Skip to main content
Log in

Shades of red and blue: government ideology and sustainable development

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the effect of government ideology on sustainable development, measured as investment in genuine wealth, in a dynamic panel of 79 countries between 1981 and 2013. We find robust and statistically significant evidence that genuine investment grows faster under right-wing governments than under left-wing or center governments. In contrast, we find no indication of opportunistic cycles.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Natural capital refers to physical stocks of renewable and non-renewable resources and to the physical receptor systems that can assimilate pollution (e.g., the seas and the atmosphere).

  2. This, of course, not the only definition of sustainable development. In fact, many different definitions have been proposed in the literature (see, e.g., Lawn 2003). The advantage of the World Commission’s definition over alternatives is that it is firmly based on welfare economics considerations.

  3. One consequence of the intertemporal emphasis is that tradeoffs are allowed, in the sense that social welfare may be lower at some future date than it is today so long as the discounted present value is not declining. See Arrow et al. (2004, p. 150) for further discussion of the implications of this definition.

  4. Formally, let xij be a particular indicator of “development” i in country j. Then the preformance gap for that indicator for that country is \(I_{ij} = \frac{{\left\{ {max_{j} x_{ij} - x_{ij} } \right\}}}{{\left\{ {max_{j} x_{ij} - min_{j} x_{ij} } \right\}}}\); the HDI for country j is \(1 - \frac{1}{M}\sum\nolimits_{i} {I_{ij} } ,\) where M is the number of indicators (see Fleurbaey (2009) for a discussion of human development index and other measures of social welfare).

  5. Persistence is a strong assumption as institutions do change. It can be justified by the so-called “critical junctions” theory of institutional development. According to that theory, institutional reform happens at critical junctions in history. Once the new institutions are in place, they persist for a long time—until the next critical junction. (See Acemoglu et al. 2001 for an example of this line of reasoning.) That view is, however, challenged by modernization theory, according to which democratic institutions emerge gradually as a consequence of economic development (see, e.g., Gundlach and Paldam 2009; Guerriero 2016, who shows legal institutions also evolve gradually in response to socio-economic factors). In the statistical analysis, we do attempt to capture institutional changes, but for the logic of the theoretical analysis to go through, it is a convenient simplification to consider institutions as fixed and ideology as the aspect that fluctuates.

  6. See also Dasgupta (2001, chapter 9) and Hamilton and Clemens (1999).

  7. See also Reed (2006), Imbeau et al. (2001) and Frederiksson et al. (2013). Moreover, Folke (2014) shows that small political parties with a focus on specific issues such as the environment or immigration can influence policy on those margins. For a good survey of the relevance of government ideology, see Potrafke (2017).

  8. The theoretical foundation for the opportunistic political business cycle was laid by Nordhaus (1975) and integrated into rational expectations models by Rogoff and Sibert (1988) and Rogoff (1990) and applied in Aidt and Mooney (2014). The literature recently has been surveyed by Dubois (2016). Empirical studies suggest that favorable economic conditions in the lead-up to an election do benefit the incumbent government (Hibbs 2006).

  9. Specifically, we use the Legislative and Executive Indices of Electoral Competitiveness from the Database of Political Institutions (DPI) to define the sample. It scores countries on a 1–7 scale with higher values meaning more competitive elections. We excluded countries with values lower than 6, meaning that we include countries (during periods) in which they had competitive elections and when multiple parties did win seats. A score of 6 indicates that the largest party received more than 75% of the seats, while a score of 7 indicates that it won less than that (in some robustness checks, we restrict the sample to those countries with a score of 7). The countries in our sample are listed in the note to Table 2. It includes countries from Europe, the Americas, Africa, Oceania, the Middle East and Asia.

  10. For details on how it is computed, see Arrow el al. (2003). The WDI use the term “adjusted net savings” to describe what we refer as “genuine investment”.

  11. It has two parts. The first is designed to capture the cost of global warming. An estimate of the social cost of carbon dioxide emissions is subtracted from national savings, with the assumption that the average social cost of a ton of carbon is US$30. The second part is designed to capture the impact of local environmental degradation. The World Bank makes a financial deduction for an estimate of the health damages caused by urban air pollution (particulate emissions) from gross savings.

