Skip to main content
Log in

Public debt stabilization: the relevance of policymakers’ time horizons

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Policymakers are stuck in time. Political short-termism, policy myopia, policy short-sightedness, and similar words have been coined to emphasize the present-centric policy thinking. Politics tends to produce short time horizons, and as a result, policymakers often fail to use present opportunities to mitigate future harms. Focusing on fiscal and monetary strategic interactions, given different separate decision makers, our paper aims to explore the effects of policymakers’ time horizons on debt stabilization. To formalize our ideas, we use the novel concept of Nonlinear-model-predictive-control Feedback Nash Equilibrium (NFNE) and find that present-centric policy thinking and decision horizons matters under several dimensions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, e.g., van Aarle et al. (1995, 1997), Tabellini and La Via (1989), Engwerda et al. (2002, 2013, 2015, 2016), Getzner and Neck (2001), Van den Broek (2002), Di Bartolomeo and Di Gioacchino (2008), Blueschke and Neck (2011, 2014), Anevlavis et al. (2018), and van Aarle et al. (2018).

  2. Except in the case in which he agrees with the other members of the group (with a quid pro quo).

  3. See also Buchanan and Wagner (1977: Chapter 9) and Buchanan and Lee (1982).

  4. See, e.g., Alesina and Tabellini (1990), Buchanan and Congleton (1994), Lockwood et al. (1996), Glaeser (1997), Devereux and Wen (1998), Persson and Tabellini (1999), Sieg (2001), Lopez (2003), Johnson and Crain (2004), Dalle Nogare and Ricciuti (2011), and Smart and Sturm (2013).

  5. Whether a democratic or an authoritarian regime is better for economic growth has been largely discussed and researched. A partial survey is provided by Dixit (2010). See also Wintrobe (2001) or Acemoglu and Robinson (2006).

  6. See, e.g., Persson and Tabellini (1999) and Eslava (2011), for partial surveys.

  7. The model collapses to Tabellini (1986) for α = 0.

  8. This formalization represents the NFNE. A full discussion on the idea of NFNE and a comparison with other equilibrium concepts can be found in Di Bartolomeo et al. (2017). See also van den Broek (2002), for a similar concept based on repetitions of infinite horizon problems. Under some circumstances (in particular, long horizons), the NFNE may approximate the open-loop Nash equilibrium.

  9. Note that we focus on changes in rulers (leadership turnover) and not on changes in the rulers' ideology (ideological turnover), which has been studied elsewhere (for instance, Drazen 2000, 2001).

  10. See, for instance, Sims (2003, 2006). Hebert and Woodford (2017) give a deeper explanation of the rational inattention theory by including explicitly information cost, justifying the sequential forward-looking information sampling behavior for finite time.

  11. These are obtained implementing Grüne et al. (2015) routines adapted to a differential game context.

  12. Calibration is similar to that proposed by Engwerda et al. (2013). However, our results are qualitatively robust to changes in the calibration. Further numerical simulations are available upon request. It is also worth noting that different calibrations may lead to different equilibrium, which in this game can be not unique (see Engwerda et al. 2013).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adam, K. (2011). Government debt and optimal monetary and fiscal policy. European Economic Review, 55, 57–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Özler, S., Roubini, N., & Swagel, P. L. (1996). Political instability and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 189–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Tabellini, G. (1990). A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt. Review of Economic Studies, 57, 403–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anevlavis, T., Papavassilopoulos, V., Engwerda, J., & Aarle van, B. (2018). Debt stabilization in the presence of endogenous risk premia: A dynamic game approach. Macroeconomic Dynamics. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100517000906.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baskaran, T. (2010). On the link between fiscal decentralization and public debt in OECD countries. Public Choice, 145, 351–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blueschke, D., & Neck, R. (2011). “Core” and “Periphery” in a monetary union: A macroeconomic policy game. International Advances in Economic Research, 17, 334–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blueschke, D., & Neck, R. (2014). “Haircuts” for the EMU periphery: Virtue or vice? Empirica, 41, 153–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Congleton, R. D. (1994). The incumbency dilemma and rent extraction by legislators. Public Choice, 79, 47–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Lee, D. R. (1982). Politics, time, and the Laffer curve. Journal of Political Economy, 90, 816–819.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Wagner, R. E. (1977). Democracy in deficit—The political legacy of Lord Keynes. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chari, V., & Cole, H. (1993), Why are representative democracies fiscally irresponsible. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Saff report No 163.

