Public Choice

, Volume 166, Issue 1–2, pp 161–182 | Cite as

The perils of government enforcement

  • Rustam Romaniuc
  • Katherine Farrow
  • Lisette Ibanez
  • Alain Marciano
Article

Abstract

An important part of the debate about self versus state-governance involves a discussion about enforcement mechanisms. While some scholars argue that private enforcement mechanisms work sufficiently well in supporting cooperation, others cite the downfalls of private mechanisms so as to legitimize government enforcement. This paper focuses on the interplay between government and private enforcement mechanisms. Using an experimental approach, we demonstrate two results. First, we show that government enforcement, in the form of a centralized monetary punishment in our experiment, can be useful if aligned with and implemented after a private form of enforcement, namely peer disapproval. However, our second result suggests that the removal of government enforcement leads to a substantial decrease in overall cooperation levels—cooperation levels are higher under private enforcement when subjects had never experienced government enforcement compared to when they had been exposed to government enforcement. Specifically, the removal of government enforcement undermines the power of the remaining private enforcement mechanism to affect the behavior of free-riders.

Keywords

Self-governance Private enforcement Peer control Government enforcement Public goods 

JEL Classification

C92 D70 H41 K42 

Supplementary material

11127_2016_319_MOESM1_ESM.pdf (62 kb)
Supplementary material 1 (pdf 61 KB)

