If it proves that I cannot trust the local policemen, judges, teachers, and doctors, then whom in this society can I trust?’ The ethics of public officials become central here, not only with respect to how they do their jobs, but also to the signals they send to citizens about what kind of ‘game’ is being played in the society.
Rothstein and Eek (2009, p. 90).
Abstract
Although often at the heart of the public debate, the underlying determinants of political selection and voters’ punishment of corrupt politicians remain poorly investigated. This paper contributes to our understanding of those issues by showing that places, such as Italy, where social norms are weak and trust in government is low, also feature adverse political selection and low levels of electoral punishment of corrupt politicians. Our measure of trust in government is based on the occurrence of cheating by Italian schoolteachers. We show that untrustworthiness is strongly related to both the malfeasance of local representatives and to low levels of electoral punishment of them.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Source: see Table A.1 in the online "Appendix A"

Source: See Table A.1 in the online "Appendix A"

Source: See Table A.1 in the online "Appendix A".
Notes
According to Uslaner (2008, p. 290), “generalized trust represents a sense of social solidarity, a belief that other people, especially people unlike yourself, are part of your moral community”.
As explained by Golden and Chang (2001), Italy represents an extreme case of political corruption in an established democratic setting. The evidence that wealth does not account for perceived corruption should be considered as an exception to be included in any theory of political corruption. Italy offers a unique source of data on political corruption in terms of RAPs. Owing to the “Clean Hands” investigations since 1992, Italy offers one of the most important single sources of information about the nature, extent and functioning of general political corruption in a modern democratic system.
For a detailed review of the results on empirical indicators of social capital, see Grootaert and van Bastelaer (2001).
Bjørnskov and Sønderskov (2013) revived the relevance of social capital, confirming that it is comprised of multiple dimensions.
We also test with the single measure of cheating or standardize by its standard deviation. The empirical findings are similar to those reported here.
The measure of constraints on the executive was coded for different 40-year windows around the years 1600, 1700, 1750, 1800 and 1850; it takes values from 1 (unconstrained authority) to 7 (maximum accountability and constraints).
Unlike Chang et al. (2010), we do not consider the XI (1992) and the XII legislatures (1994) since the political scandal of “Clean Hands”, that took place in those two legislatures, would impart bias to our estimates.
Furthermore, Chang et al. (2010) report that, differently from the XI (1992) and the XII legislatures (1994), from 1948 to 1987 the average reelection rate of politicians already involved in corruption scandals was closer to the reelection rate of other politicians. That evidence minimizes the potential risk of politicians’ selection bias.
In fact, the totality of political parties and a large fraction of the politicians active in the 1948–1987 period no longer are present in the 2007–2009 political scenario.
In the "Appendix", Table A.1 supplies details on variable definitions and data sources, whereas Table A.2 reports descriptive statistics.
The electoral rule for seats in the Italian House of Representatives between 1948 and 1987 was a pure proportional system. Thus, deciding to normalize the RAP and S_RAP variables for inhabitants seems to us the correct choice.
In the observed time span, we have 32 electoral districts.
As far as we know, in Italy, blood donations are done on a voluntary basis and do not entitle blood donors to receive any amount of money.
In their "Appendix" the authors check for alternative measures of social capital based on principal-component analysis.
For convenience, in the following estimates we report only the variables of interest. The full estimates are available from the authors upon request.
The variable was coded for different 40-year windows around the years 1600, 1700, 1750, 1800 and 1850; it takes values from 1 (unconstrained authority) to 7 (maximum accountability and constraints). For more details, see Tabellini (2010).
To provide a comparison with the results obtained by Nannicini et al. (2013), we also report in "Appendix A" the estimates using blood donations as a measure of social capital. Specifically, in each column of Tables A.5 and A.6, we estimate a baseline model analogous to the baseline estimates in column 1 (using blood donations) of Table 4 and in column 4 (using the cheating index) of Table 5. The only difference is the exclusion of dummy variables for macro geographical areas (i.e., North-West, North-East, Center, South, Islands), owing to the large correlations of those geographical areas with our instruments.
Incidentally, average per capita blood donations as measure of social capital seems to suffer endogeneity in explaining politicians’ misbehavior.
For convenience, in the following estimates we report only the variables of interest. The full estimates are available from the authors upon request.
As a further robustness check and to offer an additional comparison between the two measures, in "Appendix A" we also report the estimates for two subsamples based on the median of blood donations and trust in government, respectively (Nannicini et al. 2013). Operationally, we split the sample by pooling the observations lying above or below the median values of blood donations and trust in government. Specifically, in both Tables A.7 and A.8 columns 1 to 4 represent the estimates of the split samples based on the median of blood donations in the electoral districts. Similarly, columns 5 to 8 report the estimates of the split samples based on the median of our measure of trust in government at district level. Tables A.7 and A.8 show that the incidences of RAP or S_RAP cause electoral punishment of politicians involved in misbehavior in the electoral districts exhibiting high levels of trust in government. Incidentally, the magnitude of the coefficients on electoral punishment seem slightly smaller than in the estimates based on blood donations.
