Skip to main content
Log in

Episodes of Exuberance in Housing Markets: In Search of the Smoking Gun

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we examine changes in the time series properties of three widely used housing market indicators (real house prices, price-to-income ratios, and price-to-rent ratios) for a large set of countries to detect episodes of explosive dynamics. Dating such episodes of exuberance in housing markets provides a timeline as well as empirical content to the narrative connecting housing exuberance to the global 2008 −09 recession. For our empirical analysis, we employ two recursive univariate unit root tests recently developed by Phillips and Yu (International Economic Review 52(1):201–226, 2011) and Phillips et al. (2015). We also propose a novel extension of the test developed by Phillips et al. (2015) to a panel setting in order to exploit the large cross-sectional dimension of our international dataset. Statistically significant periods of exuberance are found in most countries. Moreover, we find strong evidence of the emergence of an unprecedented period of exuberance in the early 2000s that eventually collapsed around 2006 −07, preceding the 2008 −09 global recession. We examine whether macro and financial variables help to predict (in-sample) episodes of exuberance in housing markets. Long-term interest rates, credit growth and global economic conditions are found to be among the best predictors. We conclude that global factors (partly) explain the synchronization of exuberance episodes that we detect in the data in the 2000s.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We complement the Dallas Fed dataset with housing rents from the OECD for 16 of the 22 countries for which there is consistent data over the same sample period (Girouard et al. 2006).

  2. Mildly explosive behavior is modeled by an autoregressive process with a root that exceeds unity, but remains within the vicinity of one. This represents a small departure from martingale behavior, but is consistent with the submartingale property often used in the rational bubbles literature (see Section “The Univariate SADF and GSADF Procedures” for further details). Phillips and Magdalinos (2007a, b) and Magdalinos (2012) provide a large sample asymptotic theory for this class of processes that enables econometric inference in this case, unlike for purely explosive processes.

  3. The SADF and GSADF tests better detect mildly explosive behavior in time series data than standard methods such as unit root/cointegration tests (Diba and Grossman 1988), but also variance bound tests (LeRoy 1981; Shiller 1981), specification tests (West 1987), and Chow and CUSUM-type tests (Homm and Breitung 2012). A few studies have implemented these techniques in the context of housing markets (Phillips and Yu 2011; Yiu et al. 2013), but only on domestic and not across international markets.

  4. The existing empirical evidence points out that house prices may temporarily deviate from fundamentals (e.g., the time series and cross-section evidence in Clayton 1996; Hwang and Quigley 2006; Mikhed and Zemcik 2009a; Capozza et al. 2004; Adams and Fuss 2010) and the importance of the bank lending channel in housing (e.g., Mian and Sufi 2009; Pavlov and Wachter 2011; Berkovec et al. 2012).

  5. The asset-pricing approach to housing builds on the extensive rational bubbles literature. See, e.g., the seminal work of Blanchard (1979) and Blanchard and Watson (1982).

  6. We implicitly use this demand equation for rental housing to relate house prices to personal disposable income. In doing so, however, the definition of fundamentals has to be augmented with a particular specification of the rental housing demand.

  7. Log-linear approximations are also commonly used but may be less relevant with nonstationary data where sample means do not converge to population constants (Campbell and Shiller 1988; Campbell et al. 1997). Further discussion on these approximations can be found in Lee and Phillips (2011). In this paper, we work with levels. Using logs does not qualitatively alter the results.

  8. For the standard dividend discount model in which the payoff stream \(\left \{ X_{t}\right \}_{t=1}^{\infty }\) grows at a constant rate, see Gordon and Shapiro (1956). Blanchard and Watson (1982) and Campbell et al. (1997) examine more general processes for \(\left \{ X_{t}\right \}_{t=1}^{\infty }\).

  9. For a discussion of a more general solution with log-linear approximation methods, see Engsted et al. (2012).

  10. The price-to-income ratio in particular provides a metric of house prices relative to the ability of households to pay (Himmelberg et al. 2005; Girouard et al. 2006) and, thus, it incorporates one of the key determinants of the demand for housing.

