Advertisement

Titles for me but not for thee: transitional gains trap of property rights extension in Colombia

  • Perry Ferrell
Article

Abstract

I apply Tullock’s transitional gains trap to the formalization of property titles in Latin America to understand public choice problems in mending institutions. In an area where land is owned by formal and informal institutions, policies to extend property rights will not be supported by voters holding legal title because it will devalue their property. To test this I use data from Colombia where a peace deal to end a 50-year conflict with Revolutionary Armed Forces of Colombia rebels was reached in 2016 and put to a public referendum. The deal included formalization of property titles across the nation as well as an end to the conflict. Using municipal-level data on voting and property ownership and controlling for conflict history, I find potential losses to formal property holders pushed median voter preferences toward dissension. A 1% increase in legally titled land increases dissenting vote share by 3% points. These results are relevant to institutional reforms anywhere with corrupted property rights.

Keywords

Referendum Property rights Violence Transitional gains trap 

JEL Classification

D72 D74 

Notes

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank Josh Hall, Bryan McCannon, Lynne Kiesling, Bonnie Wilson, Michael Munger, two anonymous referees, and many helpful insights from commenters at Public Choice Society, Southern Economic Association, and American Institute of Economic Research meetings and the Universidad de Los Andes CEDE for data assistance.

References

  1. Acemoglu, D. (2006). A simple model of inefficient institutions. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(4), 515–546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2005). Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), 949–995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Acevedo, K., & Bornacelly, I. (2016). Panel municipal del CEDE. Centro de Estudios sobre Desarrollo Económico.Google Scholar
  4. Albertus, M., & Kaplan, O. (2013). Land reform as a counterinsurgency policy. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(2), 198–231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Alpert, M. (2016). Politics roils Colombia’s tentative peace deal with the FARC. https://foreignpolicy.com/2016/07/18/politics-roils-colombias-tentative-peace-deal-with-the-farc-eln-santos-uribe/.
  6. Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., & Mueller, B. (1999). A model of rural conflict: Violence and land reform policy in Brazil. Environment and Development Economics, 4(2), 135–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., & Mueller, B. (2000). Land reform policies, the sources of violent conflict, and implications for deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 39(2), 162–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Benson, B. L. (1988). Legal evolution in primitive societies. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 144, 772–788.Google Scholar
  9. Benson, B. L., & Siddiqui, Z. R. (2014). Pashtunwali-law for the lawless, defense for the stateless. International Review of Law and Economics, 37, 108–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Besley, T. (1995). Property rights and investment incentives: Theory and evidence from Ghana. Journal of Political Economy, 103(5), 903–937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Brasselle, A.-S., Gaspart, F., & Platteau, J.-P. (2002). Land tenure security and investment incentives: Puzzling evidence from Burkina Faso. Journal of Development Economics, 67(2), 373–418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Brittain, J. J. (2010). Revolutionary social change in Colombia: The origin and direction of the FARC-EP. London: Pluto Press.Google Scholar
  13. Brunner, E., Sonstelie, J., & Thayer, M. (2001). Capitalization and the voucher: An analysis of precinct returns from California’s Proposition 174. Journal of Urban Economics, 50(3), 517–536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Chen, C. (2017). Untitled land, occupational choice, and agricultural productivity. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 9(4), 91–121.Google Scholar
  15. Colombian State Department. (2016). Election results.Google Scholar
  16. De Janvry, A., Emerick, K., Gonzalez-Navarro, M., & Sadoulet, E. (2015). Delinking land rights from land use: Certification and migration in Mexico. The American Economic Review, 105(10), 3125–3149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. De Soto, H. (1989). The other path: The economic answer to terrorism. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  18. De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else. New York: Basic Civitas Books.Google Scholar
  19. Dehring, C. A., Depken, C. A., & Ward, M. R. (2008). A direct test of the homevoter hypothesis. Journal of Urban Economics, 64(1), 155–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Di Tella, R., Galiant, S., & Schargrodsky, E. (2007). The formation of beliefs: Evidence from the allocation of land titles to squatters. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(1), 209–241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Fajardo, D. (2002). La tierra y el poder político; la reforma agraria y la reforma rural en Colombia. Revista Reforma Agraria Colonización y Cooperativas, 1, 4–20.Google Scholar
