Skip to main content
Log in

Beyond market failure and government failure

Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Cite this article

Abstract

Criticisms of market outcomes often rest upon a notion of ‘market failure,’ meaning that the market has failed to align incentives and knowledge to produce an optimal outcome. Rejoinders to classic market failure arguments have taken several forms: that there are institutional or contracting solutions to various forms of market failures, that optimality is not a reasonable goal for real world economic activity, or that government may fail as well. Similarly, Wittman (The myth of democratic failure, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1995) and others have argued that concepts of government failure are equally problematic as the ordinary forces of political competition may render politicians sufficiently accountable to achieve realistically defined standards of efficiency. Even thinkers like Buchanan imagine that constitutional design may allow politics to fend off its tendency to become a zero-sum game. Both concepts are problematic in a world of entangled political economy in which market and government activity are interconnected. We argue that it is time to abandon both ‘market failure’ and ‘government failure,’ and instead focus on problems of institutional mismatch, when the rules governing interaction are ill-suited to the problems that agents confront.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. Arrow (1951) and Downs (1957) published their work before Bator (1958) and Samuelson (1954), while Black (1958), and ultimately Buchanan and Tullock (1962) as well as Olson (1965) appeared shortly afterwards. See also Medema (2009, Chaptert 4) on the Italian Tradition of Public Finance in economics.

  2. Hall et al. (2018) find that most (upper level) undergraduate public economics textbooks cover rent-seeking in varying degrees of detail. On the other hand, rent-seeking receives zero coverage in graduate-level public economics textbooks. Receives zero coverage in graduate level public economics textbooks. Llyalk actually matters, arguing that standard models assu.

  3. A simpler and ubiquitous method of property delineation is the practice of fencing. To see a discussion of land enclosure via fencing in the American west with the introduction of low-cost barbed wire fencing, see Anderson and Hill (1975).

  4. Van Zandt (1993) and Bertrand (2006) push back against claims made by Coase.

  5. Examples include childcare (Mocan 2001), labor (Gibbons and Katz 1991), credit (Ausubel 1991), insurance (Puelz and Snow 1994; Chiappori and Salanie 2000), capital (Booth and Smith 1986), and automobiles (Bond 1982; Genesove 1993).

  6. For an empirical examination of market-provided warranties in used car markets, see Mann and Holdych (1996). For similar studies using laboratory experiments, see Holt and Sherman (1990).

  7. This is the main reason we have not explicitly addressed monopoly as a form of market failure. Antitrust policy and regulation of natural monopolies are obviously institutional solutions to purported problems. It is worth noting, however, that monopoly has probably become less of a concern in the academic literature on market failure, owing to insights about contestability (Demsetz 1982), and that it is unclear whether anti-trust policy is a an effective solution to concentrations of market power that do exist (Shughart and McChesney 2010; Young and Shughart 2010). Moreover, whether monopoly generates inefficiency also depends on controversial behavioral assumptions, such as whether monopolists act as Cournot or Bertrand competitors.

  8. Pasour (1987, p. 123) argues against the claim that rent-seeking is a government failure, pointing to the fact “that rent-seeking waste can only be identified by substituting the observer's own standard of value.”

  9. Similarly, Salter and Young (2017) compare governance institutions in England and France. Their research highlights the importance of assembly representation in the development of the rule of law in the former as well as differences in their effect on economic institutions in both countries.

  10. See, for example, Brennan and Buchanan (1980, 1985) and Buchanan and Congleton (2003).

  11. Spreadsheet available here (link).

  12. Despite the advantages we enumerate in the proceeding section, then, mismatch talk does not allow us to evade the problem of the second best (Lipsey and Lancaster 1956). Rather, it transfers that problem from the domain of interacting policies to the domain of interacting institutions.

  13. Governance likewise may be about more than determining rules, so that the two concepts would be overlapping rather than proper subsets. Governance failure could include the misallocation of resources within an institutional framework and not only the inept design of an institutional framework.

  14. A popular example is that of controls on fluid milk. See, for example, Ippolito and Masson (1978), Helmberger and Helmberger (1994) and Johnson (1985).

  15. This is also an advantage for an “efficiency always” perspective. Leeson (2018) “bites the bullet”, arguing that since institutions are the result of maximizing behavior, they must be efficient. Our argument is orthogonal to his. Even he allows a role for economists to “improve the world” by shifting relative prices through costly action and lowering others’ search costs for better institutions. In his approach, such actions change what is efficient rather than closing the gap between what is efficient and what simply is. He also distinguishes sharply between efficiency and wealth generation. Though we have used the language of inefficiency throughout because it is standard, mismatch talk works both for analyzing the non-efficiency properties of institutions (such as how much wealth they generate), or as a talk strategy for Leeson’s “inside the model” economists who shift was is efficient.

