Expectation in Austrian business cycle theory: Market share matters
Article
First Online:
- 317 Downloads
- 8 Citations
Abstract
One of the most important objections to the Mises-Hayek business cycle theory is the rational expectations critique. The debate between supporters and critics of the Mises-Hayek theory has not paid sufficient attention to the problem of differences in expectations and the market share in the allocation of production factors. I represent financially the effects that occur under the Austrian business cycle theory in the market of production factors as well as how economic imbalances occur when a central bank follows an expansionary policy and entrepreneurs have different expectations.
Keywords
Austrian business cycle theory Rational expectations Market share EVA(R) Economic value addedReferences
- Barnett, W., II, & Block, W. E. (2005). Professor Tullock on Austrian business cycle theory. Advances in Austrian Economics, 8, 431–443. doi: 10.1016/S1529-2134(05)08018-X.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Barnett, W., II, & Block, W. E. (2006). Tyler Cowen on Austrian business cycle theory: a critique. New Perspectives on Political Economy, 2(2), 26–85.Google Scholar
- Bernanke, B. S., & Gertler, M. (1989). Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations. The American Economic Review, 79(1), 14–31.Google Scholar
- Bernanke, B. S., & Gertler, M. (1990). Financial fragility and economic performance. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(1), 87–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1996). The financial accelerator and the flight to quality. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1), 1–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1999). The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In J. Taylor (Ed.), Handbook of macroeconomics 1 (pp. 1341–1393). Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
- Block, W. E. (2001). Yes, we have no chaff: a reply to Wagner’s “Austrian cycle theory: saving the wheat while discarding the chaff”. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 4(1), 63–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Buchanan, J. M. (1964). What should economists do? Southern Economic Journal, 30(3), 213–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Butos, W. N. (1997). Toward an Austrian theory of expectations. Advances in Austrian Economics, 4, 75–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Caballero, R. J. (2010). Macroeconomics after the crisis: time to deal with the pretense-of-knowledge syndrome. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(4), 85–102. doi: 10.1257/jep.24.4.85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cachanosky, J. C. (1999). Value based management. Libertas, 30(May), 179–211.Google Scholar
- Cachanosky, N. (2012). The Mises-Hayek business cycle theory, fiat currencies and open economies. The Review of Austrian Economics. doi: 10.1007/s11138-012-0188-2.Google Scholar
- Cachanosky, N. (2014). The international effects of monetary policy in the capital structure of production: the cases of Colombia and Panama (2002–2007). The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance. doi: 10.1016/j.qref.2014.03.003.Google Scholar
- Caldwell, B. J. (1984). Praxeology and its critics: an appraisal. History of Political Economy, 16(3), 363–379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Callahan, G., & Horwitz, S. G. (2010). The role of ideal types in Austrian Business cycle theory. Advances in Austrian Economics, 14(2010), 205–224. doi: 10.1108/S1529-2134(2010) 0000014013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Caplan, B. (1997). Why I am not an Austrian economist. Unpublished Manuscript.Google Scholar
- Carilli, A. M., & Dempster, G. M. (2001). Expectations in Austrian business cycle theory: an application of the prisoner’s dilemma. The Review of Austrian Economics, 14(4), 319–330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Carilli, A. M., & Dempster, G. M. (2008). Is the Austrian business cycle theory still relevant? The Review of Austrian Economics, 21(4), 271–281. doi: 10.1007/s11138-008-0044-6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ćorić, B. (2011). The financial accelerator effect: concept and challenges. Financial Theory and Practice, 35(2), 171–196.Google Scholar
- Cowen, T. (1997). Risk and business cycles: New and old Austrian perspectives. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
- Ebeling, R. M. (Ed.). (1978). The Austrian theory of the trade cycle and other essays (1996th ed.). Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
- Eusepi, S., & Preston, B. (2011). Expectations, learning, and business cycle fluctuations. American Economic Review, 101(6), 2844–2872. doi: 10.1257/aer.101.6.2844.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Evans, A. J., & Baxendale, T. (2008). Austrian business cycle theory in light of rational expectations: the role of heterogeneity, the monetary footprint, and adverse selection in monetary expansion. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 11(2), 81–93. doi: 10.1007/s12113-008-9034-6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Evans, A. J., & Friedman, J. (2011). “Search” vs. “Browse”: a theory of error grounded on radical (not Rational) ignorance. Critical Review, 23(1–2), 73–104. doi: 10.1080/08913811.2011.574471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Friedman, M. (1993). The “Plucking model” of business fluctuations revisited. Economic Inquiry, XXXI, 171–177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fuster, A., Laibson, D., & Mendel, B. (2010). Natural expectations and macroeconomic fluctuations. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(4), 67–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Garrison, R. W. (1986). From Lachmann to Lucas: On Institutions, Expectations, and Equilibrating Tendencies. In I. M. Kirzner (Ed.), Subjectivism, intelligibility and economic understanding (pp. 87–101). New York: New York University Press and Macmillan Co.Google Scholar
- Garrison, R. W. (1989). The Austrian theory of the business cycle in the light of modern macroeconomics. The Review of Austrian Economics, 3(1), 3–29. doi: 10.1007/BF01539555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Garrison, R. W. (1991). New classical and old Austrian economics: equilibrium business cycle theory in perspective. The Review of Austrian Economics, 5(1), 91–103. doi: 10.1007/BF00843932.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Garrison, R. W. (1996). Friedman’s “Plucking mode”: comment. Economic Inquiry, XXXIV, 799–802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Garrison, R. W. (2001). In M. J. Rizzo & L. H. White (Eds.), Time and money. The macroeconomics of capital structure (2002nd ed.). London: Routledge.Google Scholar
- Hayek, F. A. (1931). Prices and production (1967th ed.). New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
- Hayek, F. A. (1933). Monetary theory and the trade cycle. (N. Kaldor & H. M. Croome, Trans.). New York: Sentry Press.Google Scholar
- Hayek, F. A. (1967). Studies in philosophy, politics and economics (1978th ed.). London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
- Hayek, F. A. (1973). Law, legislation and liberty: Rules and order, vol. 1 (1983rd ed.). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
- Hoffmann, A. (2010). An overinvestment cycle in Central and Eastern Europe? Metroeconomica, 61(4), 711–734. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-999X.2010.04103.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hoffmann, A. (2012). Zero-interest rate policy and unintended consequences in emerging markets. SSRN Electronic Journal. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.2055690.Google Scholar
- Horwitz, S. G. (2011). The expanding sphere of opportunities. The freeman online.Google Scholar
- Hummel, J. R. (1979). Problems with Austrian business cycle theory. Reason Papers, 5(Winter), 41–53.Google Scholar
- Kamber, G., & Thoenissen, C. (2011). The financial accelerator and monetary policy rules. Victoria.Google Scholar
- Kirzner, I. M. (1965). What economists do. Southern Economic Journal, 31(3), 257–261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kohn, M. (2004). Value and exchange. Cato Journal, 24(3), 303–339.Google Scholar
- Kollar, M. (2008). Production structure in the context of international trade. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 11(1), 18–42. doi: 10.1007/s12113-008-9029-3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kuhn, T. S. (1962). The structure of scientific revolutions (1996th ed.). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
- Lachmann, L. M. (1943). The rôle of expectations in economics as a social science. Economica, 10(37), 12–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Lachmann, L. M. (1977). In W. E. Grinder (Ed.), Capital, expectations, and the market process. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel.Google Scholar
- Lakatos, I. (1978). In J. Worral & G. Currie (Eds.), The methodology of scientific research programmes (1999th ed., Vol. 1). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- McAuliff, R. E. (1985). The rational expectations hypothesis and economic analysis. Eastern Economic Journal, 11(4), 331–341.Google Scholar
- McCallum, B. T. (1982). Macroeconomics after a decade of rational expectations: some critical issues. Economic Review, November/D, 3–12.Google Scholar
- O’Driscoll, G. P. J., & Rizzo, M. J. (1985). In M. J. Rizzo & L. H. White (Eds.), The economics of time and ignorance (1996th ed.). New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
- Sargent, T. J. (2008). Rational expectations. The concise encyclopedia of economics. Retrieved January 30, 2014, from http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/RationalExpectations.html.
- Stern, J. M., Shiely, J. S., & Ross, I. (2001). The EVA challenge. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
- Stewart III, B. G. (1991). The quest for value. Harper Collins Publishers.Google Scholar
- Tullock, G. (1988). Why the Austrians are wrong about depressions. The Review of Austrian Economics, 2(1), 73–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Tullock, G. (1989). Reply to comment by Joseph T. Salerno. The Review of Austrian Economics, 3(1), 147–149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- von Mises, L. (1912). The theory of money and credit. (H. E. Batson, Trans.) (1981st ed.). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
- von Mises, L. (1943). “Elastic expectations” and the Austrian theory of the trade cycle. Economica, 10(39), 251–252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- von Mises, L. (1949). Human action (1996th ed.). Irvington-on-Hudson: The Foundation for Economic Education.Google Scholar
- von Mises, L. (1955). Buck hills lectures. Irvington-on-Hudson: The Foundation for Economic Education.Google Scholar
- Wagner, R. E. (1999). Austrian cycle theory: saving the wheat while discarding the chaff. The Review of Austrian Economics, 12, 65–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- White, L. H., & Selgin, G. A. (2010). The Austrian theory of the business cycle in a fiat money regime.Google Scholar
- Yeager, L. B. (1986). The significance of monetary disequilibrium. Cato Journal, 6(2), 369–399.Google Scholar
- Young, A. T. (2012). Austrian Business Cycle Theory: A Modern Appraisal. In P. J. Boettke & C. J. Coyne (Eds.), Oxford handbook of Austrian economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
- Young, D. S., & O’Byrne, S. E. (2001). EVA and value-based management. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
- Zanotti, G. J., & Cachanosky, N. (2013). The epistemological implications of Machlup’s interpretation of Mises’s epistemology. SSRN Electronic Journal. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.2229570.Google Scholar
Copyright information
© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2014