Advertisement

Public Choice

, Volume 158, Issue 3–4, pp 359–382 | Cite as

An experimental study of the efficiency of unanimity rule and majority rule

  • Keith DoughertyEmail author
  • Brian Pitts
  • Justin Moeller
  • Robi Ragan
Article

Abstract

Scholars traditionally claim that unanimity rule is more capable of producing Pareto optimal outcomes than majority rule. Dougherty and Edward (Public Choice 151(3):655–678, 2012) make the opposite claim assuming proposals are either random, sincere, or strategic. We test these competing hypotheses in a two-dimensional framework using laboratory experiments. Our primary results suggest: (1) majority rule enters the Pareto set more quickly than unanimity rule, (2) majority rule leaves the Pareto set at the same rate as unanimity rule, and (3) majority rule is more likely to select a Pareto optimal outcome than unanimity rule at the end of the game.

Keywords

Majority rule Unanimity rule Pareto optimality Empirical social choice Experiment 

Notes

Acknowledgements

We thank T.K. Ahn for careful comments on both the experimental design and the presentation of the results. Bill Bianco, Joe Oppenheimer, Oleg Smirnov, and Jimmy Walker provided useful comments as well.

References

  1. Aldrich, J. (1995). Why parties?: the origin and transformation of party politics in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Arrow, K. J. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New Haven: Yale University Press. Google Scholar
  3. Arthur, W. B. (2006). Out-of-equilibrium economics and agent-based modeling. In K. L. Judd & L. Tesfatsion (Eds.), Handbook of computational economics, vol. 2: agent-based computational economics. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Google Scholar
  4. Bianco, W. T., Lynch, M. S., Miller, G. J., & Sened, I. (2006). ‘A theory waiting to be discovered and used’: a reanalysis of canonical experiments on majority rule decision making. The Journal of Politics, 68(4), 837–850. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bianco, W. T., Lynch, M. S., Miller, G. J., & Sened, I. (2008). The constrained instability of majority rule: experiments on the robustness of the uncovered set. Political Analysis, 16(2), 115–137. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (2000). The reason of rules. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund. Google Scholar
  7. Buchanan, J. M. (1967). Public finance in democratic process. Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press. Google Scholar
  8. Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press. Google Scholar
  9. Chen, Y., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1998). Veto games: spatial committees under unanimity rule. Public Choice, 97(4), 617–643. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Colomer, J. H. (2001). Political institutions: democracy and social choice. New York: Oxford University Press. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods, and club goods (2nd ed.). New York: Cambridge University Press. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Camerer, C., Ho, T., & Chong, J. (2004). Behavioral game theory: thinking, learning, and teaching. In S. Huck (Ed.), Advances in understanding strategic behaviour: game theory, experiments, and bounded rationality: essays in honour of Werner Güth. Basingstoke: Palgrave. Google Scholar
  13. Dougherty, K. L., & Edward, J. (2004). The Pareto efficiency and expected costs of k-majority rules. Politics Philosophy & Economics, 3(2), 161–189. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Dougherty, K. L., & Edward, J. (2005). A non-equilibrium analysis of unanimity rule, majority rule, and two Pareto concepts. Economic Inquiry, 43(4), 855–864. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Dougherty, K. L., & Edward, J. (2011). The calculus of consent and constitutional design. New York: Springer. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Dougherty, K. L., & Edward, J. (2012). Voting for Pareto optimality: a multidimensional analysis. Public Choice, 151(3), 655–678. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Duggan, J. (2006). Endogenous voting agendas. Social Choice and Welfare, 27(3), 495–530. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Feld, S. L., Grofman, B., & Miller, N. (1988). Centripetal forces in spatial voting: on the size of the yolk. Public Choice, 59(1), 37–50. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Fiorina, M. P., Plott, C. R. (1978). Committee decisions under majority rule: an experimental study. The American Political Science Review, 72(2), 575–598. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Fishburn, P. C. (1973). The theory of social choice. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Google Scholar
