Skip to main content
Log in

The role of information transparency in the product market: an examination of the sustainability of profitability differences

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We investigate whether information transparency at the industry level is associated with the sustainability of within-industry differences in profitability. Since competition leads to the elimination of intra-industry profitability differences, this investigation provides evidence on whether competitors act on information about rivals. Using an industry-level transparency measure that integrates corporate reporting by firm managers, private information search and communication by analysts, and information dissemination by the media, we find that transparency is associated with faster reductions in within-industry profitability differences. Using aggregate financial statement data for public and private firms provided by the U.S. Census Bureau, we further find that differences in profitability between public and private firms are less persistent when public firms’ profitability exceeds private firms’ profitability, consistent with theoretical and anecdotal arguments that public firms are at a competitive disadvantage because they are required to be more transparent than private counterparts. Our results are robust to the use of local newspaper closures and mergers as exogenous shocks to transparency. Collectively, these findings indicate that information transparency facilitates competition, leading to the erosion of profitability differences within an industry. We further demonstrate that information transparency is positively associated with the degree to which competitors enter or exit an industry in anticipation of changes in the industry’s profitability outlook.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Brozen 1971a, 1971b; Qualls 1974; Mueller 1977, 1986, 1990; Jacobsen 1988; Waring 1996; McGahan and Porter 1997, 1999, 2003; Roberts 1999; Roberts and Dowling 2002

  2. Bain 1951, 1956; Williamson 1963; Mann 1966; Brozen 1971a, 1971b; Qualls 1974; Mueller 1977, 1986, 1990; Waring 1996; Roberts 1999; Roberts and Dowling 2002; Carlton 2004; McAfee et al. 2004

  3. We use NAICS codes because the data from the U.S. Census Bureau that we use for additional analysis relies on the NAICS codes. Our results are robust to the use of two-digit SIC codes.

  4. Stigler (1963) and Qualls (1974) argue that highly concentrated industries experience a slower mean convergence of profitability. Similar effects apply to R&D and advertising investment, which create potential innovations and product loyalty (Roberts 1999; Bunch and Smiley 1992). Additionally, employees’ skill level represents industry complexity, one of the main informational impediments to imitation (Mansfield et al. 1981; Lippman and Rumelt 1982; Mansfield 1985; Dierickx and Cool 1989). On the other hand, the number of firms and capital intensity are normally treated as factors that expedite the convergence process, because they possibly increase competition and the efficiency of capital utilization (Waring 1996).

  5. Mas-Colell (1998) points to perfect knowledge and market transparency as key assumptions to reach market equilibrium (p. 18). Stiglitz (1985) argues that “when one of the central pieces (the assumption of perfect information) is removed, the structure [of perfect market competition] collapses” (p. 26). Salop (1976) and Stiglitz (1989) argue that imperfect information can contribute to market power, which works against perfectly competitive outcomes. In particular, Salop (1976) argues, “because imperfect [and costly] information gives firms market power at least in the short run and often in the long run as well ... the relevant market structure with imperfect information is not perfect competition but rather [close to] monopolistic competition” (p. 240). Allen (2014) points to the fact that producers undergo costly information searches to underscore the economic importance of information for product market competition.

  6. “Conceptually, DQ differs from existing disclosure measures in that it captures the “fineness” of data and is based on a comprehensive set of accounting line items in annual reports” (Chen et al. 2015, p.1019).

  7. Forecasts of long-term earnings growth provide crucial forward-looking and value-relevant information (Da and Warachka 2011).

  8. “With weekday circulation of about six million copies, these four newspapers account for 11% of total daily circulation in the United States” (Fang and Peress 2009, p. 2027).

  9. We restrict this search to firms ranked in the top 20% of sales for the industry each year, which allows us to sample economically significant portions of each industry while economizing on labor-intensive searches. In addition, to ensure the accuracy of our news search, as suggested by the Factiva representatives, we further narrow the results to news articles in which the leading paragraph contains the full company name and the word count is greater than 50.

  10. To ensure reasonable estimates of ROA and its components, we require each firm to have at least $10 million in revenue.

  11. Our sample period starts from 1981 because it’s “the first year in which I/B/E/S consistently provides analysts’ forecasts of long-term earnings growth” (Dechow et al. 2000, p.13).

  12. The QFR program collects and publishes quarterly aggregate statistics on the financial results and position of U.S. corporations in specific industries. The data can be found on the Census website: https://www.census.gov/econ/qfr/historic.html. The QFR target population consists of all corporations engaged primarily in manufacturing with total assets of $250,000 or more and all corporations engaged primarily in mining, wholesale trade, retail trade, information, or professional and technical services (except legal services) industries with total assets of $50 million or more. QFR uses a mail-out/mail-back survey to the selected firms. Nearly all corporations whose operations are within scope of the QFR and have total assets of $250 million or more are included in the sample pool, and random samples are selected from the eligible units in the remaining strata. The average response rate of the whole sample is higher than 60%, with greater response rates from larger firms. The QFR survey is conducted on a calendar quarter basis. Companies report their financial data for each of their fiscal quarters and are included in the calculation of the calendar quarter estimates of QFR depending on the month their books are closed. To merge the Compustat data with the QFR database, we first translate the historical NAICS code of each company to the 2007 NAICS code by using concordances of NAICS provided by the Census Bureau. We then translate the 2007 NAICS code to the QFR industry classification using a mapping between the two provided by the QFR program.

  13. A recent survey by the Readership Institute of Northwestern University shows that local papers have much higher local readership than other papers. In 2006, 71% of respondents read a local paper, whereas 24% read a paper other than (or in addition to) a local paper.

  14. See https://www.usnewsdeserts.com/.

  15. The average percentage of newspaper reduction for the industry captures both the average percentage of newspaper reduction for individual firms within the industry and the proportion of firms that experienced such newspaper reductions. For example, the 1% reduction in newspaper coverage for the industry can be due to 100% of firms within the industry experiencing a 1% reduction in their newspaper coverage, 1% of firms within the industry experiencing a 100% reduction in newspaper coverage, or everything else between these two extremes.

  16. Statistics of U.S. Businesses (SUSB) Employment Change Data Tables are available through the following link: https://www.census.gov/programs-surveys/susb/data/tables.2016.html

  17. For example, a new set of firms could emerge as the most and least profitable with the exactly the same profit differential as the most and least profitable firms from the previous year.

  18. We find that the correlation between industry-year earnings persistence and FERC is insignificant. Thus, the relation between FERC and the persistence of within-industry profitability differences is unlikely to be mechanical.

References

  • Akamah, Herita. (2016). Strategic non-disclosure of major customer identity. Working Paper.

  • Ali, Ashiq, Sandy Klasa, and Eric Yeung. (2009). The limitations of industry concentration measures constructed with Compustat data: Implications for finance research. Review of Financial Studies 22: 3839–3871.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, Treb. (2014). Information frictions in trade. Econometrica 82 (6): 2041–2083.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baginski, Stephen P., Kenneth S. Lorek, G. Lee Willinger, and Bruce C. Branson. (1999). The relationship between economic characteristics and alternative annual earnings persistence measures. The Accounting Review 74 (1): 105–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bain, Joe S. (1951). Relation of profit rate to industry concentration: American manufacturing, 1936–1940. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 65 (3): 293–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bain, Joe S. (1956). Barriers to new competition, their character and consequences in manufacturing industries. Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barth, Mary E., Yaniv Konchitchki, and Wayne R. Landsman. (2013). Cost of capital and earnings transparency. Journal of Accounting and Economics 55 (2–3): 206–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, Philip G. (2011). Challenges and opportunities in disclosure research—A discussion of ‘the financial reporting environment: Review of the recent literature’. Journal of Accounting and Economics 51 (1–2): 204–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, Philip G., Jung Ho Choi, and Sorabh Tomar. (2021). Breaking it down: economic consequences of disaggregated cost disclosures. Working Paper.

  • Berger, Philip G., and Rebecca N. Hann. (2007). Segment profitability and the proprietary and agency costs of disclosure. The Accounting Review 82 (4): 869–906.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, Darren. (2016). Is the risk of product market predation a cost of disclosure? Journal of Accounting and Economics 62 (2–3): 305–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beyer, Anne, Daniel A. Cohen, Thomas Z. Lys, and Beverly R. Walther. (2010). The financial reporting environment: Review of the recent literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics 50 (2–3): 296–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, Matthew. (2009). Essential Economics: An A to Z guide (2nd ed.). New York: Bloomberg Press.

  • Bou, Juan Carlos, and Albert Satorra. (2007). The persistence of abnormal returns at industry and firm levels: Evidence from Spain. Strategic Management Journal 28 (7): 707–722.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradshaw, Mark T., Yonca Ertimur, and Patricia C. O'Brien. (2017). Financial analysts and their contribution to well-functioning capital markets. Foundations and Trends in Accounting 11 (3): 119–191.

  • Brown, James R., and Gustav Martinsson. (2019). Does transparency stifle or facilitate innovation? Management Science 65 (4): 1600–1623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brozen, Yale. (1970). The antitrust task force deconcentration recommendation. The Journal of Law and Economics 13 (2): 279–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brozen, Yale. (1971a). Bain's concentration and rates of return revisited. The Journal of Law and Economics 14 (2): 351–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brozen, Yale. (1971b). The persistence of" high rates of return" in high-stable concentration industries. The Journal of Law and Economics 14 (2): 501–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bunch, David S., and Robert Smiley. (1992). Who deters entry? Evidence on the use of strategic entry deterrents. The Review of Economics and Statistics 74 (3): 509–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bushman, Robert M., Joseph D. Piotroski, and Abbie J. Smith. (2004). What determines corporate transparency? Journal of Accounting Research 42 (2): 207–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cage, Julia, Nicolas Herve, and Marie-Luce Viaud. (2019). The production of information in an online world: Is copy right? Working Paper.

  • Cao, Sean Shun, Guang Ma, Jennifer Wu Tucker, and Chi Wan. (2018). Technological peer pressure and product disclosure. The Accounting Review 93 (6): 95–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlton, Dennis W. (2004). Why barriers to entry are barriers to understanding. American Economic Review 94 (2): 466–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Shuping, Bin Miao, and Terry Shevlin. (2015). A new measure of disclosure quality: The level of disaggregation of accounting data in annual reports. Journal of Accounting Research 53 (5): 1017–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, Qiang, Du Fei, Xin Wang, and Yutao Wang. (2016). Seeing is believing: Analysts’ corporate site visits. Review of Accounting Studies 21 (4): 1245–1286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, Jong-Hag, Linda A. Myers, Yoonseok Zang, and David A. Ziebart. (2011). Do management EPS forecasts allow returns to reflect future earnings? Implications for the continuation of management’s quarterly earnings guidance. Review of Accounting Studies 16 (1): 143–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Da, Zhi, and Mitch Warachka. (2011). The disparity between long-term and short-term forecasted earnings growth. Journal of Financial Economics 100 (2): 424–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darrough, Masako N., and Neal M. Stoughton. (1990). Financial disclosure policy in an entry game. Journal of Accounting and Economics 12 (1–3): 219–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechow, Patricia M., Amy P. Hutton, and Richard G. Sloan. (2000). The relation between analysts' forecasts of long-term earnings growth and stock price performance following equity offerings. Contemporary Accounting Research 17 (1): 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dierickx, Ingemar, and Karel Cool. (1989). Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage. Management Science 35 (12): 1504–1511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drake, Michael S., Nicholas M. Guest, and Brady J. Twedt. (2014). The media and mispricing: The role of the business Press in the Pricing of accounting information. The Accounting Review 89 (5): 1673–1701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duarte, Jefferson, Xi Han, Jarrad Harford, and Lance Young. (2008). Information asymmetry, information dissemination and the effect of regulation FD on the cost of capital. Journal of Financial Economics 87 (1): 24–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyck, Alexander, Adair Morse, and Luigi Zingales. (2010). Who blows the whistle on corporate fraud? The Journal of Finance 65 (6): 2213–2253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dye, Ronald A., and Sri S. Sridhar. (1995). Industry-wide disclosure dynamics. Journal of Accounting Research 33 (1): 157–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easton, Peter D., and Trevor S. Harris. (1991). Earnings as an explanatory variable for returns. Journal of Accounting Research 29 (1): 19–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engelberg, Joseph. (2008). Costly information processing: Evidence from earnings announcement. Working Paper.

  • Engelberg, Joseph E., and Christopher A. Parsons. (2011). The causal impact of media in financial markets. The Journal of Finance 66 (1): 67–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erdal, Ivar John. (2011). Where does the news come from? News flow between print newspapers, broadcasting and the web in Norway. Working Paper.