References

  • Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1973). The property rights paradigm. The Journal of Economic History, 33(1), 16–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (1975). The evolution of property rights: A study of the American west. Journal of Law and Economics, 18, 163–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (1980). The birth of a transfer society. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1951). Social choice and individual values. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ausubel, L. M. (1991). The failure of competition in the credit card market. American Economic Review, 81(1), 50–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, J. (2013). Who pays for obesity? evidence from health insurance benefit mandates. Economics Letters, 121(2), 287–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartels, L. M. (1996). Uninformed votes: Information effects in presidential elections. American Journal of Political Science, 40(1), 194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bator, F. M. (1958). The anatomy of market failure. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72(3), 351.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baysinger, B., Ekelund, R. B. J., & Tollison, R. D. (1980). Mercantilism as a rent-seekign society. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent seeking society (pp. 235–268). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (1989). The spontaneous evolution of commercial law. Southern Economic Journal, 5513311(3), 644–661.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (1991). An evolutionary contractarian view of primitive law: The institutions and incentives arising under customary Indian law. The Review of Austrian Economics, 5(1), 41–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (2010). It takes two invisible hands to make a market: Lex Mercatoria (Law Merchant) always emerges to facilitate emerging market activity. Studies in Emergent Order, 3, 100–128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (2011). The enterprise of law: Justice without the state (2nd ed.). Oakland: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, E. (2006). The Coasean analysis of lighthouse financing: Myths and realities. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30(3), 389–402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (2006). Principled agents: The political economy of good government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Coyne, C. J. (2009). Context matters: Institutions and entrepreneurship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 5(3), 133–209.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2008). Institutional stickiness and the new development economics. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 67(2), 331–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2011). Quasimarket failure. Public Choice, 149(1–2), 209–224.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bond, E. W. (1982). A direct test of the “lemons” model: The market for used pickup trucks. American Economic Review, 72(4), 836–840.

