Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The efficiency of regulatory arbitrage

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Classic public choice skepticism about the regulatory state, based on theories of rent-seeking, rent extraction and regulatory capture, is based on the unrealistic, and usually unstated, assumption of a monopolist regulator. In practice, the regulatory state is polycentric, involving numerous quasi-independent agencies with overlapping responsibilities. This has led to a more optimistic picture based on the idea of regulatory arbitrage: when firms can, to some extent, pick and choose their preferred regulator, regulatory agencies are constrained to deliver relatively efficient regulatory policies. In our view, this optimism is also unrealistic. We build a family of models that explores the possible regulatory outcomes, and use some aspects of Gordon Tullock’s critique of the common law as a conceptual foundation for the analysis of the efficiency of a polycentric regulatory system.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Explore related subjects

Discover the latest articles, news and stories from top researchers in related subjects.

Notes

  1. Such concerns were anticipated partly by Hayek (1944), see Boettke (1995) and Boettke and López (2002).

  2. The problem can be ameliorated by so-called patent trolls that buy packages of many patents and act as intermediaries between patent users and the original patent holders. Without the patent anticommons problem, such “patent trolls” simply would raise production costs without any economic benefits. In the presence of the patent anticommons trolls actually may increase economic efficiency.

  3. See Geradin and McCahery (2004) for an overview of the evidence, including a contrarian argument claiming that the possibility of races to the bottom still needs to be taken seriously.

  4. Notable exceptions are Ostrom (1997) and Wagner (1989, 2009, 2016).

  5. The tables were produced using data from RegData 2.2. RegData provides several datasets, including one identifying which federal agency produced each piece of regulation (identified by year, title, part) and others estimating the probability that each piece of regulation affects each specific industry (three industry datasets are available, based on the NAICS 2017 industry identification codes, 2-digit, 3-digit, and 4-digit). We used the 3-digit identification industry dataset, and, for each piece of regulation, we kept only the industries that had an assigned probability greater than 90%. For more details about how RegData’s probabilities are calculated, see Al-Ubaydli and McLaughlin (2015) and Goldschlag and Tabarrok (2018). The R code for producing all of the industry-agency interaction tables (similar to Tables 1, 2, 3 and 4) is available at: https://github.com/vladtarko/regulation-of-industry.

  6. Health concerns are used as a justification (Guy 2016).

  7. The regulation component of the index is an average of the following: (A) Credit market regulations: (i) Ownership of banks; (ii) Private sector credit; (iii) Interest rate controls/negative real interest rates; (B) Labor market regulations: (i) Hiring regulations and minimum wage; (ii) Hiring and firing regulations; (iii) Centralized collective bargaining; (iv) Hours regulations; (v) Mandated cost of worker dismissal; (vi) Conscription; (C) Business regulations: (i) Administrative requirements; (ii) Bureaucracy costs; (iii) Starting a business; (iv) Extra payments/bribes/favoritism; (v) Licensing restrictions; (vi) Cost of tax compliance.

  8. See the Appendix in Gwartney et al. (2018, pp. 213–225) for the full explanation of their sources.

  9. See for example Buchanan and Goetz (1972), Lowery and Lyons (1989), Donahue (1997), Caplan (2001), Powell (2004), Howell-Moroney (2008). See McPhail and Tarko (2017) for an overview and a critique of those objections to Tiebout competition.

  10. The result is similar to how Bertrand competition can generate the same outcome as perfect competition even with only two firms.

  11. As noted by Tullock (1980a), the amount paid by rent-seekers ultimately depends on the ease of entry in the rent-seeking market (see also Higgins et al. 1988). Aligica and Tarko (2014) also argue that “crony capitalism” is built on this logic, limiting access to rent-seeking based on “crony” relations, in order to secure larger rents. If the number of rent seekers affects the individual rent-seeking investment in accordance with the formula \(r\left( {N - 1} \right)/N\) (see Mueller 2003, pp. 331–338, for a discussion), which we weight by probability ψ, we obtain the revenue \(R = \psi r\left( {N - 1} \right)\) instead of \(R = \psi rN\).

  12. For a critique of Tullock’s view on common law see Shughart II (2018).

  13. Tullock has a particularly iconoclastic and negative view of trial by jury (2005a: 345–346) and is especially critical of any claim that the average juror is adequately equipped to determine “factual or other information” (2005a: 350). This side of his argument is not particularly relevant for our purposes here.

  14. Error costs are the sum of the costs associated with Type 1 error (the Court incorrectly finds a party to a dispute liable) and Type 2 error (the Court incorrectly fails to impose liability on a party to a dispute). Administrative costs are the sum of the various costs associated with legal proceedings (Zywicki 2008: 39–40).

  15. Needless to say, Tullock views the “nonuse of the jury system by people who have a choice at the time they write their [arbitration] contracts” to provide strong evidence that juries are not highly valued by the parties to the contract (83).