References

  1. Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. H. (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737–753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Andreoni, J., & Gee, L. K. (2012). Gun for hire: Delegated enforcement and peer punishment in public goods provision. Journal of Public Economics, 96(11–12), 1036–1046.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Anderson, T., & Hill, P. J. (1977). An American experiment in anarcho-capitalism: The not so wild, wild West. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 3, 9–29.Google Scholar
  4. Aviram, A. (2004). A paradox of spontaneous formation: The evolution of private legal systems. Yale Law & Policy Review, 22, 1–68.Google Scholar
  5. Baldassarri, D., & Grossman, G. (2011). Centralized sanctioning and legitimate authority promote cooperation in humans. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(27), 11023–11027.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Benabou, R. & Tirole, J. (2011). Laws and norms. NBER Working Paper No. 17579.Google Scholar
  7. Benson, B. L. (1989). Enforcement of private property rights in primitive societies: Law without government. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 9(1), 1–26.Google Scholar
  8. Benson, B. L. (1990). Customary law with private means of resolving disputes and dispensing justice: A description of a modern system of law and order without state coercion. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 9(2), 25–42.Google Scholar
  9. Benson, B. L. (1991a). An evolutionary cntractarian view of primitive law: The institutions and incentives arising under customary American Indian law. Review of Austrian Economics, 5(1), 41–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Benson, B. L. (1991b). Reciprocal exchange as the basis for recognition of law: Examples from American history. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 10(1), 53–82.Google Scholar
  11. Bernstein, L. (1992). Opting out of the legal system: Extralegal contractual relations in the diamond industry. Journal of Legal Studies, 21(1), 115–157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Bicchieri, C. (2006). The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Boehm, C. (1999). Hierarchy in the forest: The evolution of egalitarian behavior. Harvard: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  14. Boettke, P., Coyne, C., & Leeson, P. T. (2008). Institutional stickiness and the new development economics. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 67(2), 331–358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Chaudhuri, A. (2011). Sustaining cooperation in laboratory public goods experiments: A selective survey of the literature. Experimental Economics, 14, 47–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Cooter, R. D. (1984). Prices and sanctions. Columbia Law Review, 84, 1523–1560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Cooter, R. D. (1998). Expressive Law and Economics. Journal of Legal Studies, 27(2), 585–608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Cooter, R. D. (2000). Three effects of social norms on law: Expression, deterrence, and internalization. Oregon Law Review, 79(1), 1–22.Google Scholar
  19. Cox, J. C. (2004). How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 46(February), 260–281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Dunbar, R. I. M. (2004). Gossip in evolutionary perspective. Review of General Psychology, 8, 100–110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Ellickson, R. (1991). Order without law: How neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  22. Engel, C. (2014). Social preferences can make imperfect sanctions work: Evidence from a public good experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 108, 343–353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Fehr, E., & Gaechter, S. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90(4), 980–994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Feinberg, M., Cheng, J. T., & Willer, R. (2012). Gossip as an effective and low-cost form of punishment. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 35(1), 25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Feldman, Y. (2009). The expressive function of trade secret law: Legality, cost, intrinsic motivation, and consensus. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 6(1), 177–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Feldman, Y., & Taylor, T. R. (2011). Mandated justice: The political promise and possible pitfalls of mandating procedural justice in the workplace. Regulation & Governance, 6(1), 46–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Fleury, J.-B., & Marciano, A. (2014). Order, coordination, and collective action among the undead. In G. Whitman & J. P. Dow (Eds.), Economics of the undead: Blood, brains and benjamins. New York: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar
  28. Friedman, D. (1979). Private creation and enforcement of law—A historical case. Journal of Legal Studies, 8(2), 399–415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Funk, P. (2007). Is there an expressive function of law? An empirical analysis of voting law with symbolic fines. American Law and Economics Review, 9(1), 135–159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Gaechter, S. (2014). Human pro-social motivation and the maintenance of social order. In E. Zamir & D. Teichman (Eds.), Handbook on Behavioral Economics and the Law. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  31. Gaechter, S., & Fehr, E. (1999). Collective action as a social exchange. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 39(4), 341–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Gaechter, S., & Herrmann, D. (2009). Reciprocity, culture and human cooperation: Previous insights and a new cross-cultural experiment. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 364(1518), 791–806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Giardini, F. (2012). Deterrence and transmission as mechanisms ensuring reliability of gossip. Cognitive Processing, 13(2), 465–475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Giardini, F., & Conte, R. (2011). Gossip for social control in natural and artificial societies. Simulation, 88(1), 18–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Gneezy, U., & Rustichini, A. (2000). A fine is a price. Journal of Legal Studies, 29, 1–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Goeree, J. K., Holt, C. H., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Private costs and public benefits: Unraveling the effects of altruism and noisy behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 83, 255–276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: Evidence on the Maghribi traders. Journal of Economic History, XLIX, 857–882.Google Scholar
  38. Greif, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: The Maghribi traders' coalition. American Economic Review, 83(3), 525–548.Google Scholar
  39. Grenier, B. (2004). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. In: Kremer, K. and Macho, V. (eds.), Forshung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen, GWDG Bericht 63, 79–93.Google Scholar