  • Fang, Lily, and Joel Peress. (2009). Media coverage and the cross-section of stock returns. The Journal of Finance 64 (5): 2023–2052.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feltham, G.A., and J.Z. Xie. (1992). Voluntary financial disclosure in an entry game with continua of types. Contemporary Accounting Research 9 (1): 46–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Firth, Michael, Kailong Wang, and Sonia M.L. Wong. (2015). Corporate transparency and the impact of investor sentiment on stock prices. Management Science 61 (7): 1630–1647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flåm, Sjur Didrik. (1995). Learning competitive market balance. Economic Theory 6 (3): 511–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis, Jere R., Shawn Huang, Inder K. Khurana, and Raynolde Pereira. 2009. Does corporate transparency contribute to efficient resource allocation? Journal of Accounting Research 47 (4): 943–989.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, Richard, and Xu Li. (2004). Characteristics of a firm's information environment and the information asymmetry between insiders and outsiders. Journal of Accounting and Economics 37 (2): 229–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelb, David S., and Paul Zarowin. (2002). Corporate disclosure policy and the informativeness of stock prices. Review of Accounting Studies 7 (1): 33–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigler, Frank, John Hughes, and Judy Rayburn. (1994). International accounting standards for line-of-business reporting and oligopoly competition. Contemporary Accounting Research 11 (1): 619–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, Stephen, and James D. Omartian. (2019). Public firm presence, financial reporting, and the decline of US manufacturing. Working Paper.

  • Gschwandtner, Adelina. (2005). Profit persistence in the ‘very’ long run: Evidence from survivors and exiters. Applied Economics 37 (7): 793–806.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurun, Umit G., and Alexander W. Butler. (2012). Don't believe the hype: Local media slant, local advertising, and firm value. The Journal of Finance 67 (2): 561–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayes, Rachel M., and Russell Lundholm. (1996). Segment reporting to the capital market in the presence of a competitor. Journal of Accounting Research 34 (2): 261–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, Mary Stanford. (1998). The association between competition and managers' business segment reporting decisions. Journal of Accounting Research 36 (1): 111–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen, Robert. (1988). The persistence of abnormal returns. Strategic Management Journal 9 (5): 415–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kessides, Ioannis N. 1990. Towards a testable model of entry: A study of the US manufacturing industries. Economica 57 (226): 219–238.

  • Kessides, Ioannis N. (1991). Entry and market contestability: The evidence from the United States. In Entry and Market Contestability: An International Comparison, eds. Paul A. Geroski and Joachim Schwalbach, 23–48. Cambridge: Blackwell.

  • Kim, Min, Derrald Stice, Han Stice, and Roger M. White. (2021). Stop the presses! Or wait, we might need them: Firm response to local newspaper closures and layoffs. Journal of Corporate Finance 69. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2021.102035

  • Lang, Mark, and Edward Sul. (2014). Linking industry concentration to proprietary costs and disclosure: Challenges and opportunities. Journal of Accounting and Economics 58 (2–3): 265–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lev, Baruch. (1983). Some economic determinants of time-series properties of earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 5 (1): 31–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Xi. (2010). The impacts of product market competition on the quantity and quality of voluntary disclosures. Review of Accounting Studies 15 (3): 663–711.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lippman, S.A., and R.P. Rumelt. (1982). Uncertain imitability: An analysis of interfirm differences in efficiency under competition. The Bell Journal of Economics 13 (2): 418–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundholm, Russell, and Linda A. Myers. (2002). Bringing the future forward: The effect of disclosure on the returns-earnings relation. Journal of Accounting Research 40 (3): 809–839.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mann, H. Michael. (1966). Seller concentration, barriers to entry, and rates of return in thirty industries, 1950-1960. The Review of Economics and Statistics 48 (3): 296–307.

  • Mansfield, Edwin. (1985). How rapidly does new industrial technology leak out? The Journal of Industrial Economics 34 (2): 217–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, Edwin, Mark Schwartz, and Samuel Wagner. (1981). Imitation costs and patents: An empirical study. The Economic Journal 91 (364): 907–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell, Andreu. (1998). On the theory of perfect competition. Econometric Society Monographs 29: 16–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAfee, Preston R., Hugo M. Mialon, and Michael A. Williams. (2004). What is a barrier to entry? American Economic Review 94 (2): 461–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGahan, Anita M., and Michael E. Porter. (1997). How much does industry matter, really? Strategic Management Journal 18 (S1): 15–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGahan, Anita M., and Michael E. Porter. (1999). The persistence of shocks to profitability. Review of Economics and Statistics 81 (1): 143–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGahan, Anita M., and Michael E. Porter. (2003). The emergence and sustainability of abnormal profits. Strategic Organization 1 (1): 79–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, Gregory S. (2006). The press as a watchdog for accounting fraud. Journal of Accounting Research 44 (5): 1001–1033.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, Dennis C. (1977). The persistence of profits above the norm. Economica 44 (176): 369–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, Dennis C. (1986). Profits in the long-run. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, Dennis C. (1990). The dynamics of company profits. An International Comparison. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, Patricia C., and Ravi Bhushan. (1990). Analyst following and institutional ownership. Journal of Accounting Research 28: 55–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park, Jihwon, Jalal Sani, Nemit Shroff, and Hal White. (2019). Disclosure incentives when competing firms have common ownership. Journal of Accounting and Economics 67 (2–3): 387–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pew Research Center: Journalism and Media Staff. (2010). How news happens. A study of the news ecosystem of one American city. https://www.journalism.org/2010/01/11/how-news-happens/. Accessed 16 Aug 2021.

  • Pindyck, Robert S. (1988). Irreversible investment, capacity choice, and the value of the firm. The American Economic Review 78 (5): 969–985.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qualls, David. (1974). Stability and persistence of economic profit margins in highly concentrated industries. Southern Economic Journal 40 (4): 604–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, Peter W. (1999). Product innovation, product–market competition and persistent profitability in the US pharmaceutical industry. Strategic Management Journal 20 (7): 655–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, Peter W., and Grahame R. Dowling. (2002). Corporate reputation and sustained superior financial performance. Strategic Management Journal 23 (12): 1077–1093.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, Joan. (1934). What is perfect competition? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 49 (1): 104–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roychowdhury, Sugata, Nemit Shroff, and Rodrigo S. Verdi. (2019). The effects of financial reporting and disclosure on corporate investment: A review. Journal of Accounting and Economics 68 (2–3): 101–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salop, Steve. (1976). Information and monopolistic competition. American Economic Review 66 (2): 240–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegfried, John J., and Laurie Beth Evans. (1994). Empirical studies of entry and exit: A survey of the evidence. Review of Industrial Organization 9 (2): 121–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soliman, Mark T. (2008). The use of DuPont analysis by market participants. The Accounting Review 83 (3): 823–853.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, George J. (1957). Perfect competition, historically contemplated. Journal of Political Economy 65 (1): 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, George J. (1963). Capital and rates of return in manufacturing industries. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1985). Information and economic analysis: A perspective. Economic Journal 95: 21–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1989). Imperfect information in the product market. Handbook of Industrial Organization 1: 769–847.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tetlock, Paul C., Maytal Saar-Tsechansky, and Sofus Macskassy. (2008). More than words: Quantifying language to measure firms' fundamentals. The Journal of Finance 63 (3): 1437–1467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verrecchia, Robert E. (1983). Discretionary disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics 5: 179–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verrecchia, Robert E. (1990). Information quality and discretionary disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics 12 (4): 365–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Villalonga, Belén. (2004). Intangible resources, Tobin’s q, and sustainability of performance differences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 54 (2): 205–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagenhofer, Alfred. (1990). Voluntary disclosure with a strategic opponent. Journal of Accounting and Economics 12 (4): 341–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waring, Geoffrey F. (1996). Industry differences in the persistence of firm-specific returns. The American Economic Review 86 (5): 1253–1265.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, Oliver E. (1963). Selling expense as a barrier to entry. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 77(1): 112–128.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael D. Kimbrough.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 11 Variable Definitions

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Feng, R.(., Kimbrough, M.D. & Wei, S. The role of information transparency in the product market: an examination of the sustainability of profitability differences. Rev Account Stud 27, 668–705 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-021-09626-4

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-021-09626-4

Keywords

JEL classifications

Navigation