  12. The rents are calculated as the market price of the resource minus average extraction cost for the two non-renewable resources (energy and mineral depletion). For renewable forest resources, the rent is estimated as the market price per unit of harvest in excess of the natural regeneration rate.

  13. In the baseline, we follow Arrow et al. (2004) and the ratios we use are 0.2 for industrialized countries and 0.15 for developing and oil-rich countries. We have investigated if the results are sensitive to this choice and Table A2 in the supplementary material shows that the results are not sensitive to variations within the range of plus/minus 25.

  14. For the subset of OECD countries and for individual countries (such as the United States and Canada), more refined classifications of party ideology exist (see Bjørnskov 2005, 2008; Bjørnskov and Potrafke 2012, 2013; Lamérisa et al. 2018).

  15. For further information on how the party classification is constructed, see the DPI codebook (Keefer 2012).

  16. Although the two-step estimator is asymptotically more efficient than the one-step estimator and relaxes the assumption of homoscedasticity, the efficiency gains are not that important even in the case of heteroscedastic errors. That result is supported by Judson and Owen (1999). They show empirically that the one-step estimator outperforms the two-step estimator, especially when the number of time periods is relatively large (T = 30), which is the case in this study. Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundel and Bond (1998) suggest another GMM estimator with additional moment conditions. If the conditions are valid, efficiency will increase. The system GMM estimator combines the moment conditions of the model in first differences with those of the model in levels. However, if the orthogonality conditions for the first-differenced equation are valid, but those for the level equation are not, then the system GMM estimator may not be better than first-differences GMM estimator. That can happen, for example, if the regressors used in the orthogonality conditions for the levels equation are correlated with the individual effects. Moreover, simulations suggest that the system GMM estimator is not necessarily superior to the standard GMM estimator in cases for which the autoregressive parameter is below 0.8 and the time-series observations are relatively large (Blundell and Bond 1998; Moshirian and Wu 2012). That is what we observe in our data. So, to sum up, the estimator that is most suitable for our empirical analysis is the one-step first-differences GMM estimator.

  17. Table A6 in the supplementary material reports the results from a system-GMM estimator. The results are similar to those shown in Table 3.

  18. That conjecture is substantiated by the fact that the correlation between the Fraser Institute’s Economic Freedom Index and the right-wing government indicator is positive (0.11) and significant at the 1% level. Moreover, the correlation between the right-wing government indicator and the regulation sub-component of the Freedom House index (capturing credit, labor and business regulations) is negative (− 0.14) and also significant at the 1% level.

  19. In additional experiments, reported in Table A1 in the supplementary material, we investigate the existence of cycles in elections that result in a change in the political orientation of the government, if differences are observed in pre- and post-election years, or if it matters how long the interval between elections is. Apart from a weak positive effect of elections that result in a change in government ideology, we find no evidence of an election cycle.

  20. Specifically, we consider the democratization index proposed by Acemoglu et al. (2018) and the machine learning-based index proposed by Gründler and Krieger (2016) as alternatives to the Polity IV index and find similar results [available upon request]. We also have investigated the effect of controlling for specific (as opposed to general) features of the political system including controls for the type of political regime (presidential versus parliamentarian; plurality versus non-plurality), for the election system (majority versus proportional rules) and for various indicators of the quality of institutions from the International Country Risk Guide. Those results are reported in Tables A3 and A4 in the supplementary material. Very occasionally one of the institutional controls is significant, but in no case does it have more than a small effect on the size and significance of the estimated effect of right-wing government ideology.

  21. We have investigated if the effect of right-wing government ideology on sustainable development is conditional on the general quality of political institutions, on the regime type or on the election rule. We cannot find any evidence that it is contigent on the general quality of political institutions (results available upon request). Tables A3 and A4 in the supplementary material report that the effect is larger in plurality regimes and in countries with proportional election rules.

  22. While in the group of OECD countries the growth rate of genuine wealth per capita is, on average, 0.13% points higher when a right-wing party is in office, in the non-OECD countries it is 0.24% points higher, ceteris paribus.

  23. Besides dividing the sample between the OECD and non-OECD countries, we also investigated alternative sample splits. Those results, reported in Tables A3, A4 and A5 in the supplementary material, show that right-wing parties affect investment in genuine wealth in presidential, plurality and proportional representation regimes and are observed in both high- and low-income countries/democracies.

  24. Furthermore, the positive relationship between right-wing governments and genuine investment is robust to changes in the proxies for the economy’s capital stocks, shadow prices (see Table A2 in the supplementary material), exclusion of some countries (with more populist reputations), and to the use of the Blundell-Bond system GMM estimator (see Tables A6 in the supplementary material).

  25. We use the Stata procedure PSACALC (Oster, 2017) to calculate the numbers.

  26. See, for example, the seminal papers by Mueller (1970) and Veiga and Veiga (2004).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Naidu, S., Restrepo, P., & Robinson, J. A. (2018). Democracy does cause growth. Journal of Political Economy (in press).

  • Aidt, T. S. (2009). Corruption, institutions, and economic development. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 25(2), 271–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S. (2011). Corruption and sustainable development. In S. Rose-Ackerman & T. Soreide (Eds.), International handbook on the economics of corruption (Vol. II, Ch. 1). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S., & Mooney, G. (2014). Voting suffrage and the political budget cycle: Evidence from the London Metropolitan Boroughs 1902–1937. Journal of Public Economics, 112, 53–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (1987). Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 651–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji, J. G., Taber, C. R., & Todd, E. E. (2005). Selection on observed and unobserved variables: Assessing the effectiveness of Catholic schools. Journal of Political Economy, 113(1), 151–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, S. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K., Dasgupta, P., Goulder, L., Daily, G., Ehrlich, P., Heal, G., et al. (2004). Are we consuming too much? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), 147–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K., Dasgupta, P., & Mäler, K. (2003). The genuine savings criterion and the value of population. Economic Theory, 21(2), 217–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asheim, G. (2000). Green national accounting: Why and how? Environment and Development Economics, 5, 25–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, G., & Hamilton, K. (2003). Savings, growth and the Resource Curse Hypothesis. World Development, 31(11), 1793–1807.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi, B. (2008). Econometric analysis of panel data (4th ed.). Chichester, UK: John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C. (2005). Does political ideology affect economic growth? Public Choice, 123(2), 133–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C. (2008). The growth-inequality association: Government ideology matters. Journal of Development Economics, 87(2), 300–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C., & Potrafke, N. (2012). Political ideology and economic freedom across Canadian provinces. Eastern Economic Journal, 38, 143–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C., & Potrafke, N. (2013). The size and scope of government in the US states: Does party ideology matter? International Tax and Public Finance, 20, 687–714.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, G. (2005a). Estimation and inference in dynamic unbalanced panel-data models with a small number of individuals. Stata Journal, 5(4), 473–500.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, G. (2005b). Approximating the bias of the LSDV estimator for dynamic unbalanced panel data models. Economics Letters, 87(3), 361–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P. (2001). Human well-being and the natural environment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P. (2010). The place of nature in economic development. In D. Rodrik & M. Rosenzweig (Eds.), Handbook of development economics (Vol. 5, pp. 4977–5047). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P., & Mäler, K. (2000). Net national product, wealth, and social well-being. Environment and Development Economics, 5(1), 69–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Database of Political Institutions (several years). World Bank (http://www.worldbank.org).

  • Doornik, J., Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (2002). Panel data estimation using DPD for OX: Manuscript. Oxford: Oxford University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dubois, E. (2016). Political business cycles 40 years after Nordhaus. Public Choice, 166(1–2), 235–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleurbaey, M. (2009). Beyond GDP: The quest for a measure of social welfare. Journal of Economic Literature, 474, 1029–1075.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Folke, O. (2014). Shades of brown and green: Party effects in proportional election systems. Journal of the European Economic Association, 12(5), 1361–1395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederiksson, P. G., Wang, L., & Warren, P. L. (2013). Party politics, governors and economic policy. Southern Economic Journal, 80(1), 106–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gründler, K., & Krieger, T. (2016). Democracy and growth: Evidence from a machine learning indicator. European Journal of Political Economy, 45, 85–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guerriero, C. (2016). Endogenous legal traditions. International Review of Law and Economics, 46, 49–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gundlach, E., & Paldam, M. (2009). A farewell to critical junctures: Sorting out long-run causality of income and democracy. European Journal of Political Economy, 25, 340–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, K., & Clemens, M. (1999). Genuine savings rates in developing countries. World Bank Economic Review, 13(2), 333–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. A. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. American Political Science Review, 71, 1467–1487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. A. (1987). The american political economy: Macroeconomics and electoral politics in the United States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. A. (2006). Voting and the macroeconomy. In B. R. Weingast & D. A. Wittman (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of political economy (pp. 565–586). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. (1940). The valuation of social income. Economica, 7, 105–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbeau, L., Pétry, F., & Lamari, M. (2001). Left-right party ideology and government policies: A meta-analysis. European Journal of Political Research, 40(1), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Judson, R., & Owen, A. (1999). Estimating dynamic panel data models: A guide for macroeconomists. Economics Letters, 65(1), 9–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kauder, B., & Potrafke, N. (2013). Government ideology and tuition fee policy: Evidence from the German States. CESifo Economic Studies, 59(4), 628–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P. (2012). Database of political institutions: Changes and variable definitions. Development Research Group. Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lamérisa, M., Jong-A-Pin, R., & Garretsen, H. (2018). On the measurement of voter ideology. European Journal of Political Economy. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2018.03.003. in press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawn, P. A. (2003). A theoretical foundation to support the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW), Genuine Progress Indicator (GPI), and other related indexes. Ecological Economics, 44(1), 105–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moshirian, F., & Wu, Q. (2012). Banking industry volatility and economic growth. Research in International Business and Finance, 26, 428–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, J. E. (1970). Presidential popularity from Truman to Johnson. American Political Science Review, 64, 18–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, XLII2, 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oster, E. (2017). Unobservable selection and coefficient stability: Theory and validation. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics. https://doi.org/10.1080/07350015.2016.1227711. in press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pickering, A., & Rockey, J. (2011). Ideology and the growth of government. Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(3), 907–919.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pickering, A. C., & Rockey, J. (2013). Ideology and the size of US state government. Public Choice, 156(3–4), 443–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polity IV project (2013). Individual Country Regime Trends, 1946–2013. (http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4x.htm).

  • Potrafke, N. (2010). Does government ideology influence deregulation of product markets? Empirical evidence from OECD countries. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 135–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2017). Partisan politics: The empirical evidence from OECD panel data studies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 45(4), 712–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed, W. R. (2006). Democrats, republicans, and taxes: Evidence that political parties matter. Journal of Public Economics, 90(4–5), 725–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. The American Economic Review, 801, 21–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Review of Economic Studies, 1, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roodman, D. (2009a). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. Stata Journal, 9(1), 86–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roodman, D. M. (2009b). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71, 135–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veiga, F., & Veiga, L. (2004). The determinants of vote intentions in Portugal. Public Choice, 118(3–4), 341–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venard, B. (2013). Institutions, corruption and sustainable development. Economics Bulletin, 33(4), 2545–2562.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2006). Where is the wealth of nations? Measuring capital for the 21st century. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Commission. (1997). Our common future. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Development Indicators (several years). Washington DC: World Bank (http://data.worldbank.org/).

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors acknowledge the helpful comments and suggestions from the participants at the 23rd International Academic Conference of the International Institute of Social and Economic Sciences, Venice International University, Venice, Italy, 27–30 April 2016; the participants at the 10th Annual Meeting of the Portuguese Economic Journal, University of Coimbra, Portugal, 1–3 July 2016; and the participants at the 2017 annual Meeting of the European Public Choice Society, Central European University, Budapest, Hungary, 19–22 April. Vitor Castro also wishes to thank the financial support provided by the Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology under the research grant SFRH/BSAB/113588/2015 (partially funded by COMPTE, QREN and FEDER).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vitor Castro.

Electronic supplementary material

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aidt, T.S., Castro, V. & Martins, R. Shades of red and blue: government ideology and sustainable development. Public Choice 175, 303–323 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0536-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0536-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation