Skip to main content
Log in

Targeted incentives, broad impacts: Evidence from an E-commerce platform

  • Published:
Quantitative Marketing and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Digital platforms sometimes offer incentives to a subset of sellers to nudge behavior, possibly affecting the behavior of all sellers in the equilibrium. In this paper, we study a policy change on a large e-commerce platform that offers financial incentives only to platform-certified sellers when they provide fast handling and generous return policies on their listings. We find that both targeted and non-targeted sellers become more likely to adopt the promoted behavior after the policy change. Exploiting a large number of markets on the platform, we find that in markets with a larger proportion of the targeted population—hence more affected by the policy change—non-targeted sellers are more likely to adopt the promoted behavior and experience a larger increase in sales and equilibrium prices. This finding is consistent with our key insight that a targeted incentive may increase demand for non-targeted sellers when both platform certificates and the promoted behaviors are quality signals. Our results have implications for digital platforms that use targeted incentives.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. https://www.cnet.com/news/to-power-prime-one-day-shipping-amazon-asks-sellers-to-send-it-more-stuff/; https://www.uber.com/blog/los-angeles/consecutive-trips-earnings/; (9/14/2020)

  2. This is different from targeted subsidies which are monetary transfers to sellers of a given type regardless of their behavior. Examples of targeted subsidies are government subsidies for small firms and tax cuts for a sector of the economy. With targeted subsidies, the demand for non-targeted (thus non-subsidized) firms will be unambiguously lower because the prices of their subsidized competitors will decrease. As we show later, targeted incentives do not necessarily lead to such equilibrium outcomes.

  3. See Rafieian and Yoganarasimhan (2021) for a discussion of the pros and cons of behavioral and contextual targeting from the perspective of an ad network.

  4. We do not allow for entry and exit in this model, to keep it tractable. In Table A1 in the online appendix, we show that the policy change did not change the number of eTRS or non-eTRS sellers.

  5. Refer to the example given by Tirole (1988) (Section 2.1.1, Chapter 2) for the intuition of this assumption.

  6. We note that there are points of departure from the Tirole (1988) model. The key difference with Tirole’s model is that we allow sellers to endogenously select the quality (PS vs. non-PS). The reason is to fit with our research objective, which is to study how targeted incentives affect sellers’ quality choice and thus the equilibrium outcomes.

    The vertical structure of the model restricts that there is only direct substitution between sellers in adjacent segments. In our context, it means that, for example, eTRS-PS listings only compete against eTRS-non-PS listings but not non-eTRS-PS listings. This could be a limitation of Tirole’s model applying to our context. However, we note that non-adjacent listings can still affect each other indirectly at the market equilibrium.

    We note that, because of the simplifying assumptions, Tirole’s model is used to illustrate the mechanism driving our findings. It is not meant to form a basis for the structural model of which researchers can apply the data to estimate the primitives of the model.

  7. The eTRS badge is beneficial for sellers as it increases sales probability by 7% on the eBay U.K. site (Elfenbein et al. , 2015) and increases sales price by 3% on the eBay U.S. site (Hui et al. , 2016).

  8. The sample period ends at Week 13 because eBay announced a new policy in Week 14. This policy was designed to further incentivize sellers to improve on shipping and handling. Specifically, eTRS sellers would lose the 20% discount on the commission fee for listings without PS.

  9. We have also plotted the figure using 33 weeks after the policy change in Fig. A3 in the online appendix. Both time series became relatively stable in the extended period. This suggests that sellers did not shift forward some inventory because of the targeted incentive. However, this is a possibility that we cannot fully rule out.

  10. One may argue that otherwise identical listings that only differ in PS may render the one without PS inferior and thus not able to sell. However, due to market friction, the matched listings are likely not perfect substitutes. Because of search cost, consumers may not be able to find and compare the two otherwise identical listings. Therefore, the listings without PS may still generate sales in equilibrium.

  11. Using the share of eTRS sellers as an alternative policy exposure measure does not change the results qualitatively.

  12. Specifically, under the targeted incentive, eTRS sellers pay 75% of the normal commission for PS listings and 80% for their non-PS listings. Therefore, the discount for PS listings is 75/80 = 15/16.

  13. Specifically, the targeted incentive only lasted for three months, meaning that eTRS sellers who offered PS after the three-month period do not get the reduced commission rate. Given this, the platform commission growth reduces to \((C_1 - C_0)/C_0 = \beta \).