  11. We note that, apart from income and rent, there are other fundamental drivers of housing prices, such as the cost of foregone interest, the cost of property taxes and maintenance costs (see, e.g., the discussion in Himmelberg et al. 2005). Lack of consistent and comparable data across countries for fundamental factors like this remains a limitation for applied research in housing.

  12. The recursive representation of the discount rate is equivalent to the following alternative characterization,

  13. For a discussion on the characteristics of the volatility process in house prices with data from the International House Price Database see Mack and Martínez-García (2012). These authors provide empirical evidence of an increase in house price volatility that is consistent with the stylized implications of declining discount rates laid out here.

  14. We can also show that the persistence term \(\frac {\theta _{t-1}}{\theta _{t-2}}\) in the house price equation is bounded below by g and above by \(g^{k^{\prime }-k}\) over the period from t up to \(t+k^{\prime }\).

  15. For the numerical example, we set ρ=0.02, g=1.0002774397, \(k^{\prime }-k=70\) and \(\sigma _{\epsilon }^{2}=0.01\).

  16. Evans (1991) shows using simulation methods that standard unit root and cointegration tests cannot reject the null of no explosive behavior when such periodically collapsing episodes are present in the data. Price increases during the boom followed by a decline during the correction phase make it look like a mean-reverting (stationary) process. Intuitively, this is the reason why many non-recursive unit root tests wrongly suggest that processes that incorporate periodically collapsing boom-bust episodes are stationary—as indicated by Evans (1991).

  17. These approaches are used to test a permanent change in persistence from a random walk to an explosive process. As a consequence, they perform well only in cases where the series becomes explosive but never bursts in-sample.

  18. The Backward SADF (BSADF) statistic relates to the GSADF statistic as follows,

  19. Exploring alternative minimum window sizes can be computationally demanding since for each r 0 new critical values must be computed.

  20. The choice of a fixed lag length is appealing because it allows us to employ a recursive least squares approach, which substantially reduces the computational cost of estimation.

  21. Using asymptotic critical values doesn’t qualitatively change our results. Asymptotic values are provided in Phillips et al. (2015).

  22. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for motivating this extension.

  23. National house price indices aggregate across dwelling types and diverse locations within a country which may impact the performance of the econometric tests described in the previous section. In order to examine the effect of aggregation on the properties of the SADF and GSADF tests, we have conducted a large simulation experiment based on the S&P/Case-Shiller 10-City Composite Home Price Index and its constituent series. The results of the simulation experiment (which are available upon request from the authors) illustrate that aggregating lowers the power of both the SADF and GSADF tests. The effect is much larger for the SADF test than for the GSADF test, which gives us another reason to prefer the latter in our econometric strategy.

  24. The variability of E X U t within a country is limited because the GSADF methodology does not detect many episodes of exuberance. An advantage of the pooled probit model is that, by incorporating the full variability across countries, it increases the number of episodes leading to more tightly identified results.

  25. While the Stone-Geary reduces to the Cobb-Douglas utility function whenever the parameters 𝜃 H and 𝜃 C are both set equal to zero, the specification permits both the rental rate elasticity and the income elasticity to vary with both rental rates and income—unlike the Cobb-Douglas where both elasticities are constant or the constant elasticity of substitution utility function for which the income elasticity is constant.

References

  • Adams, Z., & Fuss, R (2010). Macroeconomic determinants of international housing markets. Journal of Housing Economics, 19(1), 38–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agnello, L., & Schuknecht, L (2011). Booms and busts in housing markets: determinants and implications. Journal of Housing Economics, 20(3), 171–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • André, C., Gil-Alana, L.A., & Gupta, R (2014). Testing for persistence in housing price-to-income and price-to-rent ratios in 16 OECD countries. Applied Economics, 46(18), 2127–2138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berkovec, J., Chang, Y., & McManus, D.A (2012). Alternative lending channels and the crisis in U.S. housing markets. Real Estate Economics, 40(s1), S8–S31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B.S. (2005). The global saving glut and the U.S. current account deficit. At the Sandridge Lecture. Richmond, Virginia: Virginia Association of Economists. http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2005/200503102/.