  16. One can adopt a less radical position: in the same way that a small subset of the ASME requirements have been adopted as mandatory state codes, we might still maintain mandatory minimal state codes for medicine, taken as a subset from the requirements created by the certification companies.

  17. Aligica et al. (2019) discuss the issue of market power as a few certification companies may come to dominate the market similar to how ASME dominates the certification market for industrial safety.

References

  • Aligica, P. D., Boettke, P. J., & Tarko, V. (2019). Public governance and the classical liberal tradition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aligica, P. D., & Tarko, V. (2012). Polycentricity: From Polanyi to Ostrom, and beyond. Governance, 25(2), 237–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aligica, P. D., & Tarko, V. (2014). Crony capitalism: Rent seeking, institutions and ideology. Kyklos, 67(2), 156–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aligica, P. D., & Tarko, V. (2015). Capitalist alternatives: Models, taxonomies, scenarios. London, New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Al-Ubaydli, O., & McLaughlin, P. A. (2015). RegData: A numerical database on industry-specific regulations for all United States industries and federal regulations, 1997–2012. Regulation & Governance, 11(1), 109–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D., Dorn D., Katz, L. F., Patterson, C., & Van Reenen, J. (2017). Concentrating on the fall of the labor share. Working paper 23108. National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w23108.

  • Azar, J., Schmalz, M. C., & Tecu. I. (2018). Anticompetitive effects of common ownership. Journal of Finance, 73(4), 1513–1565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biser, J. J. (2014). Law-and-economics: Why Gordon Tullock prefers Napoleon Bonaparte over the Duke of Wellington; and why he may end up on St. Helena. Public Choice, 158, 261–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bó, E. D. (2006). Regulatory capture: A review. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(2), 203–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J. (1995). Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom revisited: Government failure in the argument against socialism. Eastern Economic Journal, 21(1), 7–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2011). Quasimarket failure. Public Choice, 149(1/2), 209–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & López, E. J. (2002). Austrian economics and public choice. Review of Austrian Economics, 15(2–3), 111–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broughel, J. (2017). Regulation and economic growth. Arlington, VA: Mercatus Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1980). Rent seeking and profit seeking. In Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society. Texas A&M University Press.

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Congleton, R. D. (1998). Politics by principle, not interest: Towards nondiscriminatory democracy. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Goetz, C. J. (1972). Efficiency limits of fiscal mobility: An assessment of the Tiebout model. Journal of Public Economics, 1(1), 25–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., Tullock, G., & Tollison, R. (Eds.). (1980). Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Yoon, Y. J. (2000). Symmetric tragedies: Commons and anticommons. Journal of Law & Economics, 43, 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B. (2001). Standing Tiebout on his head: Tax capitalization and the monopoly power of local governments. Public Choice, 108(1–2), 101–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D., & Hillman, A. L. (Eds.). (2015). Companion to the political economy of rent seeking. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Pub.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D., Hillman, A. L., & Konrad, K. A. (Eds.). (2008). 40 years of research on rent seeking. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. (2011). The great stagnation. Harmondsworth: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. (2017). The complacent class. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • DeMuth, C. (2016). Can the administrative state be tamed? Journal of Legal Analysis, 8(1), 121–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donahue, J. D. (1997). Tiebout? Or not Tiebout? The market metaphor and America’s devolution debate. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(4), 73–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Douglas, G. W., & Miller, J. C. (1974). Economic regulation of domestic air transport. Washington: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dudley, S. E., & Brito, J. (2012). Regulation: A primer (2nd ed.). Washington, DC: Mercatus Center at George Mason University and George Washington University Regulatory Studies Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellig, J. (1995). Why do regulators regulate? The case of the southern California gas market. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 7(3), 293–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geradin, D., & McCahery, J. A. (2004). Regulatory co-opetition: Transcending the regulatory competition debate. In J. Jordana & D. Levi-Faur (Eds.), The politics of regulation. Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goetz, G. (2010). Who inspects what? A food safety scramble. Food Safety News. December 16, 2010. http://www.foodsafetynews.com/2010/12/who-inspects-what-a-food-safety-scramble/.

  • Goldschlag, N., & Tabarrok, A. (2018). Is regulation to blame for the decline in American entrepreneurship? Economic Policy, 33, 5–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grullon, G., Larkin, Y., & Michaely, R. (2017). Are US industries becoming more concentrated? Working paper, https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2612047.

  • Guy, A. (2016). You’re probably eating Asian catfish without knowing it. Should you be worried? Oceana. September 13, 2016. https://oceana.org/blog/you%E2%80%99re-probably-eating-asian-catfish-without-knowing-it-should-you-be-worried.