References

  • Abhishek, V., Jerath, K., & Sharma, S. (2022). The impact of sponsored listings on online marketplaces: Insights from a field experiment. Available at SSRN 3013468.

  • Ahn, D. -Y., Duan, J. A., & Mela, C. F. (2011). An equilibrium model of user generated content. Available at SSRN 1957989.

  • Anderson, E. T., & Simester, D. (2013). Advertising in a competitive market: The role of product standards, customer learning, and switching costs. Journal of Marketing research, 50(4), 489–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, M., Luo, X., Fang, Z., & Ghose, A. (2016). Mobile ad effectiveness: Hyper-contextual targeting with crowdedness. Marketing Science, 35(2), 218–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansari, A., & Mela, C. F. (2003). E-customization. Journal of marketing research, 40(2), 131–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bleier, A., & Eisenbeiss, M. (2015). Personalized online advertising effectiveness: The interplay of what, when, and where. Marketing Science, 34(5), 669–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burtch, G., Hong, Y., Bapna, R., & Griskevicius, V. (2018). Stimulating online reviews by combining financial incentives and social norms. Management Science, 64(5), 2065–2082.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, L., & Li, L. (2015). A dollar for your thoughts: Feedback-conditional rebates on ebay. Management Science, 61(9), 2052–2063.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao, G., Jin, G. Z., Weng, X., & Zhou, L.-A. (2018). Market expanding or market stealing? competition with network effects in bikesharing. National Bureau of Economic Research: Technical report.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cennamo, C., Gu, Y., & Zhou, F. (2016). Value co-creation and capture in the creative industry: The us home video game market. Technical report, Working paper.

  • Chae, I., Stephen, A. T., Bart, Y., & Yao, D. (2017). Spillover effects in seeded word-of-mouth marketing campaigns. Marketing Science, 36(1), 89–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., Harper, F. M., Konstan, J., & Li, S. X. (2010). Social comparisons and contributions to online communities: A field experiment on movielens. American Economic Review, 100(4), 1358–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chesnes, M., & Jin, G. Z. (2019). Direct-to-consumer advertising and online search. Information Economics and Policy, 46, 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einav, L., Kuchler, T., Levin, J., & Sundaresan, N. (2015). Assessing sale strategies in online markets using matched listings. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 7(2), 215–247.

    Google Scholar 

  • Einav, L., Kuchler, T., Levin, J. D., & Sundaresan, N. (2011). Learning from seller experiments in online markets. National Bureau of Economic Research: Technical report.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Elfenbein, D. W., Fisman, R., & McManus, B. (2012). Charity as a substitute for reputation: Evidence from an online marketplace. Review of Economic Studies, 79(4), 1441–1468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elfenbein, D. W., Fisman, R., & McManus, B. (2015). Market structure, reputation, and the value of quality certification. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 7(4), 83–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feinberg, F. M., Krishna, A., & Zhang, Z. J. (2002). Do we care what others get? a behaviorist approach to targeted promotions. Journal of Marketing research, 39(3), 277–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fong, N. M., Fang, Z., & Luo, X. (2015). Geo-conquesting: Competitive locational targeting of mobile promotions. Journal of Marketing Research, 52(5), 726–735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fradkin, A., Grewal E., & Holtz, D. (2018). The determinants of online review informativeness: Evidence from field experiments on airbnb. Available at SSRN 2939064.

  • Goldfarb, A., & Tucker, C. (2011). Online display advertising: Targeting and obtrusiveness. Marketing Science, 30(3), 389–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hui, X., & Liu, M. (2022). Quality certificates alleviate consumer aversion to sponsored search advertising.

  • Hui, X., Saeedi, M., Shen, Z., & Sundaresan, N. (2016). Reputation and regulations: evidence from ebay. Management Science, 62(12), 3604–3616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hui, X., Saeedi, M., Spagnolo, G., & Tadelis, S. (2023). Raising the bar: Certification thresholds and market outcomes. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joo, M., Shi, J., & Abhishek, V. (2021). Seller incentives in sponsored product listings on online marketplaces. Available at SSRN 3896716.

  • Kuang, L., Huang, N., Hong, Y., & Yan, Z. (2019). Spillover effects of financial incentives on non-incentivized user engagement: Evidence from an online knowledge exchange platform. Journal of Management Information Systems, 36(1), 289–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, V., Sun, B., & Srinivasan, K. (2014). Why do consumers contribute to connected goods? A Dynamic Model of Competition and Cooperation Working Paper.

  • Lambrecht, A., & Tucker, C. (2013). When does retargeting work? information specificity in online advertising. Journal of Marketing research, 50(5), 561–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Z., & Agarwal, A. (2017). Platform integration and demand spillovers in complementary markets: Evidence from facebook’s integration of instagram. Management Science, 63(10), 3438–3458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liang, C., Shi, Z., & Raghu, T. (2019). The spillover of spotlight: Platform recommendation in the mobile app market. Information Systems Research, 30(4), 1296–1318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luo, X., Andrews, M., Fang, Z., & Phang, C. W. (2014). Mobile targeting. Management Science, 60(7), 1738–1756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGranaghan, M., Liaukonyte, J., Fisher, G., & Wilbur, K. C. (2019). Lead offer spillovers. Marketing Science, 38(4), 643–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moshary, S. (2021). Sponsored search in equilibrium: Evidence from two experiments. Available at SSRN 3903602.

  • Nosko, C., & Tadelis, S. (2015). The limits of reputation in platform markets: An empirical analysis and field experiment. National Bureau of Economic Research: Technical report.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rafieian, O., & Yoganarasimhan, H. (2021). Targeting and privacy in mobile advertising. Marketing Science, 40(2), 193–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reshef, O. (2019). Smaller slices of a growing pie: The effects of entry in platform markets.

  • Roberts, J. A., Hann, I.-H., & Slaughter, S. A. (2006). Understanding the motivations, participation, and performance of open source software developers: A longitudinal study of the apache projects. Management science, 52(7), 984–999.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sahni, N. S. (2016). Advertising spillovers: Evidence from online field experiments and implications for returns on advertising. Journal of Marketing Research, 53(4), 459–478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sahni, N. S., Zou, D., & Chintagunta, P. K. (2017). Do targeted discount offers serve as advertising? evidence from 70 field experiments. Management Science, 63(8), 2688–2705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, B. T. (2018). Positive spillovers and free riding in advertising of prescription pharmaceuticals: The case of antidepressants. Journal of political economy, 126(1), 381–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shen, Q., & Xiao, P. (2014). Mcdonald’s and kfc in china: Competitors or companions? Marketing Science, 33(2), 287–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shriver, S. K., Nair, H. S., & Hofstetter, R. (2013). Social ties and user-generated content: Evidence from an online social network. Management Science, 59(6), 1425–1443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, Y., Dong, X., & McIntyre, S. (2017). Motivation of user-generated content: Social connectedness moderates the effects of monetary rewards. Marketing Science, 36(3), 329–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1988). The theory of industrial organization. MIT press.

  • Yang, N. (2019). Learning in retail entry. International Journal of Research in Marketing.

  • Yao, S., & Mela, C. F. (2011). A dynamic model of sponsored search advertising. Marketing Science, 30(3), 447–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, D. J., Dai, H., Dong, L., Qi, F., Zhang, N., Liu, X., Liu, Z., Yang, J., et al. (2018). How do price promotions affect customer behavior on retailing platforms? evidence from a large randomized experiment on alibaba. Production and Operations Management, 27(12), 2343–2345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, J., & Wedel, M. (2009). The effectiveness of customized promotions in online and offline stores. Journal of marketing research, 46(2), 190–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, X. M., & Zhu, F. (2011). Group size and incentives to contribute: A natural experiment at chinese wikipedia. American Economic Review, 101(4), 1601–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Seth Benzell, Avi Collis, Oren Reshef, Song Yao, and seminar and conference participants at Washington University in St. Louis, CIST, CODE, UTD-FORMS, ISMS Marketing Science for their helpful comments. We gratefully acknowledge the guidance provided by the editor and two anonymous referees. We are also grateful to eBay for providing access to the data.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xiang Hui.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

None of the authors has a current financial relationship with eBay. Xiang Hui did an internship at eBay from May 2015 to August 2015, and received a \( \$ \)16,000 compensation.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hui, X., Liu, M. & Chan, T. Targeted incentives, broad impacts: Evidence from an E-commerce platform. Quant Mark Econ 21, 493–517 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-023-09267-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-023-09267-8

Keywords

Navigation