Advertisement

Banking regulation, regulatory capture and inequality

  • G. P. Manish
  • Colin O’Reilly
Article

Abstract

Regulation of the banking and finance industry may lead to a more equal distribution of income if regulators pursue goals in the public interest. Alternatively, the economic theory of regulation predicts that regulatory and supervisory processes may be captured by the banking industry, leading to policies that promote the industry’s interests. The liberalization of the banking and finance sector since the 1980s has produced more intense banking supervision and prudential regulation. In this study we find that banking supervision regulation is associated with greater income inequality. These findings are consistent with the economic theory of regulation. We interpret these results as evidence that regulatory capture in the banking and finance industry can have pernicious effects on the distribution of income.

Keywords

Regulation Inequality Regressive Regulatory capture Liberalization Banking supervision 

JEL Classification

D31 D63 D72 D73 L51 F65 

References

  1. Anderson, J., Bailey, J., & Thomas, D. (this issue). Regressive effects of regulation on wages. Public Choice.Google Scholar
  2. Abiad, A., Detragiache, E., & Tressel, T. (2010). A new database of financial reforms. IMF Staff Papers, 57(2), 281–302.  https://doi.org/10.1057/imfsp.2009.23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2015). The Rise and decline of general laws of capitalism. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 29(1), 3–28.  https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.29.1.3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Agnello, L., Mallick, S. K., & Sousa, R. M. (2012). Financial reforms and income inequality. Economics Letters, 116(3), 583–587.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2012.06.005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Apergis, N., & Cooray, A. (2017). Economic freedom and income inequality: Evidence from a panel of global economies—A linear and a non-linear long-run analysis. The Manchester School, 85(1), 88–105.  https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Barth, J. R., Caprio, G., & Levine, R. (2004). Bank regulation and supervision: What works best? Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13(2), 205–248.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2003.06.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Beck, T., Demirgüc-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2007). Finance, inequality and the poor. Journal of Economic Growth, 12(1), 27–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2006). Bank supervision and corruption in lending. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53(8), 2131–2163.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.10.014.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Peria, M., & Soledad, M. (2008). Banking services for everyone? Barriers to bank access and use around the world. The World Bank Economic Review, 22(3), 397–430.  https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhn020.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Berggren, N. (1999). Economic freedom and equality: Friends or foes? Public Choice, 100(3–4), 203–223.  https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1018343912743.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Bergh, A., & Nilsson, T. (2010). Do liberalization and globalization increase income inequality? European Journal of Political Economy, 26(4), 488–505.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2010.03.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Blau, B. M., Brough, T. J., & Thomas, D. W. (2013). Corporate lobbying, political connections, and the bailout of banks. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(8), 3007–3017.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2013.04.005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Borenstein, S., & Bushnell, J. (2015). The US electricity industry after 20 years of restructuring. Annual Review of Economics, 7(1), 437–463.  https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-080614-115630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Boyer, P. C., & Ponce, J. (2012). Regulatory capture and banking supervision reform. Journal of Financial Stability, 8(3), 206–217.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2011.07.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Buchanan, J., Tollison, R. D., & Tullock, G. (Eds.). (1980). Toward a theory of the rent seeking society. College Station: Texas A&M Press.Google Scholar
  16. Carter, J. R. (2007). An empirical note on economic freedom and income inequality. Public Choice, 130(1–2), 163–177.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-006-9078-0.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Chambers, D., McLaughlin, P., & Stanley, L. (this issue). Regulation and poverty: an empirical examination of the relationship between the incidence of federal regulation and the occurrence of poverty across the states. Public Choice.Google Scholar
  18. Christopoulos, D., & McAdam, P. (2017). Do financial reforms help stabilize inequality? Journal of International Money and Finance, 70, 45–61.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2016.05.003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Claessens, S., & Perotti, E. (2007). Finance and inequality: Channels and evidence. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(4), 748–773.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2007.07.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Congleton, R. D. (2009). On the political economy of the financial crisis and bailout of 2008–2009. Public Choice, 140(3–4), 287–317.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-009-9478-z.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. De Haan, J., & Sturm, J.-E. (2017). Finance and income inequality: A review and new evidence. European Journal of Political Economy.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2017.04.007.Google Scholar
  22. Delis, M. D., Hasan, I., & Kazakis, P. (2014). Bank regulations and income inequality: Empirical evidence. Review of Finance, 18(5), 1811–1846.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Demirgüc-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2009). Finance and inequality: Theory and evidence. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 1(1), 287–318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Dolar, B., & Shughart, W. F. (2011). Enforcement of the USA Patriot Act’s anti-money laundering provisions: Have regulators followed a risk-based approach? Global Finance Journal, 22(1), 19–31.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gfj.2011.05.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Dolar, B., & Shughart, W. F. (2012). The USA Patriot Act’s differential impact on large and small banks: Evidence from California’s high-risk money laundering and related financial crime areas. Journal of Banking Regulation, 13(2), 127–146.  https://doi.org/10.1057/jbr.2011.22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Dorsch, M. (2013). Bailout for sale? The vote to save Wall Street. Public Choice, 155(3/4), 211–228.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9888-6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Easterly, W. (2001). The elusive quest for growth: Economists’ adventures and misadventures in the tropics (1st ed.). Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  28. Easterly, W. (2005). What did structural adjustment adjust? The association of policies and growth with repeated IMF and World Bank adjustment loans. Journal of Development Economics, 76(1), 1–22.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2003.11.005.Google Scholar
  29. Feenstra, R. C., Inklaar, R., & Timmer, M. P. (2015). The next generation of the Penn World Table. American Economic Review, 105(10), 3150–3182.  https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20130954.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Gimet, C., & Lagoarde-Segot, T. (2011). A closer look at financial development and income distribution. Journal of Banking & Finance, 35(7), 1698–1713.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2010.11.011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Heinemann, F., & Schüler, M. (2004). A Stiglerian view on banking supervision. Public Choice, 121(1–2), 99–130.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-004-5437-x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Holcombe, R. (2015). Political capitalism. Cato Journal, 35(1), 41–66. https://object.cato.org/sites/cato.org/files/serials/files/cato-journal/2015/2/cj-v35n1-2.pdf
  33. Jauch, S., & Watzka, S. (2016). Financial development and income inequality: A panel data approach. Empirical Economics, 51(1), 291–314.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-1008-x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Jaumotte, F., Lall, S., & Papageorgiou, C. (2013). Rising income inequality: Technology, or trade and financial globalization? IMF Economic Review, 61(2), 271–309.  https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2013.7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Jaumotte, F., & Osorio, M. C. (2015). Inequality and labor market institutions. Washington: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
  36. Kim, D.-H., & Lin, S.-C. (2011). Nonlinearity in the financial development–income inequality nexus. Journal of Comparative Economics, 39(3), 310–325.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2011.07.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Kunieda, T., Okada, K., & Shibata, A. (2014). Finance and inequality: How does globalization change their relationship? Macroeconomic Dynamics, 18(5), 1091–1128.  https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100512000843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Laffont, J., & Martimort, D. (1999). Separation of regulators against collusive behavior. The Rand Journal of Economics, 30(2), 232–262.  https://doi.org/10.2307/2556079.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Lambert, T. (2015). Lobbying on regulatory enforcement actions: Evidence from banking. Working Paper.Google Scholar
  40. Law, S. H., Tan, H. B., & Azman-Saini, W. N. W. (2014). Financial development and income inequality at different levels of institutional quality. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 50(sup1), 21–33.  https://doi.org/10.2753/REE1540-496X5001S102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Li, J., & Yu, H. (2014). Income inequality and financial reform in Asia: The role of human capital. Applied Economics, 46(22–24), 2920–2935.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Lindsey, B., & Teles, S. (2017). The captured economy: How the powerful enrich themselves, slow down growth, and increase inequality. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  43. Martimort, D. (1999). The life cycle of regulatory agencies: Dynamic capture and transaction costs. Review of Economic Studies, 66(4), 929–947.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Martin, A., & Thomas, D. (2013). Two-tiered political entrepreneurship and the congressional committee system. Public Choice, 154(1–2), 21–37.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9805-z.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Mccormick, R., & Tollison, R. D. (2012). Politicians, legislation, and the economy: An inquiry into the interest-group theory of government. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
  46. McLeod, R. H. (1999). Control and competition: Banking deregulation and re-regulation in Indonesia. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy, 4(2), 258–297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Mishkin, F. S. (Ed.). (2002). Prudential supervision: What works and what doesn’t (1st ed.). Chicago: University Of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  48. Mitchell, W. C. (1990). Interest groups: Economic perspectives and contribution. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2, 85–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Mitchell, W. C., & Munger, M. (1991). Economic models of interest-groups: An introductory survey. American Journal of Political Science, 35(2), 512–546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Mitchener, K. J. (2007). Are prudential supervision and regulation pillars of financial stability? Evidence from the Great Depression. Journal of Law and Economics, 50(2), 273–302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Mulholland, S. (this issue). Stratification by regulation. Public Choice.Google Scholar
  52. Naceur, S. B., & Zhang, R. (2016). Financial development, inequality and poverty; some international evidence (IMF Working Papers No. 16/32). International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
  53. Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Peltzman, S. (1989). The economic theory of regulation after a decade of deregulation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1989(1989), 1–41.Google Scholar
  55. Philippon, T., & Reshef, A. (2012). Wages and human capital in the U.S. finance industry: 1909–2006. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(4), 1551–1609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty first century. (Trans.: A. Goldhammer). Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press: An Imprint of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Piketty, T., & Saez, E. (2006). The evolution of top incomes: A historical and international perspective. The American Economic Review, 96(2), 200–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics, 5(2), 335–358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Shughart, W. F., & McChesney, F. S. (2010). Public choice theory and antitrust policy. Public Choice, 142(3–4), 385–406.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-009-9552-6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Solt, F. (2009). Standardizing the world income inequality database. Social Science Quarterly, 90(2), 231–242.  https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6237.2009.00614.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3–21.  https://doi.org/10.2307/3003160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Stiglitz, J. E. (2012). The price of inequality: How today’s divided society endangers our future (1st ed.). New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
  63. The McLaughlin-Sherouse List: The 10 most-regulated industries of 2014. (2016, January 21). https://www.mercatus.org/publication/mclaughlin-sherouse-list-10-most-regulated-industries-2014.
  64. Thomas, D. (2012). Regressive effects of regulation. Mercatus Center Working Paper. Arlington: Mercatus Center.Google Scholar
  65. Tollison, R. D. (1976). Rent seeking: A survey. Kyklos, 35(4), 575–602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5(3), 224–232.Google Scholar
  67. World Bank. (2005). Economic growth in the 1990s: Learning from a decade of reform. Washington, D.C: World Bank Publications.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Young, A. T., & Lawson, R. A. (2014). Capitalism and labor shares: A cross-country panel study. European Journal of Political Economy, 33, 20–36.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2013.11.006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Sorrell College of Business, Manuel Johnson Center for Political EconomyTroy UniversityTroyUSA
  2. 2.Heider College of Business, Institute for Economic InquiryCreighton UniversityOmahaUSA

Personalised recommendations