  • Gwartney, J. D., Lawson, R., & Hall, J. (2018). Economic freedom of the world: 2018 annual report. Vancouver: The Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamburger, P. (2014). Is administrative law unlawful?. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1944). The road to serfdom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller, M. (1998). The tragedy of the anticommons: Property in the transition from Marx to markets. Harvard Law Review, 111(3), 621–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, M. (2008). The gridlock economy: How too much ownership wrecks markets, stops innovation, and costs lives. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller, M. (2013). The tragedy of the anticommons: A concise introduction and Lexicon. Modern Law Review, 76, 6–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higgins, R. S., Shughart, W. F., II, & Tollison, R. D. (1988). Free entry and efficient rent-seeking. In C. K. Rowley, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), The political economy of rent-seeking (pp. 127–139). Boston, MA: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Howell-Moroney, M. (2008). The Tiebout hypothesis 50 years later: Lessons and lingering challenges for metropolitan governance in the 21st Century. Public Administration Review, 68(1), 97–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordana, J., & Levi-Faur, D. (Eds.). (2004). The politics of regulation: Institutions and regulatory reforms for the age of governance. Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kwoka, J. (2014). Mergers, merger control, and remedies: A retrospective analysis of US policy. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Levi-Faur, D. (2005). The global diffusion of regulatory capitalism. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 598(1), 12–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindsey, B., & Teles, S. (2017). The captured economy: How the powerful enrich themselves, slow down growth, and increase inequality. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowery, D. (1998). Consumer sovereignty and quasi-market failure. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 8(2), 137–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowery, D., & Lyons, W. E. (1989). The impact of jurisdictional boundaries: An individual-level test of the Tiebout model. Journal of Politics, 51(01), 73–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F. S. (1987). Rent extraction and rent creation in the economic theory of regulation. The Journal of Legal Studies, 16(1), 101–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F. S. (1997). Money for nothing: Politicians, rent extraction, and political extortion. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McPhail, E., & Tarko, V. (2017). The evolution of governance structures in a polycentric system. In M. Altman (Ed.), Handbook of behavioral economics and smart decision-making (pp. 290–313). Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H. (2012). Why capitalism?. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, J. C., Shughart, W. F., II, & Tollison, R. D. (1984). A note on centralized regulatory review. Public Choice, 43(1), 83–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, M., & Stratmann, T. (2015). A tragedy of the anticommons: Local option taxation and cell phone tax bills. Public Choice, 165, 171–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1991). Polycentricity: The structural basis of self-governing systems. In The meaning of American federalism, 223–248. San Francisco, CA: ICS Press.

  • Ostrom, V. (1997). The meaning of democracy and the vulnerabilities of democracies. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V., Tiebout, C. M., & Warren, R. (1961). The organization of government in metropolitan areas. American Political Science Review, 55(04), 831–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1989). The economic theory of regulation after a decade of deregulation. In Brookings papers on economic activity, 1–41. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

  • Peltzman, S. (1993). George Stigler’s contribution to the economic analysis of regulation. Journal of Political Economy, 101(5), 818–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. ([1973] 2003). The economic analysis of law (6th edn.). New York: Aspen.

  • Powell, B. (2004). Competition and monopoly power in local government. Public Choice, 120(3/4), 353–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajagopalan, S., & Wagner, R. E. (2013). Constitutional craftsmanship and the rule of law. Constitutional Political Economy, 24, 295–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shughart II, W. F. (2018). Gordon Tullock’s critique of the common law. Independent Review, 23(2).

  • Steele, C., & Bowman, J. (1987). The constitutionality of independent regulatory agencies under the necessary and proper clause: The case of the Federal Election Commission. Yale Journal on Regulation, 4(2), 363–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, pp. 3–21.

  • Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R. D. (1982). Rent seeking: A survey. Kyklos, 35(4), 575–602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971). The logic of the law. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980a). Efficient rent seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980b). Trials on trial: The pure theory of legal procedure. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1991). Rent seeking. In The new Palgrave: The world of economics, (pp. 604–609). New York, London: W.W. Norton.

  • Tullock, G. (2005a). Law and economics. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2005b). The rent-seeking society. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1996). Regulatory reform and liability for pharmaceuticals and medical devices. In Advancing medical innovation: Health, safety and the role of government in the 21st century. Washington, DC: Progress and Freedom Foundation.

  • Vogel, S. K. (1996). Freer markets, more rules: Regulatory reform in advanced industrial countries. Ithaca, London: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (1989). To promote the general welfare: Market processes vs. political transfers. San Francisco, CA: Pacific Research Inst for Public.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2009). Property, state, and entangled political economy. In Markets and politics (pp. 37–49). Marburg: Metropolis.

  • Wagner, R. E. (2016). Politics as a peculiar business: Insights from a theory of entangled political economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Pub.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zywicki, T. J. (2008). Spontaneous order and the common law: Gordon Tullock’s critique. Public Choice, 135, 35–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Jerry Ellig, Patrick McLaughlin, Matt Mitchell, and William Shughart II for very useful feed-back and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vlad Tarko.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tarko, V., Farrant, A. The efficiency of regulatory arbitrage. Public Choice 181, 141–166 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-00630-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-00630-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation