Abstract
Do Republican and Democratic presidents vary in their geographic allocations of federal spending? Recent scholarship suggests that US presidents provide more federal outlays to districts represented by their co-partisans, but leave the issue of partisan affiliation unanswered. We explore that question using an updated database that covers federal spending programs over the 1984–2014 period. We show that the alignment effect found in previous studies cannot be observed for Republican presidents. We argue that Republican presidents may not use pork as much as Democratic presidents because their core constituency is fiscally conservative. One implication of the results reported herein is that the electoral benefits of distributive politics depend on the fiscal preferences of the electorate.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
Notes
See also Couch and Shugart (2000), Wallis et al. (2006), and Wallis (2010) on this topic. Similar evidence on the importance of political motives for the geographical targetting of federal policies is provided by Garret and Sobel (2003) for the example of FEMA disaster relief programs and Young et al. (2001) for IRS tax audits.
Various studies explore other types of heterogeneity. Kriner and Reeves (2015b) allow for heterogeneity across states, but not across presidents. Dynes and Huber (2015) distinguish between voters and representatives, but again do not focus on individual presidents or their parties. It thus remains an open question whether the partisan bias identified by all of those studies in the allocation of federal outlays is a general feature of presidential politics, or whether differences between presidents and their parties can be observed.
Note that for our study, it is less important whether presidents reward aligned voters or aligned representatives. We are concerned mainly with whether Republican and Democratic presidents differ in how they reward political alignment, not whether their primary targets are aligned representatives or aligned voters. While we define below a district’s alignment based on the partisan affiliation of the representative, we do not claim that it is the main dimension of alignment the president takes into account.
Compared to congressional variables, there is less evidence that senatorial politics distorts federal spending.
A further complication is that presidents may implement universalistic policies even if they are motivated chiefly by political concerns (such as ensuring their reelection), because they face—if we abstract from the idiosyncrasies of the Electoral College—a national constituency, incentivizing them roughly to focus on the welfare of the national median voter (Wood 2009). Equally, a universalistic president might decide to support specific districts out of universalistic rather than parochial motives. For the purposes of the present paper, we assume the simple case.
Our estimates are similar quantitatively when outliers are included.
We use an almost identical specification, and arrive at very similar results. Using Berry et al.(2010)’s specification yields identical results
We follow Berry et al. and assess the effect of the president on the budget for the following year. For that reason, 1993 is classified as being under a Republican president, while 2001 is classified as being under a Democratic president. Changing that assumption does not affect the results significantly.
Note that the subperiods are defined using a lag of one year. For example, Bill Clinton’s term is treated as beginning in 1994 and not 1993, since the federal budget for 1993 already was in place when Clinton entered office.
For the regressions at hand, we rely on the federal spending data from the FAADS+ database, which is available for 2000–2014. Since we use a smaller and more disaggregated sample and do not need to compare the results below with the original Berry et al. results, we do not drop outliers from the specifications.
Net federal outlays went from $3517 billion in 2009 (the last fiscal year decided by Bush) to $3686 billion in 2015, in current prices. During a similar period, George W. Bush increased spending from $2159 billion (in 2003) to $3517 billion (in 2009) (source: Fred, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/FYONET).
References
Albouy, D. (2013). Partisan representation in Congress and the geographic distribution of federal funds. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95, 127–141.
Alvarez, R. M., & Saving, J. L. (1997a). Congressional committees and the political economy of federal outlays. Public Choice, 92, 55–73.
Alvarez, R. M., & Saving, J. L. (1997b). Deficits, democrats, and distributive benefits: congressional elections and the pork barrel in the 1980s. Political Research Quarterly, 50, 809–831.
Arnold, R. D. (1997). Congress and the bureaucracy: A theory of influence. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Arulampalam, W., Dasgupta, S., Dhillon, A., & Dutta, B. (2009). Electoral goals and center-state transfers: a theoretical model and empirical evidence from India. Journal of Development Economics, 88, 103–119.
Asher, S., & Novosad, P. (2017). Politics and local economic growth: Evidence from India. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 9(1), 229–273.
Baskaran, T., & Hessami, Z. (2017). Political alignment and intergovernmental transfers in parliamentary systems: Evidence from germany. Public Choice, 171, 75–98.
Berry, C. R., Burden, B. C., & Howell, W. G. (2010). The president and the distribution of federal spending. American Political Science Review, 104, 783–799.
Berry, C. R., & Gersen, J. E. (2017). Agency design and political control. Yale Law Review, 126, 1002–1049.
Bertelli, A. M., & Grose, C. R. (2009). Secretaries of pork? A new theory of distributive public policy. Journal of Politics, 71, 926–945.
Bond, J. R., & Fleisher, R. (1990). The president in the legislative arena. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Brollo, F., & Nannicini, T. (2012). Tying your enemy’s hands in close races: the politics of federal transfers in Brazil. American Political Science Review, 106, 742–761.
Cain, B., Ferejohn, J., & Fiorina, M. (1987). The personal vote: Constituency service and electoral independence. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Couch, J. F., & Shugart, W. F. (1998). The political economy of the New Deal. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Couch, J. F., & Shugart, W. F. (2000). New Deal spending and the states: The politics of public works. In J. Heckelman, J. Moorhouse, & R. Whaples (Eds.), Public choice interpretations of American economic history (pp. 105–122). Boston: Kluwer Academic.
Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1986). Electoral politics as a redistributive game. Journal of Politics, 48, 370–389.
Cox, W. G. (2009). Swing voters, core voters, and distributive politics. In I. Shapiro, S. C. Stokes, E. J. Wood, & A. S. Kirshner (Eds.), Political representation (pp. 342–357). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Crespin, M. H., & Finocchiaro, C. J. (2013). lections and the politics of pork in the us senate. Social Science Quarterly, 94, 506–529.
