Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The political economy of sales taxes and sales tax exemptions

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I analyze the choice politicians face when seeking votes from groups that lobby for sales tax rate decreases or tax exemptions, given the constraint that politicians want to raise a certain amount of revenue. Using data on sales taxes, I develop a model predicting a positive relationship between the number of exemptions and the sales tax rate. The estimation results provide support for this prediction. Each additional exemption is associated with an increase of between 0.10 and 0.25 percentage points in the tax rate.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To test this hypothesis, I assume that cross-border shopping or any online shopping that might give rise to an erosion of tax and exemption differences across states is quantitative small, relative to all sales within the state.

  2. The states are: Arkansas, Georgia, Indiana, Iowa, Kansas, Kentucky, Michigan, Minnesota, Nebraska, Nevada, New Jersey, North Carolina, North Dakota, Ohio, Oklahoma, Rhode Island, South Dakota, Tennessee, Utah, Vermont, Washington, West Virginia, Wisconsin, and Wyoming.

  3. I chose 2009 for revenue data because it falls within the 2008-to-2012 period, for which I have data on sales tax exemptions. Owing to recessionary conditions in that time frame, sales tax revenues might have been below average; however, if the revenue reduction was similar across all states, it should not affect my estimates of the equilibrium relationship between sales tax rates and exemptions.

  4. I kept Colorado in the sample because if politicians there decide to reduce the number of sales tax exemptions, they are unable to raise sales tax rates to offset the narrower sales tax base. The constitutional constraint on raising the state sales tax rate may lead to less significant results if exemptions are reduced, and the sales tax cannot be raised.

  5. Tax Facts 96-1, General Excise vs. Sales Tax http://www6.hawaii.gov/tax/taxfacts/tf96-01.pdf.

  6. Sales tax rates are from 2012, while data on exemptions come primarily from earlier years, starting with 2008. This fact mitigates concerns that the error term in Eq. (1) is correlated with exemptions.

  7. This is done because California has the highest sales tax rate in the United States and allows one of the largest number of exemptions.

References

  • Anderson, G. M., Martin, D. T., & Tollison, R. D. (1987). Do tax loopholes increase or decrease tax revenue? Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice, 5, 83–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. J., & Rosen, H. S. (1998). Sales taxes and prices: an empirical analysis. NBER Working Paper No. 6667. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Brownell, K. D., Farley, T., Willett, W. C., Popkin, B. M., Chaloupka, F. J., Thompson, J. W., et al. (2009). The public health and economic benefits of taxing sugar-sweetened beverages. The New England Journal of Medicine, 361(16), 1599–1605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, D., Fox, W. F., & Tuttle, M. (2006). Tax base elasticities: A multi-state analysis of long-run and short-run dynamics. Southern Economic Journal, 73(2), 315–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chouinard, H. H., Davis, D. E., LaFrance, J. T., & Perloff, J. M. (2006). Fat taxes: big money for small change. Working Paper No. 1007. Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics and Policy, University of California at Berkeley.

  • Hall, B. H. (1999). Effectiveness of the California R&D credit. California Council on Science and Technology. http://www.ccst.us/publications/1999/CREST4.pdf.

  • Hansmann, H. (1987). The effect of tax exemption and other factors on the market share of non-profit versus for-profit firms. National Tax Journal, 40, 71–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins, R. R. (2002). Popular substitution effects: excess burden estimates for general sales taxes. National Tax Journal, 55(4), 755–770.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ihlanfeldt, K. R. (1995). Ten principles for state tax incentives. Economic Development Quarterly, 15, 339–355.

    Google Scholar 

  • Militaru, A. & Stratmann T. (2014). A Survey of Sales Tax Exemptions in the States: Understanding Sales Taxes and Sales Tax Exemptions Working Paper No. 14, Mercatus Center at George Mason University.

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19, 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, L. M., & Chaloupka, F. J. (2009). Food prices and obesity: evidence and policy implications for taxes and subsidies. The Milbank Quarterly, 87(1), 229–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper is based on a my co-authored working paper with (Militaru and Stratmann 2014).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Stratmann.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (DOCX 31 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Stratmann, T. The political economy of sales taxes and sales tax exemptions. Public Choice 171, 207–221 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-017-0434-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-017-0434-z

Keywords

Navigation