  • Dalle Nogare, C., & Ricciuti, R. (2011). Do term limits affect fiscal policy choices? European Journal of Political Economy, 27, 681–692.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Haan, J., Jong-A-Pin, R., & Mierau, J. O. (2013). Do budgetary institutions mitigate the common pool problem? New empirical evidence for the EU. Public Choice, 156, 423–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debrun, X., Moulin, L., Turrini, A., Ayuso-i-Casals, J., & Kumar, M. (2008). Tied to the mast? National fiscal rules in the European Union. Economic Policy, 23, 297–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devereux, M. B., & Wen, J. F. (1998). Political instability, capital taxation, and growth. European Economic Review, 42, 1635–1651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Bartolomeo, G., & Di Gioacchino, D. (2008). Fiscal-monetary policy coordination and debt management: A two-stage analysis. Empirica, 35, 433–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Bartolomeo, G., Saltari, E., & Semmler, W. (2017). The NMPC Feedback Nash Equilibrium. Sapienza University of Rome, Mimeo.

  • Dixit, A. K. (2010). Democracy, autocracy and bureaucracy. Journal of Globalization and Development, 1, 1–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. (2000). Political economy in macroeconomics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. (2001). The political business cycle after 25 years. In B. S. Bernanke & K. Rogoff (Eds.), NBER macroeconomics annual 2000 (pp. 75–138). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engwerda, J. C., Aarle van, B., & Weeren, A. J. T. M. (2015). Debt stabilization and debt mutualization in a monetary union with endogenous risk premia. Munich: CESifo Working Papers, No. 5564.

  • Engwerda, J. C., Mahmoudinia, D., & Isfahani, R. D. (2016). Government and central bank interaction under uncertainty: A differential games approach. Iranian Economic Review, 20, 225–259.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engwerda, J. C., van Aarle, B., & Plasmans, J. E. J. (2002). Cooperative and non-cooperative fiscal stabilization policies in the EMU. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 26, 451–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engwerda, J. C., van Aarle, B., Plasmans, J. E. J., & Weeren, A. J. T. M. (2013). Debt stabilization games in the presence of risk premia. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37, 2525–2546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eslava, M. (2011). The political economy of fiscal deficit: A survey. Journal of Economic Surveys, 25, 645–673.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2001). The political economy of direct legislation: Direct democracy in local and regional decision-making. Economic Policy, 33, 329–367.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foremny, D., Sacchi, A., & Salotti, S. (2017). Decentralization and the duration of fiscal consolidation: Shifting the burden across layers of government. Public Choice, 171, 359–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forte, F. (2012). The new macro political economy of Alberto Alesina. Atlantic Economic Journal, 40, 417–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forte, F. (2016). Buchanan’s philosophical approach to public choice. Rivista Internazionale di Filosofia del Diritto, 2, 185–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Getzner, M., & Neck, R. (2001). Politico-economic determinants of public debt growth: A case study for Austria. Public Choice, 109, 243–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L. (1997). Self-imposed term limits. Public Choice, 93, 389–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grüne, L., Semmler, W., & Stieler, M. (2015). Using nonlinear model predictive control for dynamic decision problems in economics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 60, 112–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hebert, B., & Woodford, M. (2017). Rational inattention and sequential information sampling. NBER Working Paper, No 23787.