    Google Scholar 

  • Booth, J. R., & Smith, R. I. (1986). Capital raising, underwriting and the certification hypothesis. Journal of Financial Economics, 15(1–2), 261–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytic foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1985). The reason of rules: Constitutional political economy. The collected works of James M. Buchanan (Vol. 10). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1959). Positive economics, welfare economics, and political economy. The Journal of Law and Economics, 2, 124–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1962). The relevance of pareto optimality. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 6(4), 341–354.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1979). Politics without romance: A sketch of positive public choice theory and its normative implications. IHS Journal, Zeitschrift des Instituts für Höhere Studien. Vienna, Austria: Institute for Advanced Studies, B1–B11.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1980). Rent seeking and profit seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent seeking society (pp. 3–15). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1997). Who cares whether the commons are privatized? Post-socialist political economy: Selected essays (pp. 160–167). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (2000). The limits of liberty: Between anarchy and leviathan (Liberty Fu). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (2008). Same players, different game: How better rules make better politics. Constitutional Political Economy, 19(3), 171–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Congleton, R. D. (2003). Politics by principle, not interest: Toward nondiscriminatory democracy. The collected works of James M. Buchanan (Vol. 11). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, R. J. (2010). Macroeconomics after the crisis: Time to deal with the pretense-of-knowledge syndrome. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(4), 85–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, C. D. (1994). New Hampshire’s tax-base limits: An example of the leviathan model. Public Choice, 78(2), 129–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Candela, R. A., & Geloso, V. J. (2018). The lightship in economics. Public Choice, 176(3–4), 479–506.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B., & Miller, S. C. (2010). Intelligence makes people think like economists: Evidence from the general social survey. Intelligence, 38(6), 636–647.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cebula, R. J. (1990). A brief empirical note on the tiebout hypothesis and state income tax policies. Public Choice, 67(1), 87–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. N. S. (1973). The fable of the bees: An economic investigation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 11–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chezum, B., & Wimmer, B. (1997). Roses or lemons: Adverse selection in the market for thoroughbred yearlings. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(3), 521–526.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chezum, B., & Wimmer, B. S. (2000). Evidence of adverse selection from thoroughbred wagering. Southern Economic Journal, 66(3), 700–714.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P., & Salanie, B. (2000). Testing for asymmetric information in insurance markets. Journal of Political Economy, 108(1), 56–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1), 1–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1974). The lighthouse in economics. The Journal of Law and Economics, 17(2), 357–376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1992). The institutional structure of production. The American Economic Review, 82(4), 713–719.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (2013). The federal communications commission. The Journal of Law and Economics, 56(4), 879–915.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1966). Some aspects of property rights. The Journal of Law and Economics, 9, 61–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1969). Information and efficiency: Another viewpoint. The Journal of Law and Economics, 12(1), 1–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1974). Toward a theory of property rights. Classic papers in natural resource economics (pp. 163–177). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1982). Barriers to entry. American Economic Review, 72(1), 47–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). And economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson, R. C. (1991). Order without the law: How neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fike, R., & Gwartney, J. (2015). Public choice, market failure, and government failure in principles textbooks. The Journal of Economic Education, 46(2), 207–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1994). A positive account of property rights. Social Philosophy and Policy, 11(2), 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genesove, D. (1993). Adverse selection in the wholesale used car market. Journal of Political Economy, 101(4), 644–665.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, R., & Katz, L. T. (1991). Layoffs and lemons. Journal of Labor Economics, 9, 351–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1990). Trade, innovation, and growth. American Economic Review, 80(2), 86–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, J., Matti, J., & Ferreira Neto, A. B. (2018). Rent-seeking in the classroom and textbooks: Where are we after 50 years? Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0563-z.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1948). The economic conditions of interstate federalism. In individualism and economic order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1973). Law, legislation and liberty. Rules and order (Vol. 1). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helmberger, H., & Helmberger, P. (1994). Economic effects of U.S. dairy programs. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 19(2), 225–238.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L., & Ursprung, H. W. (2000). Political culture and economic decline. European Journal of Political Economy, 16(2), 189–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C., & Sherman, R. (1990). Advertising and product quality in posted-offer experiments. Economic Inquiry, 28(1), 39–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume, D. (1777). Of the first principles of government. In E. F. Miller (Ed.), Essays: Moral, political, and literary (pp. 32–36). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ippolito, R. A., & Masson, R. T. (1978). The social cost of government regulation of milk. The Journal of Law and Economics, 21(1), 33–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, R. N. (1985). Retail price controls in the dairy industry: A political coalition argument. The Journal of Law and Economics, 28(1), 55–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, P., & Hudson, J. (1998). The role of political parties: An analysis based on transaction costs. Public Choice, 94(1/2), 175–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keech, W. R., & Munger, M. C. (2015). The anatomy of government failure. Public Choice, 164(1–2), 1–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1998). Coordination as a criterion for economic “goodness”. Constitutional Political Economy, 9(4), 289–301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, D. B. (1990). The voluntary provision of public goods? The turnpike companies of early America. Economic Inquiry, 28(4), 788–812.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klick, J., & Stratmann, T. (2007). Diabetes treatments and moral hazard. The Journal of Law and Economics, 50(3), 519–538.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. H. (1924). Some fallacies in the interpretation of social cost. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 38(4), 582.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. The American Economic Review, 64, 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. (1977). Capital, expectations and the market process. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews & McMeel Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2013). Gypsy law. Public Choice, 155(3–4), 273–292.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2014). “God damn”: The law and economics of monastic malediction. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 30(1), 193–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2018). Logic is a harsh mistress: Welfare claims for believers in economics.

  • Leeson, P. T., & Harris, C. (2018). Wealth-destroying private property rights. World Development, 107, 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J., & Margolis, S. E. (2002). Beta, Macintosh and other fabulous tales. In T. Cowen & E. Crampton (Eds.), Market failure or success: The new debate (pp. 195–207). Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R. G., & Lancaster, K. (1956). The general theory of second best. The Review of Economic Studies, 24(1), 11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lopez, R. A., & Pagoulatos, E. (1994). Rent seeking and the welfare cost of trade barriers. Public Choice, 79(1–2), 149–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, G. (2015). Principles of economics (8th ed.). Mason, OH: Cengage Learning.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mann, B., & Holdych, T. J. (1996). When lemons are better than lemonade: The case against mandatory used car warranties. Yale Law & Policy Review, 15, 1–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markovits, R. S. (1993). A constructive critique of the traditional definition and use of the concept of the effect of a choice on allocative (economic) efficiency: Why the Kaldor-Hicks test, the Coase theorem, and virtually all law-and-economics welfare arguments are wrong. University of Illinois Law Review, 1993(3), 485–534.

    Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F. S. (1986). Government prohibitions on volunteer fire fighting in nineteenth-century America: A property rights perspective. The Journal of Legal Studies, 15(1), 69–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. N. (2016). Max u versus humanomics: A critique of neo-institutionalism. Journal of Institutional Economics, 12(1), 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R. E., & Tollison, R. D. (1981). Politicians, legislation, and the economy. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meade, J. E. (1952). External economies and diseconomies in a competitive situation. The Economic Journal, 62(245), 54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Medema, S. G. (2009). The hesitant hand: Taming self-interest in the history of economic ideas. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mocan, N. H. (2001). Can consumers detect lemons? Information asymmetry in the market for child care. NBER working paper.