  40. Guala, F. (2012). Reciprocity: Weak or strong? What punishment experiments do (and do not) demonstrate. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 35, 1–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Josselin, J.-M., & Marciano, A. (1995). Constitutionalism and common knowledge: Assessment and application to a future European constitution. Public Choice, 85(1–2), 173–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Josselin, J.-M., & Marciano, A. (1997). The paradox of Leviathan: How to develop and contain the future European state? European Journal of Law and Economics, 4(1), 5–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Josselin, J.-M., & Marciano, A. (2002). The making of the French Civil Code: An economic interpretation. European Journal of Law and Economics, 14, 193–203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Karakostas, A., & Zizzo, D. J. (2015). Compliance and the power of authority. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2015.09.016.
  45. Karayiannis, A. D., & Hatzis, A. N. (2012). Morality, social norms and the rule of law as transaction cost-saving devices: The case of ancient Athens. European Journal of Law and Economics, 33(3), 621–643.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Keser, C., & van Winden, F. (2000). Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 102(1), 23–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Khadjavi, M. (2015). On the interaction of deterrence and emotions. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. doi:10.1093/jleo/ewu012.
  48. Ledyard, O. (1995). Public goods: some experimental results. In: Kagel, J. and Roth, A. (eds.), Handbook of experimental economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press (Chap. 2).Google Scholar
  49. Leeson, P. T. (2007). Ann-arrgh-chy: The law and economics of pirate organization. Journal of Law & Economics, 115(6), 1049–1094.Google Scholar
  50. Leeson, P. T. (2007). Trading with bandits. Journal of Law & Economics, 50, 303–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Leeson, P. T. (2009). The calculus of piratical consent: The myth of the myth of social contract. Public Choice, 139(3–4), 443–459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Leeson, P. T. (2009b). The invisible hook: The hidden economics of pirates. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  53. Leeson, P. T. (2009). The laws of lawlessness. Journal of Legal Studies, 38(2), 471–503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Leeson, P. T. (2013). Gypsy law. Public Choice, 155, 273–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Leeson, P. T. (2014). Pirates, prisoners, and preliterates: Anarchic context and the private enforcement of law. European Journal of Law and Economics, 37(3), 365–379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Leeson, P. T. (2014 b). Anarchy unbound: Why self-governance works better than you think. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Leeson, P. T. (2014). God damn: The law and economics of monastic malediction. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 30(1), 193–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Leeson, P., & Skarbek, D. (2010). Criminal constitutions. Global Crime, 11(3), 279–298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Masclet, D., Noussair, C., Tucker, S., & Villeval, M.-C. (2003). Monetary and nonmonetary punishment in the voluntary contributions mechanism. American Economic Review, 93(1), 366–380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. McAdams, R. H. (1997). The origin, development, and regulation of norms. Michigan Law Review, 96, 338–433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Milgram, S. (1963). Behavioral study of obedience. Journal of Abnormal Social Psychology, 67, 371–378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Nelissen, R. M. A., & Mulder, L. B. (2013). What makes a sanction stick? The effects of financial and social sanctions on norm compliance. Social Influence, 8(1), 70–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Nikiforakis, N. (2008). Punishment and counter-punishment in public good games: Can we really govern ourselves? Journal of Public Economics, 92, 91–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Ostrom, E., Walker, J., & Gardner, R. (1992). Covenants with and without a sword: Self-governance is possible. American Political Science Review, 86(2), 404–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Peden, J. R. (1977). Property rights in Celtic Irish law. Journal of Libertarian Studies, 1(2), 81–95.Google Scholar
  66. Peysakhovich, A., & Rand, D. G. (2015). Habits of virtue: Creating norms of cooperation and defection in the laboratory. Management Science,. doi:10.1287/mnsc.2015.2168.
  67. Posner, R. A., & Rasmusen, E. (1999). Creating and enforcing norms, with special reference to sanctions. International Review of Law and Economics, 19, 369–382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Romaniuc, R. (2016). What makes law to change behavior? An experimental study. Review of Law and Economics, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  69. Sened, I. (1997). The political institution of private property. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  70. Sobel, R. S., & Osoba, B. J. (2009). Youth gangs as pseudo-governments: Implications for violent crime. Southern Economic Journal, 75(4), 996–1018.Google Scholar
  71. Solvasson, B. (1993). Institutional evolution in the Icelandic Commonwealth. Constitutional Political Economy, 4, 97–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Stagnaro, M. N., Arechar, A. A. & Rand, D. G. (2016). From good intentions to good norms: Top-down incentives to cooperate foster prosociality but not norm enforcement. Mimeo.Google Scholar
  73. Stringham, E. P. (Ed.). (2005). Anarchy, state, and public choice. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  74. Stringham, E. P. (2015). Private governance: Creating order in economic and social life. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Stringham, E. P., & Powel, B. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: A survey. Public Choice, 140, 503–538.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Subhasish, D. (2013). Non-monetary incentives and opportunistic behavior: Evidence from a laboratory public good game. Economic Inquiry, 51(2), 1374–1388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Sugden, R. (1986). The economics of rights, cooperation, and welfare. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  78. Sunstein, C. (1996). On the expressive function of law. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 144, 2021–2053.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. Williamson, C. (2009). Informal institutions rule: Institutional arrangements and economic performance. Public Choice, 139(3), 371–387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Xiao, E., & Houser, D. (2011). Punish in public. Journal of Public Economics, 95(7–8), 1006–1017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Zizzo, D. J. (2010). Experimenter demand effects in economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 13(1), 75–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  • Rustam Romaniuc
    • 1
    • 2
    • 3
  • Katherine Farrow
    • 2
  • Lisette Ibanez
    • 4
  • Alain Marciano
    • 2
  1. 1.Laboratory for Experimental AnthropologyLille Catholic University, Maison des ChercheursLilleFrance
  2. 2.University of Montpellier, UMR 1135 LAMETAMontpellierFrance
  3. 3.University of Turin - IELTurinItaly
  4. 4.INRA, UMR 1135 LAMETAMontpellierFrance

Personalised recommendations