  • Bhargava, A. (1986). On the theory of testing for unit roots in observed time series. Review of Economic Studies, 53(3), 369–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O.J. (1979). Speculative bubbles, crashes and rational expectations. Economics Letters, 3(4), 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O.J., & Watson, M.W. (1982). Bubbles, rational expectations, and financial markets. In Wachtel, P. (Ed.) Crises in the Economic and Financial Structure (pp. 295–315). Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

  • Busetti, F., & Taylor, A.M.R. (2004). Tests of stationarity against a change in persistence. Journal of Econometrics, 123, 33–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J.Y., & Shiller, R.J. (1987). Cointegration and tests of present value models. Journal of Political Economy, 95(5), 1062–1088.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J.Y., & Shiller, R.J. (1988). The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Review of Financial Studies, 1(3), 195–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J.Y., Lo, A.W., & MacKinlay, A.C. (1997). The Econometrics of Financial Markets. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

  • Capozza, D.R., Hendershott, P.H., & Mack, C. (2004). An anatomy of price dynamics in illiquid markets: analysis and evidence from local housing markets. Real Estate Economics, 32(1), 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case, K.E., & Shiller, R.J. (2003). Is there a bubble in the housing market? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 34(2), 299–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Y. (2004). Bootstrap unit root tests in panels with cross-sectional dependency. Journal of Econometrics, 120(2), 263–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, S.-S. (2009). Predicting the bear stock market: macroeconomic variables as leading indicators. Journal of Banking & Finance, 33(2), 211–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clayton, J. (1996). Rational expectations, market fundamentals and housing price volatility. Real Estate Economics, 24(4), 441–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diba, B.T., & Grossman, H.I (1988). Explosive rational bubbles in stock prices? American Economic Review, 78(3), 520–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engsted, T., Pedersen, T.Q., & Tanggaard, C. (2012). The log-linear return approximation, bubbles, and predictability. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 47(3), 643–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G.W. (1991). Pitfalls in testing for explosive bubbles in asset prices. American Economic Review, 81(4), 922–930.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flood, R.P., & Hodrick, R.J. (1990). On testing for speculative bubbles. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(2), 85–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girouard, N., Kennedy, M., Van den Noord, P., & André, C. (2006). Recent house price developments: the role of fundamentals. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, NO 475. Paris: OECD Publishing.

  • Gordon, M.J., & Shapiro, E. (1956). Capital equipment analysis: the required rate of profit. Management Science, 3(1), 102–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, V., Mack, A., & Martínez-García, E. (2014). A new database of global economic indicators. The Journal of Economic and Social Measurement, 39 (3), 163–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hiebert, P., & Sydow, M. (2011). What drives returns to euro area housing? evidence from a dynamic dividend-discount model. Journal of Urban Economics, 70 (2–3), 88–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Himmelberg, C., Mayer, C., & Sinai, T. (2005). Assessing high house prices: bubbles, fundamentals and misperceptions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 67–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Homm, U., & Breitung, J. (2012). Testing for speculative bubbles in stock markets: a comparison of alternative methods. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 10(1), 198–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hott, C., & Monnin, P. (2008). Fundamental real estate prices: an empirical estimation with international data. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 36(4), 427–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hwang, M., & Quigley, J.M. (2006). Economic fundamentals in local housing markets: evidence from U.S. metropolitan regions. Journal of Regional Science, 46 (3), 425–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Im, K.S., Pesaran, M.H., & Shin, Y. (2003). Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 115(1), 53–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilian, L. (2009). Not all oil price shocks are alike: disentangling demand and supply shocks in the crude oil market. American Economic Review, 99(3), 1053–1069.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, J.-Y. (2000). Detection of change in persistence of a linear time series. Journal of Econometrics, 95(1), 97–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, J.-Y., Belaire-Franch, J., & Badillo Amador, R. (2002). Corrigendum to “detection of change in persistence of a linear time series”. Journal of Econometrics, 109(2), 389–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, P.R., & Milesi-Ferretti, G.M. (2003). International financial integration. IMF Staff Papers, 50, 82–113. Special Issue.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J.H., & Phillips, P.C.B. (2011). Asset pricing with financial bubble risk: Working paper, Yale University.

