Abstract
This paper critically discusses the standard concept of hierarchical preferences, which presupposes that a stable system of higher- and lower-order preferences exists, wherein the former contains an individual’s fundamental purposes and values, while the latter guides everyday choices. It is argued that systems of hierarchical preferences suffer from problems similar to those of standard preferences, in terms of rationality, that they also are potentially unstable and can change, for example, in response to individual experiences. It is furthermore argued that higher-order preferences may not be coherent internally, because their different parts result from different kinds of reasoning. Finally, it is argued that behavioral economic policies, such as soft paternalism, easily can endanger the autonomy and integrity of an individual as a person.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
This line of thought was taken up later by Dworkin (1988), who also argues that critical reflection about one’s own goals is what makes somebody an autonomous person.
See, e.g., Varian (2012) for a recent demonstration of an application of revealed preference theory.
The claim is criticized in particular by Gigerenzer (2008), who argues on empirical grounds that heuristics frequently help humans in making good decisions.
The first application of this line of thought in political economics probably was introduced by Tullock (1971).
See, in particular, Hillman (2010), who relates expressive behavior to questions of identity.
However, and relatedly, individuals can in some instances also be driven so strongly by identity-based (and similar to expressive) motives, that they incur substantial costs in order to support their identity, once they have chosen it; see, e.g., Akerlof and Kranton (2000).
Of course, the mere act of expressive voting also is associated with opportunity cost, e.g., of time and transport to the voting booth. This point has been made by an anonymous referee.
White (2013) was to my knowledge the first scholar to introduce this argument into the discussion of behavioral economic policies.
This is akin to Stigler and Becker (1977), where individuals do have stable preferences for some basic commodities, but change their preferences for consumption goods if they learn about their effectiveness in producing basic commodities.
Witt (2011) makes a smiliar argument in a framework of reinforcement learning.
See also Earl and Potts (2004) for a theory on acquiring preferences from other individuals whom one trusts and whose choices (or even lifestyle) one imitates.
References
Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 715–753.
Arad, A., & Rubinstein, A. (2017). The people’s perspective on libertarian-paternalist policies. Working Paper. Tel Aviv: Tel Aviv University.
Benabou, R., & Pycia, M. (2002). Dynamic inconsistency and self-control: A planner-doer intepretation. Economics Letters, 77, 419–424.
Bennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and decision: The pure theory of electoral politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bhagarva, S., & Loewenstein, G. (2015). Behavioral economics and public policy 102: Beyond nudging. American Economic Review P&P, 105, 396–401.
Bovens, L. (2009). The ethics of nudge. In T. Grüne-Yanoff & S. Hansson (Eds.), Preference change. Approaches from philosophy, economics and psychology (pp. 207–219). New York: Springer.
Brennan, G. (2012). Politics-as-exchange and the calculus of consent. Public Choice, 152, 351–358.
Brennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1983). Institutional aspects of “merit goods” analysis. Finanzarchiv, 41, 183–206.
Buchanan, J. M. (1999). The foundations for normative individualism. In J. M. Buchanan (Ed.), The logical foundations of constitutional liberty. Collected works (Vol. 1, pp. 282–291). Indianapolis: The Liberty Fund.
Chetty, R. (2015). Behavioral economics and public policy: A pragmatic perspective. American Economic Review P&P, 105, 1–33.
Deci, E. L., & Ryan, R. M. (2000). The “what” and “why” of goal pursuits: Human needs and the self-determination of behavior. Psychological Inquiry, 11, 227–268.
Deci, E. L., & Ryan, R. M. (2012). Motivation, personality and development within embedded social contexts: An overview of self-determination theory. In R. M. Ryan (Ed.), Oxford handbook of human motivation (pp. 85–107). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Dworkin, G. (1988). The theory and practice of autonomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Earl, P. E., & Potts, J. (2004). The market for preferences. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28, 619–633.
Falk, A., Becker, A., Dohmen, T., Enke, B., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2018). Global evidence on economic preferences. Discussion paper series of the collaborative research center Transregio 224. Bonn: University of Bonn.