References
Aassve, A., Daniele, G., & Le Moglie, M. (2018). Never forget the first time: The persistent effects of corruption and the rise of populism in Italy. BAFFI CAREFIN Centre Research Paper, (2018-96).
Anderson, C. J., & Tverdova, Y. V. (2003). Corruption, political allegiances, and attitudes toward government in contemporary democracies. American Journal of Political Science,47(1), 91–109.
Angrist, J. D., Battistin, E., & Vuri, D. (2017). In a small moment: Class size and moral hazard in the Italian mezzogiorno. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics,9(4), 216–249.
Bjørnskov, C. (2006). The multiple facets of social capital. European Journal of Political Economy,22, 22–40.
Bjørnskov, C. (2019). The political economy of trust. In R. Congleton, B. Grofman, & S. Voigt (Eds.), Oxford handbook of public choice (pp. 628–649). New York: Oxford University Press.
Bjørnskov, C., & Sønderskov, K. M. (2013). Is social capital a good concept? Social Indicators Research,114, 1225–1242.
Buonanno, P., Montolio, D., & Vanin, P. (2009). Does social capital reduce crime? The Journal of Law and Economics,52(1), 145–170.
Cartocci, R. (2007). Mappe del tesoro. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Chang, E. C., Golden, M. A., & Hill, S. J. (2010). Legislative malfeasance and political accountability. World Politics,62(2), 177–220.
Charron, N., Dijkstra, L., & Lapuente, V. (2014). Regional governance matters: Quality of government within European Union member states. Regional Studies,48(1), 68–90.
Chong, A., De La O, A. L., Karlan, D., & Wantchekon, L. (2014). Does corruption information inspire the fight or quash the hope? A field experiment in Mexico on voter turnout, choice, and party identification. The Journal of Politics,77(1), 55–71.
Clark, J. R., & Lee, D. R. (2001). Is trust in government compatible with trustworthy government? In W. F. Shughart II & L. Razzolini (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 479–493). Northampton, Mass: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Cobb, M. D., & Taylor, A. J. (2015). An absence of malice: The limited utility of campaigning against party corruption. American Politics Research,43(6), 923–951.
Costas-Pérez, E., Solé-Ollé, A., & Sorribas-Navarro, P. (2012). Corruption scandals, voter information, and accountability. European Journal of Political Economy,28(4), 469–484.
De Vries, C. E., & Solaz, H. (2017). The electoral consequences of corruption. Annual Review of Political Science,20, 391–408.
Delhey, J., & Newton, K. (2003). Who trusts? The origins of social trust in seven societies. European Societies,5(2), 93–137.
Della Porta, D. (2000). Social capital, beliefs in government, and political corruption. In S. J. Pharr & R. D. Putnam (Eds.), Disaffected democracies: What’s troubling the trilateral countries (pp. 202–230). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Di Liberto, A., & Sideri, M. (2015). Past dominations, current institutions and the Italian regional economic performance. European Journal of Political Economy,38, 12–41.
Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-De Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The new comparative economics. Journal of Comparative Economics,31, 595–619.
Ferraz, C., & Finan, F. (2008). Exposing corrupt politicians: the effects of Brazil’s publicly released audits on electoral outcomes. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,123(2), 703–745.
Fisman, R., & Miguel, E. (2007). Corruption, norms, and legal enforcement: Evidence from diplomatic parking tickets. Journal of Political Economy,115(6), 1020–1048.
Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust: The social virtues and the creation of prosperity. New York: Free Press.
Glaeser, E. L., Sacerdote, B., & Scheinkman, J. A. (1996). Crime and social interactions. Quarterly Journal of Economics,111, 507–548.
Golden, M. A., & Chang, E. C. (2001). Competitive corruption: Malfeasance in postwar Italian christian democracy. World Politics,53(July), 588–622.
Grootaert, C., & Van Bastelaer, T. (2001). Understanding and measuring social capital: A synthesis of findings and recommendations from the social capital initiative. World Bank Working Paper No. 24., (24).
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2004). The role of social capital in financial development. American Economic Review,94(3), 526–556.
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2008). Trusting the stock market. Journal of Finance,63(6), 2557–2600.
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2011). Civic capital as the missing link. In Handbook of social economics (Vol. 1, pp. 417–480). North-Holland.
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2016). Long-term persistence. Journal of the European Economic Association,14(6), 1401–1436.