Cronin, T. E., & Genovese, M. A. (2004). Paradoxes of the American Presidency. New York: Oxford University Press.
Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1998). Fiscal federalism and redistributive politics. Journal of Public Economics, 68, 153–180.
Dynes, A. M., & Huber, G. A. (2015). Partisanship and the allocation of federal spending: Do same-party legislators or voters benefit from shared party affiliation with the President and House majority? American Political Science Review, 109, 172–186.
Evans, D. (2004). Greasing the wheels: Using pork barrel projects to build majority coalitions in Congress. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Ferejohn, J. A. (1974). Pork barrel politics: Rivers and harbors legislation, 1947–1968. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Galvin, D. J. (2009). Presidential party building: Dwight D. New Jersey: Eisenhower to George W. Bush. Princton University Press.
Garret, T. A., & Sobel, R. S. (2003). The political economy of FEMA disaster payment. Economic Inquiry, 41, 496–509.
Groseclose, T., & Snyder, J. M. J. (1996). Buying supermajorities. American Poltical Science Review, 90, 303–315.
Haselswerdt, J., & Bartels, B. L. (2015). Public opinion, policy tools, and the status quo: Evidence from a survey experiment. Political Research Quarterly, 68, 607–621.
Heitshusen, V. (2001). The allocation of federal money to house committee members: Distributive theory and policy jurisdictions. American Politics Research, 29, 79–97.
Hoddie, M., & Routh, S. R. (2004). Predicting the presidential presence. Political Research Quarterly, 57, 257–265.
Hudak, J. (2014). Presidential pork: White House influence over the distribution of federal grants. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Jacobson, G. C., Kernell, S., & Lazarus, J. (2004). Assessing the president’s role as party agent in Congressional elections: The case of Bill Clinton in 2000. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 29, 159–184.
Knight, B. (2002). Endogenous federal grants and crowd-out of state government spending: Theory and evidence from the federal highway aid program. American Economic Review, 92, 71–92.
Knight, B. (2004). Parochial interests and the centralized provision of local public goods: Evidence from congressional voting on transportation projects. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 845–866.
Kriner, D. L., & Reeves, A. (2015a). The particularistc president: Executive branch politics and political inequality. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Kriner, D. L., & Reeves, A. (2015b). Presidential particularism and divide-the-dollar politics. American Political Science Review, 109, 155–171.
Kriner, D. L., & Reeves, Y. (2012). The influence of federal spending on presidential elections. American Political Science Review, 106, 348–366.
Larcinese, V., Rizzo, L., & Testa, C. (2006). Allocating the us federal budget to the states: The impact of the president. Journal of Politics, 68, 447–456.
Lazarus, J., & Reilly, S. (2010). The electoral benefits of distributive spending. Political Research Quarterly, 63, 343–355.
Lee, F. E. (2003). Geographic politics in the US House of Representatives: Coalition building and the distribution of benefits. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 714–728.
Levitt, S., & Snyder, J. (1995). Political parties and the distribution of federal outlays. American Journal of Political Science, 39, 958–980.
Levitt, S., & Snyder, J. (1997). The impact of federal spending on House election outcomes. Journal of Political Economy, 105, 30–53.
Lewis, D. E. (2008). The politics of presidential appointments: Political control and bureaucratic performace. Princton: Princton University Press.
Lindbeck, A., & Weibull, J. (1987). Balanced budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice, 52, 273–297.
Pettersson-Lidbom, P. (2008). Do parties matter for economic outcomes? A regression-discontinuity approach. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6, 1037–1056.
Reingewertz, Y. (2014). Fiscal decentralization – a survey of the empirical literature. Mimeo (University of Haifa). https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2523335.
Rich, M. J. (1989). Distributive politics and the allocation of federal grants. American Political Science Review, 83, 193–213.
Rogowski, J. C. (2016). Presidential influence in an era of Congressional dominance. American Political Science Review, 110, 325–341.
Sellers, P. J. (1997). Fiscal consistency and federal district spending in congressional elections. American Journal of Political Science, 41, 1024–1041.
Sidman, A., & Mak, M.H. (2006). Pork, awareness, and ideological consistency: The effects of distributive benefits on vote choice. In Annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association (pp. 20–23).
Sollé Ollé, A. (2003). Electoral accountability and tax mimicking: The effects of electoral margins, coalition government, and ideology. European Journal of Political Economy, 19, 685–713.
Stein, R. M., & Bickers, K. N. (1994). Universalism and the electoral connection: A test and some doubts. Political Research Quarterly, 47, 295–317.
Wallis, J. J. (2010). Lessons from the political economy of the new deal. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 26, 442–462.
Wallis, J. J., Fishback, P. V., & Kantor, S. E. (2006). Politics, relief, and reform: Roosevelt’s efforts to control corruption and political manipulation during the New Deal. In Edward L. Glaeser & Claudia Goldin (Eds.), Corruption and reform: Lessons from america’s economic history. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Wood, D. B. (2009). The myth of presidential representation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Young, M., Reksulak, M., & Shughart, W. F. (2001). The political economy of the IRS. Economics & Politics, 13, 201–220.
Acknowledgements
We wish to thank participants at the Israeli Economic Association annual meeting, as well as seminar participants at the school of Political Science at Tel Aviv University for helpfull comments and suggestions. We would also like to thank Christofer Berry, Barry Burden and William Howell for sharing their data with us.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Reingewertz, Y., Baskaran, T. Distributive spending and presidential partisan politics. Public Choice 185, 65–85 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00740-1
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00740-1
Keywords
- Distributive spending
- President
- Congress
- Partisan alignment
- Democrats
- Republicans
JEL Classification:
- H10
- H40
- H50