Frankfurt, H. G. (1971). Freedom of the will and the concept of a person. Journal of Philosophy, 68, 5–20.
Frey, B. S. (2008). Happiness: A revolution in economics. Cambridge (Mass.): MIT Press.
Frey, B. S., Benz, M., & Stutzer, A. (2004). Introducing procedural utility. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 160, 377–401.
Gigerenzer, G. (2008). Rationality for mortals. How people cope with uncertainty. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Gul, F., & Pesendorfer, W. (2001). Temptation and self-control. Econometrica, 69, 1404–1435.
Hagman, W., Andersson, A., Västfjäll, D., & Tinghög, G. (2015). Public views on policies involving nudges. Review of Philosophy and Psychology, 6, 439–453.
Hamlin, A., & Jennings, C. (2011). Expressive political behaviour: Foundations, scope and implications. British Journal of Political Science, 41, 645–670.
Hertwig, R., & Grüne-Yanoff, T. (2017). Nudging and boosting: Steering or empowering good decisions. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 12, 973–986.
Hillman, A. (2010). Expressive behavior in economics and politics. European Journal of Political Economy, 26, 403–418.
Hirschman, A. O. (1984). Against parsimony: Three easy ways of complicating some categories of economic discourse. American Economic Review, 74, 89–96.
Infante, G., Lecouteux, G., & Sugden, R. (2017). Preference purification and the inner rational agent: A critique of the conventional wisdom of behavioural welfare economics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 23, 1–24.
Johansson, P., Hall, L., & Chater, N. (2011). Preference change through choice. In R. Dolan & T. Sharot (Eds.), Neuroscience of preference and choice (pp. 121–141). Cambridge (Mass.): Elsevier Academic Press.
Jung, J. Y., & Mellers, B. A. (2016). American attitudes toward nudges. Judgment and Decision Making, 11, 62–74.
Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality. Psychology for behavioral economics. American Economic Review, 93, 1449–1475.
Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
Kamenica, E., & Egan Brad, L. (2014). Voters, dictators, and peons: Expressive voting and pivotality. Public Choice, 159, 159–176.
Kirchgässner, G. (1992). Towards a theory of low-cost decisions. European Journal of Political Economy, 8, 305–320.
Kirchgässner, G. (2010). On minimal morals. European Journal of Political Economy, 26, 330–339.
Kirchgässner, G. (2017). Soft paternalism, merit goods and normative individualism. European Journal of Law and Economics, 43, 125–152.
Kliemt, H. (1986). The veil of insignificance. European Journal of Political Economy, 2, 333–344.
Korsgaard, C. M. (2009). Self-constitution. Agency, identity, and integrity. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Kragh Pedersen, S., Koch, A. K., & Nafziger, J. (2014). Who wants paternalism? Economics Bulletin, 66, S147–S166.
Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 443–478.
Loewenstein, G., & Chater, N. (2017). Putting nudges in perspective. Behavioural Public Policy, 1, 26–53.
Lucas, G. M, Jr., & Tasic, S. (2015). Behavioral public choice and the law. West Virginia Law Review, 118, 199–266.
Lusk, J. L., Marette, S., & Norwood, F. B. (2014). The paternalist meets his match. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy, 36, 61–108.
Ryan, R. M., & Deci, E. L. (2006). Self-regulation and the problem of human autonomy: Does psychology need choice, self-determination, and will? Journal of Personality, 74, 1557–1586.
Ryan, R. M., Deci, E. L., & Vansteenkiste, M. (2016). Autonomy and autonomy-disturbances in self-development and psychopathology: Research on motivation, attachment, and clinical process. In D. Cicchetti (Ed.), Developmental psychopathology: Theory and method (pp. 385–438). Hoboken: Wiley.
Schnellenbach, J. (2012). Nudges and norms. On the political economy of soft paternalism. European Journal of Political Economy, 28, 266–277.
Schnellenbach, J. (2016). A constitutional economics perspective on soft paternalism. Kyklos, 69, 135–156.
Schnellenbach, J., & Schubert, C. (2015). Behavioral political economy: A survey. European Journal of Political Economy, 40, 395–417.
Schubert, C. (2014). Evolutionary economics and the case for a constitutional libertarian paternalism. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 24, 1107–1113.
Schubert, C. (2015). Opportunity and preference learning. Economics & Philosophy, 31, 275–295.
Schubert, C. (2017). Exploring the (behavioral) political economy of nudging. Journal of Institutional Economics, 13, 499–522.
Shayo, M., & Harel, A. (2012). Non-consequentialist voting. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 81, 299–313.
Smith, A. (1759/1984). The theory of moral sentiments. Indianapolis: The Liberty Fund.
Stigler, G. J., & Becker, G. S. (1977). De gustibus non est disputandum. American Economic Review, 67, 76–90.
Sugden, R. (2008). Why incoherent preferences do not justify paternalism. Constitutional Political Economy, 19, 226–248.
Sugden, R. (2010). Opportunity as mutual advantage. Economics & Philosophy, 26, 47–68.
Sugden, R. (2015). Opportunity and preference learning: A reply to Christian Schubert. Economics & Philosophy, 31, 297–303.
Sunstein, C. R. (2013). Behavioral economics and paternalism. Yale Law Journal, 122, 1826–1899.
Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. H. (2003). Libertarian paternalism is not an oxymoron. University of Chicago Law Review, 70, 1159–1202.
Tannenbaum, D., Fox, C. R., & Rogers, T. (2017). On the misplaced politics of behavioral policy interventions. Nature Human Behaviour, 1, 0130.
Thaler, R. H. (2016). Behavioral economics: Past, present and future. American Economic Review, 106, 1577–1600.
Thaler, R. H., & Benartzi, S. (2004). Save more tomorrow: Using behavioral economics to increase employee saving. Journal of Political Economy, 112, S164–S187.
Thaler, R. H., & Shefrin, H. M. (1981). An economic theory of self-control. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 392–406.
Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth and happiness. London: Penguin.
Tullock, G. (1971). The charity of the uncharitable. Western Economic Journal, 9, 379–392.
Vanberg, V. J. (2005). Market and state: The perspective of constitutional political economy. Journal of Institutional Economics, 1, 23–49.
Varian, H. R. (2012). Revealed preference and Its applications. Economic Journal, 122, 332–338.
Viscusi, W. K., & Gayer, T. (2015). Behavioral public choice: The behavioral paradox of government policy. Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 38, 973–1007.
Weizsäcker, C. C. V. (2014). Freedom, wealth and adaptive preferences. Bonn: Mimeo., MPI for Research on Collective Goods.
White, M. D. (2013). The manipulation of choice. Ethics and libertarian paternalism. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Whitman, D. G., & Rizzo, M. J. (2015). The problematic welfare standards of behavioral paternalism. Review of Psychology and Philosophy, 6, 409–425.
Witt, U. (2001). Learning to consume. A theory of wants and the growth of demand. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11, 23–36.
Witt, U. (2011). Economic behavior. Evolutionary versus behavioral perspectives. Biological Theory, 6, 388–398.
Acknowledgements
I am grateful to participants at the Bremen conference of the German Economic Association (Committee on Evolutionary Economics), the Freiburg conference of the European Public Choice Society, the Manchester conference of the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy, the research seminar at the University of Leipzig for comments and, in particular, to Stefan Okruch and Roger Congleton for in-depth discussions of earlier versions of this paper. To an even greater extent, I am indebted to the late Gebhard Kirchgässner, who disagreed with some of the arguments presented herein, but whose criticism always has been challenging and constructive. Finally, I am also grateful to three anonymous referees and the Editor of this journal for very constructive comments. All remaining errors are entirely my own responsibility.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Schnellenbach, J. Evolving hierarchical preferences and behavioral economic policies. Public Choice 178, 31–52 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0607-4
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0607-4