Abstract
We argue that scholars in the Austrian tradition of economics should incorporate the notion of a collaborative innovation bloc into their study of spontaneous market orders. We demonstrate how successful entrepreneurship depends on an innovation bloc of this kind, a system of innovation that evolves and within which activity takes place through time. The innovation bloc consists of five pools of economic skills from which people are drawn or recruited to form part of a collaborative team, which is necessary if innovation-based venturing is to flourish. The five skills are entrepreneurs, early- and later-stage-financiers, key personnel, and customers. Through real-world examples, we show how the application of the collaborative innovation bloc perspective could help make Austrian economics more concrete, relevant and persuasive, especially in regard to policy prescriptions.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.


Notes
The EOE perspective shares many features with the more recent literature on entrepreneurial ecosystems (Stam 2015; Autio 2016) and the national system of entrepreneurship approach (Acs et al. 2014), but we can trace its roots back to the works of Swedish economists Johan Åkerman and Erik Dahmén; see Erixon (2011) and Dahmén (1970). While the other perspectives offer valuable insights, they seldom make a clear distinction between actors and institutions, and “the institutional variables that are used, such as technology absorption, gender equality, R&D spending, and depth of capital markets, are not institutional variables; they are outcomes resulting from the evolution of the economic system in a given institutional setup” (Braunerhjelm and Henrekson 2016, p. 101).
Even the holders of knowledge in the skill structure may be unaware that they possess it or be unable to articulate it – even when they are able to use it in the right circumstances (cf. Pongracic 2009, pp. 55–56).
Intertemporal coordination – producing the right consumer goods at the right time – is facilitated by the market’s price system, which communicates the time-preferences of consumers to entrepreneurs, helping to inform their decision of how to allocate resources intertemporally.
See https://www.worker-participation.eu/National-Industrial-Relations/Across-Europe/Collective-Bargaining2 (accessed 21 April 2018).
References
Acs, Z. J., Autio, E., & Szerb, L. (2014). National systems of entrepreneurship: Measurement issues and policy implications. Research Policy, 43(3), 476–494.
Audretsch, D. B., & Thurik, A. R. (2000). Capitalism and democracy in the 21st century: From the managed to the entrepreneurial economy. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10(1), 17–34.
Audretsch, D. B., Carree, M. A., van Stel, A. J., & Thurik, A. R. (2002). Impeded industrial restructuring: The growth penalty. Kyklos, 55(1), 81–97.
Audretsch, D. B., Keilbach, M. C., & Lehmann, E. E. (2006). Entrepreneurship and economic growth. New York: Oxford University Press.
Autio, E. (2016). Entrepreneurship support in Europe: Trends and challenges. Technical report. London: Imperial College.
Bakker, G. (2013). Money for nothing: How firms have financed R&D-projects since the industrial revolution. Research Policy, 42(10), 1793–1814.
Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 893–921.
Begley, T. M., Tan, W.-L., & Schoch, H. (2005). Politico-economic factors associated with interest in starting a business: A multi-country study. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 29(1), 35–55.
Bhidé, A. (2008). The venturesome economy: How innovation sustains prosperity in a more connected world. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Bhidé, A. (2017). Constraining knowledge: Traditions and rules that limit medical innovation. Critical Review, 29(1), 1–33.
Bloom, N., Sadun, R., & van Reenen, J. (2009). Do private equity-owned firms have better management practices? In A. Gurung & J. Lerner (Eds.), The globalization of alternative investments working papers volume 2: The global economic impact of private equity report 2009 (pp. 25–43). Geneva: World Economic Forum.
Boettke, P. J. (2008). Austrian school of economics. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. URL: http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/AustrianSchoolofEconomics.html. Accessed 9 April 2019.
Boettke, P. J., & Coyne, C. J. (2009). Context matters: Institutions and entrepreneurship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 5(3), 135–209.
Böhm-Bawerk, E. (2010 [1891]). The positive theory of capital. Charleston: Nabu Press.