  • LeRoy, S.F. (1981). The present-value relation: tests based on implied variance bounds. Econometrica, 49, 555–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LeRoy, S.F. (2004). Rational exuberance. Journal of Economic Literature, 42 (3), 783–804.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mack, A., & Martínez-García, E. (2011). A cross-country quarterly database of real house prices: a methodological note. Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Papers, No. 99. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.

  • Mack, A., & Martínez-García, E. (2012). Increased real house price volatility signals break from Great Moderation. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Letter, 7(1).

  • Maddala, G.S., & Wu, S (1999). A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and a new simple test. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 61 (S1), 631–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magdalinos, T. (2012). Mildly explosive autoregression under weak and strong dependence. Journal of Econometrics, 169(2), 179–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, C. (2011). Housing bubbles: a survey. Annual Review of Economics, 3, 559–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mian, A., & Sufi, A (2009). The consequences of mortgage credit expansion: evidence from the U.S. mortgage default crisis. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(4), 1449–1496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mikhed, V., & Zemcik, P. (2009a). Do house prices reflect fundamentals? aggregate and panel data evidence. Journal of Housing Economics, 18(2), 140–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mikhed, V., & Zemcik, P. (2009b). Testing for bubbles in housing markets: a panel data approach. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 38(4), 366–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng, S., & Perron, P. (1995). Unit root tests in ARMA models with data-dependent methods for the selection of the truncation lag. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 90(429), 268–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng, S., & Perron, P. (2001). Lag length selection and the construction of unit root tests with good size and power. Econometrica, 69(6), 1519–1554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nyberg, H. (2013). Predicting bear and bull stock markets with dynamic binary time series models. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(9), 3351–3363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pavlov, A., & Wachter, S. (2011). Subprime lending and real estate prices. Real Estate Economics, 39(1), 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, P.C.B., & Magdalinos, T. (2007a). Limit theory for moderate deviations from a unit root. Journal of Econometrics, 136(1), 115–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, P.C.B., & Magdalinos, T. (2007b). Limit theory for moderate deviations from a unit root under weak dependence. In Phillips, G.D.A., & Tzavalis, E. (Eds.) The Refinement of Econometric Estimation and Test Procedures: Finite Sample and Asymptotic Analysis (pp. 123–162). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Phillips, P.C.B., & Yu, J. (2011). Dating the timeline of financial bubbles during the subprime crisis. Quantitative Economics, 2(3), 455–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, P.C.B., Shi, S.-P., & Yu, J. (2012). Testing for multiple bubbles. Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers, No 1843. Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics: Yale University.

  • Phillips, P.C.B., Wu, Y., & Yu, J. (2011). Explosive behavior in the 1990s Nasdaq: when did exuberance escalate asset values? International Economic Review, 52(1), 201–226.

  • Phillips, P.C.B., Shi, S.-P., & Yu, J. (2015). Testing for multiple bubbles: historical episodes of exuberance and collapse in the S&P 500: International Economic Review. forthcoming.

  • Rousová, L., & Van den Noord, P. (2011). Predicting peaks and troughs in real house prices. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No 882. Paris: OECD Publishing.

  • Sargent, T.J. (1987). Macroeconomic Theory, 2nd. Boston: Academic Press.

  • Shiller, R.J. (1981). Do stock prices move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in dividends? American Economic Review, 71(3), 421–436.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R.J. (2015). Irrational Exuberance (Revised and Expanded Third Edition): Princeton University Press.

  • West, K.D. (1987). A specification test for speculative bubbles. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(3), 553–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yiu, M.S., Yu, J., & Jin, L. (2013). Detecting bubbles in Hong Kong residential property market. Journal of Asian Economics, 28, 115–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank María Teresa Martínez García and Itamar Caspi for providing helpful assistance and suggestions. We acknowledge the support of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. All remaining errors are ours alone. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Enrique Martínez-García.

Additional information

The International House Price Database can be accessed online at http://www.dallasfed.org/institute/houseprice/index.cfm. An earlier version of the paper circulated under the title “Monitoring Housing Markets for Periods of Exuberance. An Application of the Phillips et al. (2012, 2013) GSADF Test on the Dallas Fed International House Price Database.”