Hagan, J., Merkens, H., & Boehnke, K. (1995). Delinquency and disdain: Social capital and the control of right-wing extremism among East and West berlin Youth. American Journal of Sociology,100, 1028–1052.
Healy, A., & Malhotra, N. (2013). Retrospective voting reconsidered. Annual Review of Political Science,16, 285–306.
Hirano, S., & Snyder, J. M., Jr. (2012). Primary elections and political accountability: What happens to incumbents in scandals? Quarterly Journal of Political Science,7(4), 447–456.
Inglehart, R., & Welzel, C. (2005). Modernization, cultural change and democracy. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2010). Response to ‘What do the worldwide governance indicators measure?’. The European Journal of Development Research,22(1), 55–58.
Keele, L. (2007). Social capital and dynamics of trust in government. American Journal of Political Science,51(2), 241–254.
Klesner, J. L. (2007). Social capital and political participation in Latin America. Latin American Research Review,42(2), 1–32.
Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics,107, 1252–1288.
Kurer, O. (2001). Why do voters support corrupt politicians? In A. K. Jain (Ed.), The political economy of corruption (pp. 75–98). London: Routledge.
La Porta, R., Lopez-De Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). Trust in large organizations. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings,137(2), 333–338.
Levi, M. (1998). Consent, dissent, and patriotism. NewYork: Cambridge University Press.
Manion, M. (2004). Corruption by design: Building clean government in mainland China and Honk Kong. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Moreno, A. (2002). Corruption and democracy: A cultural assessment. Comparative Sociology,1(3–4), 495–507.
Morris, S. D., & Klesner, J. L. (2010). Corruption and trust: Theoretical considerations and evidence from Mexico. Comparative Political Studies,43(10), 1258–1285.
Nannicini, T., Stella, A., Tabellini, G., & Troiano, U. (2013). Social capital and political accountability. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy,5(2), 222–250.
Nifo, A., & Vecchione, G. (2014). Do institutions play a role in skilled migration? The case of Italy. Regional Studies,48(10), 1628–1649.
North, D. C. (1998). Where have we been and where are we going? In A. Ben-Ner & L. Putterman (Eds.), Economics, values and organization (pp. 491–508). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Paccagnella, M., & Sestito, P. (2014). School cheating and social capital. Education Economics,22(4), 367–388.
Putnam, R. D. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling alone: The collapse and revival of American community. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Putnam, R. D. (2001). Social capital: Measurement and consequences. Isuma,2, 41–51.
Rothstein, B. (2005). Social traps and the problem of trust. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rothstein, B. (2013). Corruption and social trust: Why the fish rots from the head down. Social Research,80(4), 1009–1032.
Rothstein, B., & Eek, D. (2009). Political corruption and social trust: An experimental approach. Rationality and Society,21(1), 81–112.
Rothstein, B., & Stolle, D. (2002). How political institutions create and destroy social capital: An institutional theory of generalized trust. In delivery at the annual meeting of the American political science association, Boston, August–September.
Rothstein, B., & Uslaner, E. M. (2005). All for all: Equality, corruption, and social trust. World Politics,58, 41–72.
Seligson, M. A. (2002). The impact of corruption on regime legitimacy: A comparative study of four Latin American countries. The Journal of Politics,64(2), 408–433.
Tabellini, G. (2010). Culture and institutions: Economic development in the regions of Europe. Journal of the European Economic association,8(4), 677–716.
Uslaner, E. M. (2002). The moral foundations of trust. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Uslaner, E. M. (2008). The foundations of trust: Macro and micro. Cambridge Journal of Economics,32, 289–294.
Uslaner, E. M., & Brown, M. (2005). Inequality, trust, and civic engagement. American Politics Research,33(6), 868–894.
Wesberry, J. (2004). Institutional obstacles that limit the functions of governmental organs to combat corruption in Latin America. Caracas, Venezuela: Centro Latinoamericano de Administración para el Desarollo.
Acknowledgements
We thank the Editor-in-chief, the two guest editors of the special issue on Legal Corruption and, two anonymous referees for comments and suggestions. We are also indebted to all the participants to the ICS 2nd Workshop on Corruption, Ilinois State University, Chicago, for stimulating discussions. Finally, special thanks go to Juan F. Vargas for his contribution in enhancing the first version of the manuscript; Francesco Drago, Domenico Lisi and, Angelo Mazza, for their invaluable help in improving our work.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Electronic supplementary material
Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Finocchiaro Castro, M., Guccio, C. Birds of a feather flock together: trust in government, political selection and electoral punishment. Public Choice 184, 263–287 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00759-4
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00759-4
Keywords
- Trust in government
- Social capital
- Legal corruption
- Political corruption
- Electoral punishment
JEL Classification
- P16
- D72
- Z13