Boldrin, M., & Levine, D. K. (2013). The case against patents. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27(1), 3–22.
Braunerhjelm, P. (2011). Entrepreneurship, innovation and economic growth: Interdependencies, irregularities and regularities. In D. B. Audretsch, O. Falck, & S. Heblich (Eds.), Handbook of research on innovation and entrepreneurship (pp. 161–213). Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Braunerhjelm, P., & Henrekson, M. (2016). An innovation policy framework: Bridging the gap between industrial dynamics and growth. In D. B. Audretsch & A. N. Link (Eds.), Essays in public sector entrepreneurship (pp. 95–130). New York: Springer.
Buchanan, J. M. (1979). What should economists do? Indianapolis: Liberty Press.
Buchanan, J. M., & Vanberg, V. J. (1991). The market as a creative process. Economics & Philosophy, 7(2), 167–186.
Busenitz, L. W., Plummer, L. A., Klotz, A. C., Shahzad, A., & Rhoads, K. (2014). Entrepreneurship research (1985–2009) and the emergence of opportunities. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 38(5), 981–1000.
Carlsson, B. (1999). Small business, entrepreneurship, and industrial dynamics. In Z. J. Acs (Ed.), Are small firms important? Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Chandler, A. D. (1990). Scale and scope: The dynamics of industrial capitalism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Chetty, R., & Saez, E. (2005). Dividend taxes and corporate behavior: Evidence from the 2003 dividend tax cut. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(3), 791–833.
Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.
Conway, P., De Rosa, D., Nicoletti, G., & Steiner, F. (2006). Regulation, competition and productivity convergence. OECD Economics Department Working Paper 509. Paris: OECD.
Cosgel, M., & Klamer, A. (1990). Entrepreneurship as discourse. Mimeo. Storrs: University of Connecticut.
Cumming, D. (2005). Agency costs, institutions, learning, and taxation in venture capital contracting. Journal of Business Venturing, 20(5), 573–622.
Da Rin, M., Nicodano, G., & Sembenelli, A. (2006). Public policy and the creation of active venture capital markets. Journal of Public Economics, 90(8–9), 1699–1723.
Dahmén, E. (1970). Entrepreneurial activity and the development of Swedish industry 1919–1939. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin for the American economic association. [English translation of Dahmén’s doctoral dissertation published in Swedish in 1950.]
Davis, S. J., & Henrekson, M. (1997). Industrial policy, employer size and economic performance in Sweden. In R. B. Freeman, R. Topel, & B. Swedenborg (Eds.), The welfare state in transition (pp. 353–397). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Davis, S. J., & Henrekson, M. (1999). Explaining national differences in the size and industry distribution of employment. Small Business Economics, 12(1), 59–83.
De Clercq, D., & Sapienza, H. J. (2001). The creation of relational rents in venture capitalist–entrepreneur dyads. Venture Capital, 3(2), 107–128.
Delmar, F., & Wennberg, K. (2010). Knowledge intensive entrepreneurship: The birth, growth and demise of entrepreneurial firms. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Dopfer, K., & Potts, J. (2009). On the theory of economic evolution. Evolutionary and Institutional Economic Review, 6(1), 23–44.
Douhan, R., & Henrekson, M. (2010). Entrepreneurship and second-best institutions: Going beyond baumol’s typology. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20(4), 629–643.
Du Rietz, G., Johansson, D., & Stenkula, M. (2015). Swedish capital income taxation (1862–2013). In M. Henrekson & M. Stenkula (Eds.), Swedish taxation: Developments since 1862 (pp. 123–178). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Dyer, J. H., & Singh, H. (1998). The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23(4), 660–679.
Elert, N., & Henrekson, M. (2016). Evasive entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 47(1), 95–113.
Elert, N., & Henrekson, M. (2017). Entrepreneurship and institutions: A bidirectional relationship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 13(3), 191–263.
Elert, N., Henrekson, M., & Stenkula, M. (2017). Institutional reform for innovation and entrepreneurship: An agenda for Europe. Cham, CH and New York, NY: Springer International.
Elert, N., Henrekson, M., & Sanders, M. (2019). The entrepreneurial society: A reform agenda for the European Union. Cham, CH and New York, NY: Springer International.
Eliasson, G. (1996). Firm objectives, controls and organization: The use of information and the transfer of knowledge within the firm. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Eliasson, G. (2000). Industrial policy, competence blocs and the role of science in economic development. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10(1–2), 217–241.
Eliasson, G., & Eliasson, Å. (1996). The biotechnical competence bloc. Revue d’Économie Industrielle, 78(1), 7–26.
Erixon, L. (2011). Development blocks, malinvestment and structural tensions – The Åkerman-Dahmén theory of the business cycle. Journal of Institutional Economics, 7(1), 105–129.
Erixon, F., & Weigel, B. (2016). The innovation illusion: How so little is created by so many working so hard. New Haven: Yale University Press.
European Commission (2015). Upgrading the single market: More opportunities for business and people. Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, The Council, The European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions. https://ec.europa.eu/transparency/regdoc/rep/1/2015/EN/1-2015-550-EN-F1-1.PDF. Accessed 6 December 2016.
European Union (2016). European innovation scoreboard 2016. Brussels: European Commission, Directorate-General for Internal Market, Industry, Entrepreneurship and SMEs.
Fenn, G., Liang, N., & Prowse, S. (1995). The economics of the private equity market. Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Foss, N. J. (1997). Austrian insights and the theory of the firm. In Advances in Austrian economics (vol. 4, pp. 175–198). Bingley, UK: Emerald.
Ghoshal, S., Moran, P., & Almeida-Costa, L. (1995). The essence of the megacorporation: Shared context, not structural hierarchy. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 151(4), 748–759.
Gilson, R. J., & Schizer, D. M. (2003). Understanding venture capital structure: A tax explanation for convertible preferred stock. Harvard Law Review, 116(3), 874–916.
Gompers, P. A., & Lerner, J. (2001). The money of invention: How venture capital creates new wealth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Granstrand, O., & Alänge, S. (1995). The evolution of corporate entrepreneurship in Swedish industry – Was Schumpeter wrong. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 5(2), 133–156.
Grant Thornton. (2016). Konkurrenskraften i svensk ägarbeskattning. Stockholm: Confederation of Swedish Enterprise.
Hall, R. E., & Woodward, S. E. (2010). The burden of the nondiversifiable risk of entrepreneurship. American Economic Review, 100(3), 1163–1194.
Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35(4), 519–530.
Hayek, F. A. (1976). Law, legislation and liberty (Vol. 2: The mirage of social justice). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hayek, F. A. (1988). The fatal conceit: The errors of socialism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Henrekson, M., & Sanandaji, T. (2016). Owner-level taxes and business activity. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 12(1), 1–94.
Henrekson, M., & Sanandaji, T. (2018). Stock option taxation and venture capital activity: A cross-country study. Venture Capital, 20(1), 51–71.
Heyman, F., Norbäck, P. J., Persson, L., & Andersson, F. (2019). Has the Swedish business sector become more entrepreneurial than the U.S. business sector? Research Policy, forthcoming.
Hillman, A. J., Keim, G. D., & Schuler, D. (2004). Corporate political activity: A review and research agenda. Journal of Management, 30(6), 837–857.
Ho, Y.-P., & Wong, P.-K. (2007). Financing, regulatory costs and entrepreneurial propensity. Small Business Economics, 28(2–3), 187–204.
Holmén, M., & Högfeldt, P. (2005). A law and finance analysis of initial public offerings. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13(3), 324–358.
Huizinga, H., Laeven, L., & Nicodeme, G. (2008). Capital structure and international debt shifting. Journal of Financial Economics, 88(1), 80–118.
Johansson, D. (2009). The theory of the experimentally organized economy and competence blocs: An introduction. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20(2), 185–201.
