two state variable contingent claims mortgage valuation model. Portuguese Review of Financial Markets, 3, 35–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Azevedo-Pereira, J.A., Newton, D.P., Paxson, D.A. (2003). Fixed-rate endowment mortgage and mortgage indemnity valuation. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 26(2), 197–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bismut, J. (1984). Large deviations and the Malliavin calculus. Progress in mathematics. Birkhäuser.

  • Case, K.E. Jr, Shiller, R.J., Weiss, A.N. (1993). Index-based futures and options markets in real estate. The Journal of Portfolio Management, 19(2), 83–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case, K.E., Shiller, R.J., Weiss, A.N. (1996). Mortgage default risk and real estate prices: the use of index-based futures and options in real estate. Journal of Housing Research, 7(2), 243–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee, A., Edmister, R.O., Hatfield, G.B. (1998). An empirical investigation of alternative contingent claims models for pricing residential mortgages. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 17(2), 139–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J.C., Ingersoll, J.E. Jr, Ross, S.A. (1985). A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 385–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunn, K.B., & McConnell, J. (1981). Valuation of gnma mortgage-backed securities. The Journal of Finance, 36(3), 599–616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elworthy, K., & Li, X.M. (1994). Formulae for the derivatives of heat semigroups. Journal of Functional Analysis, 125(1), 252–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fournié, E., Lasry, J.M., Lebuchoux, J., Lions, P.L., Touzi, N. (1999). Applications of Malliavin calculus to Monte Carlo methods in finance. Finance and Stochastics, 3(4), 391–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fournié, E., Lasry, J.M., Lebuchoux, J., Lions, P.L. (2001). Applications of Malliavin calculus to Monte-Carlo methods in finance. II. Finance and Stochastics, 5(2), 201–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hilliard, J.E., Kau, J.B., Slawson, V.C. (1998). Valuing prepayment and default in a fixed-rate mortgage: A bivariate binomial options pricing technique. Real Estate Economics, 26(3), 431–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinkelmann, C., & Swidler, S. (2008). Trading house price risk with existing futures contracts. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 36(1), 37–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalotay, A., Yang, D., Fabozzi, F.J. (2004). An option-theoretic prepayment model for mortgages and mortgage-backed securities. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 7(08), 949–978.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J.B., & Carlos Slawson, V. (2002). Frictions, heterogeneity and optimality in mortgage modeling. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 24(3), 239–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J.B., & Keenan, D.C. (1995). An overview of the option-theoretic pricing of mortgages. Journal of Housing Research, 6(2), 217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J.B., Keenan, D.C., Muller, W.J., Epperson, J.F. (1992). A generalized valuation model for fixed-rate residential mortgages. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 24(3), 279–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J.B., Keenan, D.C., Muller, W.J., Epperson, J.F. (1993). Option theory and floating-rate securities with a comparison of adjustable- and fixed-rate mortgages. The Journal of Business, 66(4), 595–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J.B., Keenan, D.C., Kim, T. (1994). Default probabilities for mortgages. Journal of Urban Economics, 35(3), 278–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leece, D. (2008). Economics of the mortgage market: perspectives on household decision making. real estate issues. Wiley.

  • Longstaff, F.A. (2005). Borrower credit and the valuation of mortgage-backed securities. Real Estate Economics, 33(4), 619–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R.C. (1973). Theory of rational option pricing. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 4(1), 141–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miranda-Mendoza, F. (2010). An option-theoretic valuation model for residential mortgages with stochastic conditions and discount factors. Ph.D. thesis, Iowa State University.

  • Nualart, D. (2006). The Malliavin calculus and related topics (Vol. 1995). Springer.

  • Otaka, M., & Kawaguchi, Y. (2002). Hedging and pricing of real estate securities under market incompleteness. In Quantitative methods in finance conference. Cairns.

  • Pliska, S.R. (2006). Mortgage valuation and optimal refinancing. In Shiryaev, A.N., Grossinho, M.R., Oliveira, P.E., Esquível, M.L. (Eds.) Stochastic finance (pp. 183–196). Boston: Springer.

  • Schwartz, E.S., & Torous, W.N. (1989). Prepayment and the valuation of mortgage-backed securities. The Journal of Finance, 44(2), 375–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, E.S., & Torous, W.N. (1992). Prepayment, default, and the valuation of mortgage pass-through securities. The Journal of Business, 65(2), 221–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharp, N.J., Johnson, P.V., Newton, D.P., Duck, P.W. (2009). A new prepayment model (with default): an occupation-time derivative approach. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 39(2), 118–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, A. (2005). Arbitrage models and mortgage options pricing. In European real estate society ERES 2005. Dublin, https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00150903.

  • Stanton, R. (1995). Rational prepayment and the valuation of mortgage-backed securities. Review of Financial Studies, 8(3), 677–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugimura, T. (2004). Valuation of residential mortgage-backed securities with default risk using an intensity-based approach. Asia-Pacific Financial Markets, 11 (2), 185–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Titman, S., & Torous, W. (1989). Valuing commercial mortgages: an empirical investigation of the contingent- claims approach to pricing risky debt. The Journal of Finance, 44(2), 345–373.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors thank the comments received from Prof. Dr. Ernst Eberlein at the earlier stages of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bilgi Yilmaz.

Appendices

Appendix A: Monthly Payment and Principal Balance

In the case of FRM, the mortgage loan is repaid by a series of equal monthly payments (MP) on pre-determined payment dates. The MP of an FRM for a householder and the outstanding balance (OB)following each payment (OB) are calculated using standard annuity formulas,

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} MP &=& OB(0)\frac{(\frac{c}{12})(1+\frac{c}{12})^{m}} {(1+\frac{c}{12})^{m}-1},\\ OB(t) &=& OB(0)\frac{(1+\frac{c}{12})^{m}-(1+\frac{c}{12})^{t}} {(1+\frac{c}{12})^{m}-1}, \end{array} $$

where c is the fixed yearly mortgage rate, OB(0) is the initial loan amount and m is the life of the mortgage loan in months.

Appendix B: A Brief Review on Malliavin Calculus

The Malliavin calculus is a powerful tool to deal with anticipating processes. This theory becomes a natural tool to analyze the Greeks starting with the pioneering studies (Fournié et al. 1999; Fournié et al. 2001) since it makes possible to differentiate with respect to the chance parameter.

Consider a real separable Hilbert space, H, with a scalar product denoted by \(\left \langle \cdot ,\cdot \right \rangle _{H}\). Then, the class of smooth random variables \(\left (\mathcal {S}\right )\) contains random variables F of the form,

$$ F=f\left( W(h_{1}),\ldots,W(h_{n})\right), $$
(11)

where \(f:\mathbb {R}^{n}\longrightarrow \mathbb {R}\) represents the set of all infinitely continuously differentiable functions with all of its derivatives having polynomial growth \((f \in C_{P}^{\infty }\left (\mathbb {R}^{n}\right ))\), and hiH, i = 1, 2,…, n for n ≥ 1 and \(W=\left \{W(h), h\in H\right \}\) is an isonormal Gaussian process defined on a complete probability space \(\left ({\Omega }, \mathcal {F},P\right )\). Here, W is a centered Gaussian family of random variables and satisfies for all h, gH (Nualart 2006). Then, the Malliavin derivative is given with the following definition.

Definition 2

Let \( F \in \mathcal {S}\) and \(H=L^{2}([0,T], \mathcal {B}, \mu )\). Then, the Malliavin derivative \(D:\mathcal {S}\mapsto L^{2}\left (\left [0, T\right ],\beta ,\mu \right )\) of F is given by

$$ DF=\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n}{\frac{\partial f}{\partial x_{i}}\left( W(h_{1}),\ldots, W(h_{n})\right)h_{i}}, $$
(12)

where \(\frac {\partial f} {\partial x_{i}}\) is the derivative of \(f \in C_{P}^{\infty }\left (\mathbb {R}^{n}\right )\) with respect to its i th variable.