Appendix A: Demand Equation for Rental Housing

Appendix A: Demand Equation for Rental Housing

Consider the maximization of the Stone-Geary utility function with housing units rented, H t , and consumption of other goods, C t , i.e.,Footnote 25

$$U\left( H_{t},C_{t}\right) =\left( H_{t}-\theta_{H}\right)^{\alpha} \left( C_{t}-\theta_{C}\right)^{1-\alpha}, 0<\alpha<1, $$

subject to the intratemporal budget constraint,

$$C_{t}+x_{t}H_{t}=Y_{t}, $$

where the price of the consumption good is normalized to 1. X t x t H t is the housing rents—rental expenditures—paid and x t the rental rate per unit rented, Y t refers to disposable income, and α, 𝜃 H and 𝜃 C are preference parameters.

From first-order conditions, the Stone-Geary utility function subject to the standard intratemporal budget constraint gives a linear expenditure system where the demand for rental housing takes the following form:

$$ H_{t}=\theta_{H}+\frac{\alpha}{x_{t}}\left( Y_{t}-x_{t}\theta_{H}-\theta_{C}\right), $$
(38)

or in expenditure terms,

$$ X_{t}\equiv x_{t}H_{t}=\alpha Y_{t}+\left( 1-\alpha\right) \theta_{H} x_{t}-\alpha\theta_{C}. $$
(39)

Under the assumption that in equilibrium the units rented are constant (i.e., H t =H) and normalized to 1, the demand equation that determines housing rents in Eq. 39 reduces to an affine transformation of disposable income (Y t ), i.e.,

$$ X_{t}=x_{t}=\theta_{F}+\delta Y_{t+1}, $$
(40)

where \(\delta \equiv \frac {\alpha }{1-\left (1-\alpha \right ) \theta _{H}}\) and \(\theta _{F}\equiv -\frac {\alpha }{1-\left (1-\alpha \right ) \theta _{H}} \theta _{C}\).

B The Panel GSADF Test

The bootstrap procedure consists of the following steps:

  1. 1.

    For each country, impose the null hypothesis of a unit root and fit the restricted ADF regression equation,

    $${\Delta} y_{i,t}=a_{i,r_{1},r_{2}}+ \sum\nolimits_{j=1}^{k} \psi_{i,r_{1},r_{2}}^{j}{\Delta} y_{i,t-j}+\epsilon_{i,t}, $$

    to obtain coefficient estimates (\(\widehat {a}_{i,r_{1},r_{2}}\), and \(\widehat {\psi }_{i,r_{1},r_{2}}^{j}\) for \(j=1,\dots ,k\)) and residuals (\(\widehat {\epsilon }_{i}\)).

  2. 2.

    Create a residual matrix with typical element \(\widehat {\epsilon }_{t,i}\).

  3. 3.

    In order to preserve the covariance structure of the error term, generate bootstrap residuals, \(\epsilon _{i,t}^{b}\), by sampling with replacement draws from the residual matrix.

  4. 4.

    Use the bootstrap residuals and the estimated coefficients to recursively generate bootstrap samples for first differences,

    $${\Delta} y_{i,t}^{b}=\widehat{a}_{i,r_{1},r_{2}}+ \sum\nolimits_{j=1}^{k} \widehat{\psi}_{i,r_{1},r_{2}}^{j}{\Delta} y_{i,t-j}^{b}+\epsilon_{i,t}^{b}, $$

    and for levels,

    $$y_{i,t}^{b}= {\displaystyle\sum\nolimits_{p=1}^{t}} {\Delta} y_{i,p}^{b}. $$
  5. 5.

    Compute the sequence of panel BSADF statistics and the panel GSADF statistic for \(y_{i,t}^{b}\).

  6. 6.

    Repeat steps (3) to (5) a large number of times to obtain the empirical distribution of the test statistics under the null of a unit root.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pavlidis, E., Yusupova, A., Paya, I. et al. Episodes of Exuberance in Housing Markets: In Search of the Smoking Gun. J Real Estate Finan Econ 53, 419–449 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-015-9531-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-015-9531-2

Keywords

JEL Classification:

Navigation