Jorgenson, D. W., & Landau, R. (Eds.). (1993). Tax reform and the cost of capital. An international comparison. Washington, D.C.: Brookings.
Kasper, W., Streit, M. E., & Boettke, P. J. (2014). Institutional economics: Property, competition, and policies (2nd edition). Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Kirzner, I. M. (1997). Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An Austrian approachz. Journal of Economic Literature, 35(1), 60–85.
Klein, P. G. (2008). Opportunity discovery, entrepreneurial action, and economic organization. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 2(3), 175–190.
Klein, D. B. (2012). Knowledge and coordination: A liberal interpretation. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.
Kleiner, M. M. (2006). Licensing occupations: Ensuring quality or restricting competition? Kalamazoo: W.E. Upjohn Institute.
Klepper, S. (2016). Experimental capitalism: The nanoeconomics of American high-tech industries. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Knight, F. H. (1951). The economic organization. New York: Harper & Row.
Lamoreaux, N. R., & Sokoloff, K. L. (2007). Inventors, firms, and the market for technology in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. In N. R. Lamoreaux, D. M. G. Raff, & P. Temin (Eds.), Learning by doing in markets, firms, and countries. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Landström, H., & Mason, C. (Eds.) (2016). Handbook of research on business angels. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Lawton, T. A., McGuire, S., & Rajwani, T. (2013). Corporate political activity: A literature review and research agenda. International Journal of Management Reviews, 15(1), 86–105.
Lazear, E. P. (2004). Balanced skills and entrepreneurship. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 94(2), 208–211.
Lerner, J., & Tåg, J. (2013). Institutions and venture capital. Industrial and Corporate Change, 22(1), 153–182.
Leyden, D. P., & Link, A. N. (2015). Public sector entrepreneurship: U.S. technology and innovation policy. New York: Oxford University Press.
Lucas, D. S., & Fuller, C. S. (2017). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive, and destructive — Relative to what. Journal of Business Venturing Insights, 7, 45–49.
MacMillan, I. C., Kulow, D. M., & Khoylian, R. (1989). Venture capitalists’ involvement in their investments: Extent and performance. Journal of Business Venturing, 4(1), 27–47.
Madhok, A., & Tallman, S. B. (1998). Resources, transactions and rents: Managing value through interfirm collaborative relationships. Organization Science, 9(3), 326–339.
Malcolmson, J. M. (1997). Contracts, hold-up, and labor markets. Journal of Economic Literature, 35(4), 1916–1957.
Manish, G. P., & Powell, B. (2014). Capital theory and the process of inter-temporal coordination: The Austrian contribution to the theory of economic growth. Atlantic Economic Journal, 42(2), 133–142.
McCloskey, D., & Klamer, A. (1995). One quarter of GDP is persuasion. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 85(2), 191–195.
Metcalfe, J. S. (1998). Evolutionary economics and creative destruction. London: Routledge.
Minniti, M., & Bygrave, W. (2001). A dynamic model of entrepreneurial learning. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 25(3), 5–16.
Mises, L. (1981 [1922]). Socialism: An economic and sociological analysis. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.
Mises, L. (1998 [1949]). Human action: A treatise on economics. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Misher, N. (1984). Tax consequences of exercising an incentive stock option with stock of the granting corporation. The Tax Executive, July, 36, 357–363.
Morck, R. K. (Ed.). (2005). A history of corporate governance around the world: Family business groups to professional managers. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Mowery, D. C. (2009). Plus ça change: Industrial R&D in the “third industrial revolution”. Industrial and Corporate Change, 18(1), 1–50.
Niehof, J. (1999). Barriers for hiring personnel. Research Report 9807/E. Zoetermeer: EIM Business and Policy Research.
OECD. (2003). The sources of economic growth in the OECD countries. Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2010). The OECD innovation strategy: Getting a head start on tomorrow. Paris: OECD.
Phelps, E. S. (2007). Macroeconomics for a modern economy. 2006 Nobel prize lecture in economics. American Economic Review, 97(3), 543–561.
Piore, M., & Sabel, C. (1984). The second industrial divide. New York: Basic Books.
Pongracic, I. (2009). Employees and entrepreneurship: Co-ordination and spontaneity in non-hierarchical business organizations. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Porter, M. E. (1990). The competitive advantage of nations. New York: Free Press.
Rodrik, D. (2007). One economics, many recipes: Globalization, institutions, and economic growth. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Rothbard, M. N. (2009 [1962]). Man, economy and state. Auburn: Mises Institute.
Rubin, P. H. (2014). Emporiophobia (fear of markets): Cooperation or competition? Southern Economic Journal, 80(4), 875–889.
Sautet, F. (2000). An entrepreneurial theory of the firm. New York: Routledge.
Scarpetta, S., Hemmings, P., Tressel, T., & Woo, J. (2002). The role of policy and institutions for productivity and firm dynamics: Evidence from micro and industry data. OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 329. Paris: OECD.
Schäfer, W., Kroneman, M., Boerma, W., van den Berg, M., Westert, G., Devillé, W., & van Ginneken, E. (2010). The Netherlands: Health system review. In Health systems in transition (vol. 12, no. 1). Copenhagen: European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1989 [1949]). Economic theory and entrepreneurial history. In R. V. Clemence (Ed.), Essays on entrepreneurs, innovations, business cycles, and the evolution of capitalism (pp. 253–271). New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.
Shane, S., & Venkataraman, S. (2000). The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research. Academy of Management Review, 25(1), 217–226.
Skedinger, P. (2010). Employment protection legislation. evolution, effects, winners and losers. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Smith, A. (1976 [1776]). An inquiry into the nature and the causes of the wealth of nations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Södersten, J. (1984). Sweden. In M. A. King & D. Fullerton (Eds.), The taxation of income from capital. A comparative study of the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden and West Germany (pp. 87–148). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Stam, E. (2015). Entrepreneurial ecosystems and regional policy: A sympathetic critique. European Planning Studies, 23(9), 1759–1769.
Stam, E., & Lambooy, J. (2012). Entrepreneurship, knowledge, space, and place: Evolutionary economic geography meets Austrian economics. In D. E. Andersson (Ed.), The spatial market process: Advances in Austrian economics (vol. 16, pp. 81–103). Bingley, UK: Emerald.
Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3–21.
Tåg, J. (2012). In D. Cumming (Ed.), The Oxford handbook of private equity The real effects of private equity buyouts (pp. 271–299). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
van Stel, A., Storey, D. J., & Thurik, A. R. (2007). The effect of business regulations on nascent and young business entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 28(2–3), 171–186.
von Hippel, E., Ogawa, S., & de Jong, J. P. J. (2011). The age of the consumer-innovator. MIT Sloan Management Review, 53(1), 27–35.
Wagner, R. E. (2014). Entangled political economy: A keynote address. In S. Horwitz & R. Koppl (Eds.), Entangled political economy. Advances in Austrian Economics, Volume 18. London: Emerald.
Wennekers, S., & Thurik, A. R. (1999). Linking entrepreneurship and economic growth. Small Business Economics, 13(1), 27–56.
Witt, U. (1996). Innovations, externalities and the problem of economic progress. Public Choice, 89(1–2), 113–130.
Acknowledgments
We are grateful for useful comments and suggestions on earlier drafts from Niclas Berggren, Dan Johansson, Henrik Jordahl, and Victor Ahlqvist. We acknowledge financial support from the Jan Wallander and Tom Hedelius Foundation and the Marianne and Marcus Wallenberg Foundation.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher’s note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Elert, N., Henrekson, M. The collaborative innovation bloc: A new mission for Austrian economics. Rev Austrian Econ 32, 295–320 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-019-00455-y
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-019-00455-y
Keywords
- Austrian economics
- Entrepreneurship
- Innovation
- Institutions
- Schumpeterian entrepreneurship
- Spontaneous order
JEL classification
- B53
- D20
- G32
- L23
- L26
- O33