  21. Heckelman, J. C., & Dougherty, K. L. (2010). Majority rule versus supermajority rules, their effects on narrow and broad taxes. Public Finance Review, 38(6), 738–761. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Hinich, M. J., & Munger, M. C. (1997). Analytical politics. New York: Cambridge University Press. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. King, R. R. (1994). An experimental investigation of super majority voting rules, implications for the financial accounting standards board. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 25(2), 197–217. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Laing, J. D., & Slotznick, B. (1991). When anyone can veto, a laboratory study of committees governed by unanimous rule. Behavioral Science, 36(3), 179–195. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Mailath, G. J. (1998). Do people play Nash equilibrium? Lessons from evolutionary game theory. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(3), 1347–1374. Google Scholar
  26. McKelvey, R. D. (1976). Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory, 12, 472–482. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. McKelvey, R. D. (1986). Covering, dominance, and institution-free properties of social choice. American Journal of Political Science, 30(2), 283–314. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. McKelvey, R. D., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1981). Experiments on the core, some disconcerting results for majority rule voting games. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 25(4), 709–724. Google Scholar
  29. McKelvey, R. D., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1984a). An experimental study of the effects of procedural rules on committee behavior. The Journal of Politics, 46(1), 182–205. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. McKelvey, R. D., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1984b). Rational expectations in elections, some experimental results based on a multidimensional model. Public Choice, 44(1), 182–205. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Miller, N. (1980). A new solution set for tournament and majority voting. American Journal of Political Science, 24(1), 68–96. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Miller, G. J., & Oppenheimer, J. A. (1982). Universalism in experimental committees. The American Political Science Review, 76(3), 561–574. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Mueller, D. (1996). Constitutional democracy. New York: Oxford University Press. Google Scholar
  34. Mueller, D. (2003). Public choice III. New York: Cambridge University Press. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Niou, E., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1985). Universalism in Congress. American Journal of Political Science, 29(2), 246–258. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Oppenheimer, J. A., & Frohlich, N. (2007). Justice preferences and the arrow problem. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 19(4), 363–390. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Ordeshook, P. C. (1986). Game theory and political theory. New York: Cambridge University Press. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Penn, E. M. (2006). Alternate definitions of the uncovered set and their implications. Social Choice and Welfare, 27, 83–87. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Plott, C. R. (1967). A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. American Economic Review, 57(4), 787–806. Google Scholar
  40. Riker, W. H. (1980). Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions. The American Political Science Review, 74(2), 432–446. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Riker, W. H. (1982). Liberalism against populism. Prospect Heights: Waveland Press. Google Scholar
  42. Schofield, N. J. (1978). Instability of simple dynamic games. Review of Economic Studies, 45(3), 575–594. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Shepsle, K. A. (1979). Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models. American Journal of Political Science, 23(1), 27–59. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Shepsle, K. A. (1986). Institutional equilibrium and equilibrium institutions. In H. Weisberg (Ed.), Political science, the science of politics (pp. 51–81). New York: Agathon. Google Scholar
  45. Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players, how political institutions work. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Google Scholar
  46. Tullock, G. (1998). On voting, a public choice approach. Northampton: Edward Elgar. Google Scholar
  47. Walker, J. M., Gardner, R., Herr, A., & Ostrom, E. (2000). Collective choice in the commons, experimental results on proposed allocation rules and votes. Economic Journal, 110(460), 212–234. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Weimer, D. L., & Vining, A. R. (2005). Policy analysis, concepts and practice (4th ed.). Saddle River: Prentice Hall. Google Scholar
  49. Wilson, R. K. (1986). Forward and backward agenda procedures, committee experiments on structurally induced equilibrium. The Journal of Politics, 48(2), 390–409. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2011

Authors and Affiliations

  • Keith Dougherty
    • 1
    Email author
  • Brian Pitts
    • 1
  • Justin Moeller
    • 1
  • Robi Ragan
    • 2
  1. 1.Department of Political ScienceUniversity of GeorgiaAthensUSA
  2. 2.Emory UniversityAtlantaUSA

Personalised recommendations