  22. Field, E. (2007). Entitled to work: Urban property rights and labor supply in Peru. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(4), 1561–1602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Fischel, W. A. (2001). The homevoter hypothesis: How home values influence local government taxation, school finance, and land-use policies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Galiani, S., & Schargrodsky, E. (2010). Property rights for the poor: Effects of land titling. Journal of Public Economics, 94(9), 700–729.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Glaeser, E., Scheinkman, J., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The injustice of inequality. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(1), 199–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Goldstein, M., & Udry, C. (2008). The profits of power: Land rights and agricultural investment in Ghana. Journal of Political Economy, 116(6), 981–1022.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Grusczynski, D. M., & Jaramillo, C. F. (2002). Integrating land issues into the broader development agenda. Bogotá: Case Study.Google Scholar
  28. Ibanez, A. M. (2009). Forced displacement in Colombia: Magnitude and causes. The Economics of Peace and Security Journal, 4(1), 48–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Janvry, A. D., Gonzalez-Navarro, M., & Sadoulet, E. (2014). Are land reforms granting complete property rights politically risky? Electoral outcomes of Mexico’s certification program. Journal of Development Economics, 110, 216–225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Kerekes, C. B., & Williamson, C. R. (2010). Propertyless in Peru, even with a government land title. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 69(3), 1011–1033.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Leech, G. M. (2011). The FARC: The longest insurgency. Rebels: Fernwood.Google Scholar
  32. Leeson, P. T. (2007). Trading with bandits. The Journal of Law and Economics, 50(2), 303–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Leeson, P. T. (2009). The laws of lawlessness. The Journal of Legal Studies, 38(2), 471–503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Leeson, P. T. (2012). God Damn: The law and economics of monastic malediction. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 30(1), 193–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Leeson, P. T. (2013). Gypsy law. Public Choice, 155(3–4), 273–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Leeson, P. T., & Harris, C. (2018). Wealth-destroying private property rights. World Development, 107, 1–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Levy-Carciente, S. (2017). International property rights index. Property Rights Alliance.Google Scholar
  38. Murtazashvili, I., & Murtazashvili, J. (2015). Anarchy, self-governance, and legal titling. Public Choice, 162(3), 287–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Olson, M. (2008). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  40. Otis, J. (2014). The FARC and Colombia’s illegal drug trade. Woodrow Wilson Center: Encyclopedia of U.S.-Latin American Relations.Google Scholar
  41. Palacios, P. (2012). Forced displacement: Legal versus illegal crops. Defence and Peace Economics, 23(2), 133–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Registro Único de Víctimas. (2016). Colombian register of victims report.Google Scholar
  43. Richani, N. (2013). Systems of violence: The political economy of war and peace in Colombia. New York: Suny Press.Google Scholar
  44. Robinson, J. A. (2016). La miseria en Colombia. Revista Desarrollo y Sociedad, 76, 9–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Santos Calderón, J. M., & Jiménez, T. (2016). Acuerdo Final Para la Terminación del Conflicti y la Construcción de una Paz Estable y Duradera. Oficina del Alto Comisionado para la Paz.Google Scholar
  46. Skaperdas, S. (1992). Cooperation, conflict, and power in the absence of property rights. The American Economic Review, 82(4), 720–739.Google Scholar
  47. Sonin, K. (2003). Why the rich may favor poor protection of property rights. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 715–731.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Stringham, E. (2015). Private governance: Creating order in economic and social life. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Tullock, G. (1975). The transitional gains trap. The Bell Journal of Economics, 6, 671–678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Williamson, C. R., & Mathers, R. L. (2011). Economic freedom, culture, and growth. Public Choice, 148(3), 313–335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. World Values Survey Association. (2010–2014). World value survey wave 6. World Value Survey.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.West Virginia UniversityMorgantownUSA

Personalised recommendations