Note that the derivative operator, D, is closable from L2(Ω) to \(L^{2}\left ({\Omega }\times \left [0, T\right ]\right )\) (Nualart 2006). Therefore, it can be extended to the stochastic Sobolev space \(\mathbb {D}^{1,2}\), which is closure of \(\mathcal {S}\) with respect to the norm

figure k

Moreover, the domain of the Malliavin derivative, \(\mathbb {D}^{1,2}\), is a Hilbert space with a scalar product,

figure l

where \(F, G \in \mathbb {D}^{1,2}\).

Now, the chain rule for the Malliavin derivative can immediately be introduced.

Proposition 4 (Chain Rule)

LetF = (F1,…, Fn) bea random vector whose components are in thespace\(\mathbb {D}^{1,2}\)and\(\varphi :\mathbb {R}^{n}\mapsto \mathbb {R}\)isa function in space\(f \in C_{P}^{\infty }\left (\mathbb {R}^{n}\right )\).Then,\(\varphi (F)\in \mathbb {D}^{1,2}\)and

$$ D_{t} \varphi(F)=\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n}{\frac{\partial \varphi}{\partial x_{i}}(F)D_{t}F_{i}}, a.s.\quad t \in [0,T]. $$
(13)

As an immediate result of Proposition 4, the following lemma can be introduced.

Lemma 1

Suppose that the sequence\(F_{n}\in \mathbb {D}^{1,2}\)convergingto F in the space\(L^{2}\left ({\Omega },\mathcal {F},\mathbb {P}\right )\)satisfying . Then, \(F\in \mathbb {D}^{1,2}\) and DFn weakly converges to DF in \(L^{2}\left ({\Omega }\times \left [0, T\right ]\right )\).

Now Proposition 4 can be generalized to the functions even not necessarily differentiable.

Proposition 5

Given a functionφthatsatisfies, for a positive constant\(K\in \mathbb {R}\),

$$\left|\varphi(x)-\varphi(y)\right|\leq K\left|x-y\right|, \quad x,y\in\mathbb{R}^{n} $$

and \(F\in \mathbb {D}^{1,2}\). Then \(\varphi (F)\in \mathbb {D}^{1,2}\)and there exists an n-dimensional random vector\(G\in \mathbb {R}^{n}\), \(\left |G\right |<K\)such that

$$D(\varphi(F))=\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n}{G_{i}DF_{i}}. $$

The Malliavin derivative is a closed linear, unbounded operator with a dense domain in space L2(Ω). Now, an adjoint operator δ of this operator may be defined such that \(\delta :L^{2}\left ({\Omega }\times \left [0, T\right ]\right )\mapsto L^{2}\left ({\Omega }\right )\) and denote the domain of adjoint operator δ by Dom(δ).

Definition 3

Let \(u\in L^{2}\left (\left [0,T\right ],\beta ,\mu \right )\) and uDom(δ). Then, \(\forall F\in \mathbb {D}^{1,2}\), one has

figure n

where c is a constant depending on u,

$$\delta(u)={{\int}_{0}^{T}}{u_{t}\delta W_{t}} $$

is in L2(Ω) and the duality formula holds,

figure o

Now, based on the previous definitions the integration by parts formula can be introduced.

Proposition 6 (Integration by Parts Formula)

Suppose that\(F\in \mathbb {D}^{1,2}\)andFhDom(δ) forhH.Then, the following equation is satisfied

$$\delta\left( Fh\right)=FW(h)-\left\langle DF, h\right\rangle_{H}. $$

Moreover, if F = 1 a.s.,

$$\delta(h)=W(h). $$

Remark 1

In particular if \(H=L^{2}([0,T], \mathcal {B}, \mu )\), where μ is a σ-finite atomless measure on measurable Borel space \(([0,T], \mathcal {B})\), Proposition 6 becomes

$${{\int}_{0}^{T}} F h_{t} \delta W_{t} =F {{\int}_{0}^{T}} h_{t} \delta W_{t} -{{\int}_{0}^{T}}{D_{t}F h_{t} dt}. $$

Remark 2

The domain of the Skorohod integral also contains the adapted stochastic processes in the space \(L^{2}\left ({\Omega }\times \left [0, T\right ]\right )\). If the integrand is adapted, the Skorohod integral coincides with the Itô integral (see Nualart 2006), i.e.

$$\delta(h)={{\int}_{0}^{T}}{h_{t} dW_{t}}, $$

and

$${{\int}_{0}^{T}} F h_{t} dW_{t} = F{{\int}_{0}^{T}}{h_{t} dW_{t}}-{{\int}_{0}^{T}}{D_{t}F h_{t} dt}, $$

where \(F\in \mathbb {D}^{1, 2}\) and .

In this part it is necessary to give the following Remark.

Remark 3

In the case when F is a d-dimensional random column-vector and ht is a matrix process with a dimension d × d, Remark 2 translates to

$$\delta(hF)={{\int}_{0}^{T}} F h_{t} dW_{t} = F{{\int}_{0}^{T}}{h_{t}DW_{t}}-{{\int}_{0}^{T}}{Tr((D_{t}F)u_{t})dt}, $$

with the convention that the Itô integral for a matrix process is a column-vector. Here Tr represents the trace of the matrix.

The first variation process of multi-dimensional process Xt is the derivative of Xt with respect to its initial value x for \(t\in \left [0, T\right ]\), and it is introduced by following definition.

Definition 4

Let (Xt)t∈[0, T] be an \(\mathbb {R}^{2}\) valued Itô process whose dynamics are driven by the SDE given with Eq. 3. Then,

figure q

is known as the first variation process. Here, the primes denote the derivatives and σi is the ith column vector of σ. Moreover, corresponds to a 2 × 2 identity matrix and Yt = DxXt. Note that β and σ are at least twice continuously differentiable functions with bounded derivatives, and Xt has continuous trajectories.

It is true that one can represent Yt as Yt = ∇xXt, and moreover, since β and σ are continuously differentiable functions with bounded derivatives and the process Xt is continuous, the Malliavin derivative of Xt can immediately be written as follows (See Fournié et al. 1999 for further details)

figure s

Moreover, the following remark also can be given.

Remark 4

Note that \(Y_{t}^{11}\) can be expressed in terms of the house price, i.e.

$$Y_{t}^{11}= \frac{1} {h_{0}} h_{t},\quad a.s. $$

Now, a definition is given for a square integrable option payoff \({\Phi } = {\Phi }(X_{t_{1}},\ldots , X_{t_{n}})\), which is evaluated at time t1, t2,…, tn. Then, the price of a claim is the discounted value and it is expressed as

figure t

The objective of the computation of Greeks is to differentiate the contingent claim value v with respect to the model parameters. In order to make the proofs, it is necessary to assume the diffusion matrix σ to be uniformly elliptic, that is to say

$$ \exists\eta>0, \text{such that}\quad \xi^{\top} \sigma(x)^{\top} \sigma(x)\xi \geq \eta\left|\xi\right|^{2},\quad \text{for any}\quad \xi, x\in\mathbb{R}^{n}. $$
(17)

B.1 Variations in the Initial Condition

In order to obtain a valid computation result, it is necessary to guarantee that the weights do not degenerate with the probability one. Therefore, Fournié et al. (1999) demonstrates the following set of square integrable functions

$${\Gamma}=\left\{\alpha\in L^{2}\left( \left[0, T\right]\right);{\int}_{0}^{t_{i}}{\alpha(t)dt}= 1, \forall i = 1,\cdots,n\right\}, $$

in \(\mathbb {R}\) to avoid degeneracy. Here ti’s are a partition of [0, T] as introduced above.

The Bismut-Elworthy-Li formula introduced in Bismut (1984) and Elworthy and Li (1994) is required.

Proposition 7 (Bismut-Elworthy formula)

Assume that the diffusion matrixσisuniformly elliptic and Φ isa continuously differentiable function with bounded gradient. Then, for anyα(t) ∈Γ

figure u

B.2 Variations in the Drift Coefficient

In order to assess the sensitivity of the price of the contingent claim v to changes in the drift coefficient the perturbed process below is introduced,

$$dX_{t}^{\epsilon} =\left[\beta(X_{t}^{\epsilon})+\epsilon\gamma(X_{t}^{\epsilon})\right]dt + \sigma(X_{t}^{\epsilon})d\mathbb{W}_{t}, \quad X_{0}^{\epsilon}=x, $$

where 𝜖 is a scalar and γ is a bounded function. The following Proposition tells the user how sensitive the price of a claim on the perturbed process is to 𝜖 in the point 𝜖 = 0.

Next consider a continuously differentiable and square integrable continuous function Φ satisfying,

figure v

Proposition 8

Suppose that the diffusion matrixσsatisfiesthe uniformly ellipticity condition and the option payoff Φ isa square integrable continuous function. For the perturbed price process

figure w

the following is obtained

figure x

B.3 Variations in the Diffusion Coefficient

In the computation of the contingent claim, v, sensitivity with respect to it’s volatility parameter, the perturbed process below is used

$$dX_{t}^{\epsilon} =\beta\left( X_{t}^{\epsilon}\right) + \left[\sigma\left( X_{t}^{\epsilon}\right)+\epsilon\gamma(X_{t}^{\epsilon})\right]d\mathbb{W},\quad X_{0}^{\epsilon}=x, $$

where the parameter 𝜖 is a scalar and γ is a continuously differentiable function with bounded derivatives. Furthermore, σ + 𝜖γ satisfies the uniform ellipticity condition given with Eq. 17. To proceed the computations, it is also needed to introduce the variation process with respect to the scalar 𝜖

$$dZ_{t}^{\epsilon} =\beta^{\prime}\left( X_{t}^{\epsilon}\right)Z_{t}^{\epsilon} dt +\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{2}{\left( \sigma_{i}^{\prime}\left( X_{t}^{\epsilon}\right)+\epsilon\gamma(X_{t}^{\epsilon})\right)Z_{t}^{\epsilon} d{W_{t}^{i}}}+\gamma(X_{t}^{\epsilon})d\mathbb{W}_{t} $$

with an initial value \(Z_{0}^{\epsilon }= 0_{n}\). Here, one may notice that \(\frac {\partial X_{t}^{\epsilon }}{\partial \epsilon }=Z_{t}^{\epsilon }\). Also, \(Z_{t}^{\epsilon }|_{\epsilon = 0}\) is defined as Zt. Furthermore, the set of square integrable functions on \(\mathbb {R}\) are defined as

$$ {\Gamma}_{n}=\left\{\alpha\in L^{2}\left( [0,T)\right):{\int}_{t_{i-1}}^{t_{i}}{\alpha(t)dt}= 1,\quad \forall i = 1,\ldots,n, t_{0}= 0\right\}. $$
(18)

Now, based on the perturbed process (10) the following proposition may be given.

Proposition 9

Assume that the diffusion matrixσsatisfiesuniformly ellipticity condition (17) and for\(B_{t_{i}}=Y_{t_{i}}^{-1}Z_{t_{i}}\),i = 1,…, nthevalueσ− 1(Xt)YtBtDom(δ) exists.Then, for the price process

figure y

and for any α ∈Γn the following is obtained

figure z

where

figure aa

Remark 5

If \(B_{t}\in \mathbb {D}\), the Skorohod integral \(\delta \left (\sigma ^{-1}(X_.)Y_.\tilde {B}_.\right )\) may be calculated as

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \delta\left( \sigma^{-1}(X_.)Y_.\tilde{B}_.\right)&=&\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n}\left\{B_{t_{i}}^{\top}{\int}_{t_{i-1}}^{t_{i}}{\alpha(t)\left( \sigma^{-1}(X_{t})Y_{t}\right)^{\top}}d\mathbb{W}_{t}\right.\\ &-&{\int}_{t_{i-1}}^{t_{i}}{\alpha(t)Tr\left( \left( D_{t}B_{t_{i}}\right)\sigma^{-1}(X_{t})Y_{t}\right)dt}\\ &-&\left.{\int}_{t_{i-1}}^{t_{i}}{\alpha(t)\left( \sigma^{-1}(X_{t})Y_{t}B_{t_{i-1}}\right)^{\top} d\mathbb{W}_{t}}\right\}. \end{array} $$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yilmaz, B., Selcuk-Kestel, A.S. Computation of Hedging Coefficients for Mortgage Default and Prepayment Options: Malliavin Calculus Approach. J Real Estate Finan Econ 59, 673–697 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-018-9688-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-018-9688-6

Keywords

Navigation