  • Jochimsen, B., & Thomasius, S. (2014). The perfect finance minister: Whom to appoint as finance minister to balance the budget. European Journal of Political Economy, 34, 390–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, J. M., & Crain, W. M. (2004). Effects of term limits on fiscal performance: Evidence from democratic nations. Public Choice, 119, 73–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keech, W. R. (1994). Economic politics the cost of democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B., Philippopoulos, A., & Snell, A. (1996). Fiscal policy, public debt stabilization and politics: Theory and UK evidence. Economic Journal, 106, 894–911.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lopez, E. J. (2003). Term limits: Causes and consequences. Public Choice, 114, 1–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niemann, S. (2011). Dynamic monetary-fiscal interactions and the role of monetary conservatism. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58, 234–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niemann, S., Pichler, P., & Sorger, G. (2013). Central bank independence and the monetary instrument problem. International Economic Review, 54, 1031–1055.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niemann, S., & von Hagen, J. (2008). Coordination of monetary and fiscal policies: A fresh look at the issue. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 15, 89–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 8, 567–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Svensson, L. E. O. (1989). Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: Policy with time-inconsistent preferences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, 325–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1999). Political economics and macroeconomic policy. In J. Taylor & M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Vol. 1C, pp. 1397–1482). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rieth, M. (2014). Myopic governments and welfare-enhancing debt limits. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 38, 250–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Review of Economic Studies, 55, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacchi, A., & Salotti, S. (2015). The impact of National Fiscal Rules on the stabilisation function of fiscal policy. European Journal of Political Economy, 37, 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salhi, A., & Bolle, M. (2007). Democracy, autocracy and growth: Theoretical considerations. In Paper presented at the conference the institutional and social dynamics of growth and distribution, Lucca, December 10–12, 2007.

  • Schnellenbach, J., & Schubert, C. (2015). Behavioral political economy: A survey. European Journal of Political Economy, 40, 395–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sieg, G. (2001). A political business cycle with boundedly rational agents. European Journal of Political Economy, 17, 39–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69, 99–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1957). Models of man: Social and rational. Mathematical essays on rational human behavior in society setting. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sims, C. A. (2003). Implications of rational inattention. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 665–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims, C. A. (2006). Rational inattention: Beyond the linear-quadratic case. American Economic Review, 96, 158–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smart, M., & Sturm, D. M. (2013). Term limits and electoral accountability. Journal of Public Economics, 107, 93–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini, G. (1986). Money, debt and deficits in a dynamic game. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 10, 427–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini, G., & La Via, V. (1989). Money, deficit and public debt in the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 71, 15–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Aarle, B., Bovenberg, L., & Raith, M. (1995). Monetary and fiscal policy interaction and government debt stabilization. Journal of Economics, 62, 111–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Aarle, B., Bovenberg, L., & Raith, M. (1997). Is there a tragedy of a common central bank? A dynamic analysis. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21, 417–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Aarle, B., Engwerda, J., & Weeren, A. (2018). Effects of debt mutualization in a monetary union with endogenous risk premia: Can Eurobonds contribute to debt stabilization? Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 44, 100–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van den Broek, W. A. (2002). Moving horizon control in dynamic games. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 26, 937–961.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: An economic theory of dictatorship. The American Political Science Review, 84, 849–872.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wintrobe, R. (2001). How to understand and deal with dictatorship: An economist’s view. Economics of Governance, 2, 35–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. A. (1995). The myth of democratic failure why political institutions are efficient. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo, J. (2003). Economic, political, and institutional determinants of public deficits. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 387–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors acknowledge Francesco Forte for his detailed suggestions. They are also grateful for comments from Bas van Aarle, Jacob Engwerda, Silvia Fedeli, Paul Levine, Behnaz Minooei Fard, Joseph Plasmans, Davide Ticchi, Ronald Wintrobe, and participants from the special session in honour of Francesco Forte at the VII MPT Workshop. The authors also acknowledge financial support by Sapienza University of Rome.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giovanni Di Bartolomeo.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Di Bartolomeo, G., Di Pietro, M., Saltari, E. et al. Public debt stabilization: the relevance of policymakers’ time horizons. Public Choice 177, 287–299 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0584-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0584-7

Keywords

Navigation