  • Murphy, L., & Nagel, T. (2002). The myth of ownership: Taxes and justice. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Why is rent-seeking so costly to growth? American Economic Review, 83(2), 409–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, M. A. (1986). An empirical analysis of state and local tax structure in the context of the leviathan model of government. Public Choice, 49(3), 283–294.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. J. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orbell, J. M., & Uno, T. (1972). A theory of neighborhood problem solving: Political action vs. residential mobility. American Political Science Review, 66(2), 471–489.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutional forms of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review, 100(3), 641–672.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Gardner, R., & Walker, J. (1994). Fishers’ institutional responses to common-pool resource dilemmas. Rules, games, & common-pool resources (pp. 247–265). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., & Kiser, L. L. (2000). The three worlds of action: A metatheoretical synthesis of institutional approaches. In M. D. McGinnis (Ed.), Polycentric games and institutions: Readings from the workshop in political theory and policy analysis. Michigan: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., & Parks, R. B. (1987). Neither gargantua nor the land of lilliputs: Conjectures on mixed systems of metropolitan organization. In M. D. McGinnis (Ed.), Polycentricity and local public economies: Readings from the workshop in political theory and policy analysis (pp. 285–305). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., & Walker, J. (1997). Neither markets nor states: Linking transformation processes in collective action arenas. In D. C. Mueller (Ed.), Perspectives on public choice: A handbook (pp. 35–72). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasour, E. C. (1987). Rent seeking: Some conceptual problems and implications. The Review of Austrian Economics, 1(1), 123–143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1912). Wealth and welfare. London: Macmillan and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1920). The economics of welfare (4th ed.). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Puelz, R., & Snow, A. (1994). Evidence on adverse selection: Equilibrium signaling and cross-subsidization in the insurance market. Journal of Political Economy, 102(2), 236–257.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. (2009). Myth of efficiency. Economic Policy, 4, 200–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salter, A. W., & Young, A. T. (2017). Medieval representative assemblies: Collective action and antecedents of limited government. Constitutional Political Economy, 29, 171–192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1948). Economics: An introductory analysis. New York: McGraw-Hill Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Satz, D. (2010). Why some things should not be for sale: The moral limits of markets. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmith Conway, K., & Houtenville, A. J. (1998). Do the elderly “vote with their feet?”. Public Choice, 97(4), 663–685.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F., II, & McChesney, F. S. (2010). Public choice theory and anti-trust policy. Public Choice, 142(3/4), 385–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (1989). Theory, experiment and economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(1), 151–169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (1994). Economics in the laboratory. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(1), 113–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L., Williams, A. W., Bratton, W. K., & Vannoni, M. G. (1982). Competitive market institutions: Double auctions vs sealed bid-offer auctions. The American Economic Review, 72(1), 58–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. P. (2001). Kaldor-Hicks efficiency and the problem of central planning. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 4(2), 41–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. The Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1959). Problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy, 67(6), 571.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Economic Inquiry, 5(3), 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1975). The transitional gains trap. The Bell Journal of Economics, 6(2), 671.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2005a). Bureaucracy. (C. K. Rowley, Ed.). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Tullock, G. (2005b). Rent seeking. In C. K. Rowly (Ed.), The Rent-Seeking Society (pp. 11–82). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Vleck, V. N. L. (1997). Delivering coal by road and rail in Britain: The efficiency of the “silly little bobtailed” coal wagons. The Journal of Economic History, 57(1), 139–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Zandt, D. E. (1993). The lessons of the lighthouse: “Government” or “private” provision of goods. The Journal of Legal Studies, 22(1), 47–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2012). Deficits, debt, and democracy: Wrestling with tragedy on the fiscal commons. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2016). Politics as a peculiar business: Insights from a theory of entangled political economy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 11(1), 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wimmer, B. S., & Chezum, B. (2003). An empirical examination of quality certification in a “lemons market”. Economic Inquiry, 41(2), 279–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), 1395–1424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1995). The myth of democratic failure. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. T., & Shughart, W. F., II. (2010). The consequences of the US DOJ’s antitrust activities: A macroeconomic perspective. Public Choice, 142(3/4), 409–422.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adam Martin.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (XLSX 20 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Furton, G., Martin, A. Beyond market failure and government failure. Public Choice 178, 197–216 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0623-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0623-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation